Free Essay

Credit Risk Model

In: Business and Management

Submitted By Bradj
Words 33386
Pages 134
University of Florence Faculty of Economy Master’s Degree in Bank, Insurance and Financial Markets Thesis in Applied Statistics for Banks and Insurances

Credit Risk Models: Single Firm Default and Contagion Default Analysis

Supervisor: P rof essor Fabrizio Cipollini Student: Marco Gambacciani

Academic Year 2009/2010

Contents
Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1 Structural Models 1.1 Terminal Default . . . . . . . . . . . . 1.2 First Passage Models . . . . . . . . . . 1.2.1 The Black and Cox’s Model . . 1.2.2 Longstaff and Schwartz’s Model 1.2.3 Leland and Toft’s Model . . . . 1.2.4 Zhou’s Model . . . . . . . . . . 1.2.5 Random Threshold Model . . . 2 5 5 11 11 15 19 24 30 35 36 39 41 45 48 50 51 56 67 76 77 79 79 82 83 84 94 114

. . . . . . .

. . . . . . .

. . . . . . .

. . . . . . .

. . . . . . .

. . . . . . .

. . . . . . .

. . . . . . .

. . . . . . .

. . . . . . .

. . . . . . .

. . . . . . .

. . . . . . .

. . . . . . .

. . . . . . .

. . . . . . .

. . . . . . .

. . . . . . .

2

Modelli reduced form 2.1 Approach With An Homogenous Poisson Process . . 2.2 Approach With a Non-Homogenous Poisson Process 2.3 Approach with a Cox’s Process . . . . . . . . . . . . 2.4 Bond and Spread Valuation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Models For The Correlation Between Defaults 3.1 Bottom-Up Models . . . . . . . . . . . . . 3.1.1 Structural Apporach . . . . . . . . 3.1.2 Intensity Models Approaches . . . 3.1.3 Approaches with Copulas . . . . . 3.2 Top-Down Models . . . . . . . . . . . . .

. . . .

. . . .

. . . .

. . . .

. . . .

. . . .

. . . .

. . . .

. . . .

. . . .

. . . .

3

. . . . .

. . . . .

. . . . .

. . . . .

. . . . .

. . . . .

. . . . .

. . . . .

. . . . .

. . . . .

. . . . .

. . . . .

. . . . .

. . . . .

. . . . .

. . . . .

4

Credit Risk Derivates 4.1 The Credit Default Swaps . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 4.2 CDSs Index . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 4.3 The Collateral Debt Obbligation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Empirical Implementation 5.1 Analysis of the Trend for the iTraxx Europe . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 5.2 Factorial Model for the Intensity of Default . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Conclusion

5

6

1

Introduction
The starting point of this thesis is the risk of default, which is one of the main sources of risk faced by banks, financial institutions, insurance companies and businesses in general. In recent years we have been seeing a high pace development of models and financial instruments aimed at achieving the goal of adeguate management of the risk of default. In this context, among the instruments which could be used to hedge against the risk of default, there are the credit derivatives, which have assumed a central role in national and international markets. These assets are especially useful for banks and issuers or buyers of risky bonds who are subject to extensive exposure to credit risk, ie the risk that a counterparty does not fulfill an obligation, both for the payment of one or more coupons and, more seriously, for the occurence of its default. In particular, with the credit derivatives, the underlying credit risk corresponding to a given credit exposure is effectively eliminated, or more properly transferred to a third subject not directly exposed. However, the credit derivative holder has the potential to earn from a possible default or unfulfillment. These contracts do transfer the underlying credit risk without physically transfer the credit or instead use the traditional collaterals or guarantees for the lowering the credit risk. In my thesis, the attention is focused particularly on the assessment of the problem of default correlation: we must, in fact, examine the structure of dependence between the companies underlying credit derivative instruments on credit risk. In order to estimate the joint probability, since the common1 measures of dependence
1

Such as the coefficient of linear correlation

2

CONTENTS

3

are not adequate in this context, we avail ourselves of the copula, the use of which in recent years has been becoming more and more increasingly popular in the framework of multivariate risk of default, especially for its relative easiness of implementation. For an analysis of the structure of dependence of the default risk between several companies, we analyze a particular credit iTraxx Europe index, which measures the spreads relative to 125 European companies with high credit merit. Finally we estimate the probability of default for some firms in the European financial sector, almost all of them belonging to the iTraxx Europe index, by constructing a factor model for the intensity of default, which is the most popular among the academics, since it constitutes a link between the use of observable variables in the economic scenario in which firms operate, and which is quite easy to implement for the assessment of the default probability at the univariate and at the multivariate level. My work is organized as follows: In the first chapter and in the second chapter, respectively, are studied the structural models and the reduced form models for the assessment of univariate default risk, focusing on the estimation of the probability of default in these models and the determination of the spreads. In the third chapter the attention is shifted to the models for the analysis of the structure of dependence in default risk, in fact the chapetr is focused on the introduction and the use of copula functions, which are by far the most appropriate tool to tackle the multivariate default estimation, because they are of immediate application and their use has been widespread in the recent years in describing the joint distribution probability of default of two or more firms in terms of their marginal distributions. In the fourth chapter, is given a precise definition of what is meant by credit risk derivatives as well as the various elements that characterize them together with a detailed description of a Credit Default Swap (CDS) and of an index of CDSs. Finally in the fifth chapter, we undertake an analysis of the CDSs index, the iTraxx Europe, in the light of the results of which we proceed to build a factor model for the intensity of default, applied to

CONTENTS

4

a sample of banks and insurance companies, for which it is estimated the probability of default at univariate and multivariate level, analyzing by the use of a Gumbel copula the level of infection or contagion risk in the probability of default among firms.

Chapter 1 Structural Models
1.1 Terminal Default

The first semplified structural model was developed by Merton (1974), on the basis of the Black and Scholes framework for the option pricing. Formulating that model Merton makes some assumptions, some of the them are for semplification purpose while other are the fundamental ones 1 : 1. Assets divisibility, no transaction costs and no taxes. 2. Existence of a market where borrowing and lending is allowed at the same interest rate. 3. All the agents holds a wealth which is compatible with their intetions to buy or to sell. 4. Short sales are allowed. 5. Assets negotiation takes place continously.
From the Merton (1974)’s paper the semplificatory assumptions are the first four ones regarding market efficiency, the sixth is verified by the model and the sixth allows to split the effect on the pricing in the credit risk effect and the interest risk effect. Those assumptions are introduced to semplify the model construction. While the fundamental ones for the definition of the model are the fith and the eigth.
1

5

CHAPTER 1. STRUCTURAL MODELS

6

6. Validity of the Modigliani and Miller theorem, that is the firm valuation doesn’t depend on the capital structure (Miller (1988)), hence this is assumed to be stationary2 . 7. Flat term structure of the interest rates. 8. The Assets value obeys to a Geometric Brownian Motion. We assume that firm financial structure is composed by debt and equity capital, hence for the balance sheet constraint we get:

V (t) = D(t) + S(t)

where V (t), D(t), S(t) are respictively the assets value, the debt value and the capital value. Furthermore we know that the debt is represented by a risky Zero Coupon Bond (ZCB, from now on) with maturity T and nominal value of L. The V (t) dynamic, rispectively under the real measure P and under risk neutral measure Q, can be described by the following stochastic differential equation (SDE, from now on):

dV (t) = (µ − q)V (t)dt + σV (t)dW (t) dV (t) = (r − q)V (t)dt + σV (t)dW (t)

(1.1) (1.2)

where r is the deterministic and constant risk-free rate, which takes the place of µ, the expected/mean rate of return for V under P, q (i.e. which is equal to C/V 3 for Merton (1974)) is the payout-ratio, σ the volatility of the assets value and W the standard brownian motion.
The capital structure is defined as the composition of the capital which comes out from the liabilities reported on the balance sheet of a firm. The capital structure represents the relation among the several financial instruments (i.e. such as debt, risk capital, or other financial assets obtained as a mixing of the previous ones) with which the firm buys its assets hence financing its activity. A stationary capital structure represents a condition in which the firm mantains constant the ratio between its liabilities, hence the leverage (i.e. the ratio between Debt and Equity Capital) doesn’t change. 3 The value C corresponds to the amount per unit of time of the payments the firm owes to its shareholders and debts holders.
2

CHAPTER 1. STRUCTURAL MODELS This equation has an unique solution under Q, which is given by:

7

V (t) = V (0) exp (r − q − 0.5σ 2 )t + σW (t)

(1.3)

The assets value follows a lognormal evolution as it is for the underlying in the option pricing framework accordingly to the Black and Scholes model. If at the debt’s expiring date the assets value V (T ) is lower than the debt nominal value L, default takes place and the bondholders riceive V (T ); otherwise there is no default and the shareholders receive what is left out of the assets after the debt is reimboursed, that is S(T ) = V (T ) − L. Hence, the firm default is linked with the capability to pay back the debt at its maturity T , from which this model is also called Terminal Default model. Accordingly to the Merton scheme for the default, we can consider the following relations:

D(T ) = min(L, V (T )) S(T ) = max(0, V (T ) − L)

(1.4) (1.5)

Given in t the value of an unit risk-free ZCB with maturity T , P (t, T ) = exp (−r(T − t)), for t < T we obtain

D(t) = EQ [P (t, T ) min (V (T ), L)] = = EQ [P (t, T ) [L − max (L − V (T ), 0)]] = = P (t, T )L − P ut(t, T ; V (t), σ 2 , L) (1.6)

For the balance sheet parity condition between assets and liabilities and for the call-put parity we get the following relation for the equity capital:

S(t) = Call(t, T ; V (t), σ 2 , L)

(1.7)

CHAPTER 1. STRUCTURAL MODELS

8

In t the debt value for the bondholders can be split in a long position on a default free bond with nominal value L and a short position on a put option4 written on the assets value with strike L. Conversely, in t the assets value for the shareholders corresponds to a long position on a call option on the assets value with strike L. Despite the underlying of the options, that is V (t), is not a traded asset while the equity value S(t) is a traded asset 5 , assuming no arbitrage oppurtunities Merton shows that there exists an Equivalent Martingale Measure under which V (t) once discounted is a martingale. Given the lognormality of the underlying Black and Scholes (1973) plain vanilla 6 option pricing formulas then can be applied in this case, obtaining

D(t) = S(t) =

V (t)Φ(−d1 ) + P (t, T )LΦ(d2 ) V (t)Φ(d1 ) − P (t, T )LΦ(d2 )

(1.8) (1.9)

where
(t) ln( V L ) + (r − q + 0.5σ 2 )(T − t) √ = σ T −t √ = d1 − σ T − t

d1 d2

(1.10) (1.11)

and Φ(•) is the Cumulative density function (Cdf) of the Standard Normal. The actual probability that there is default at T is equal to the actual probability that the call option is not exercited by the shareholders. Defining with τ 7 the time of default, in t the default
The call option and the put option are two basic types of derivative instruments (vanilla options). The first gives to the buyer the option the right to buy the underlying asset at a specified price by a certain date. The second one gives the ption the right to sell the underlying asset at a specified price by a certain date. The price specified in the contract is defined exercise price or strike sprice, while the date of expiry of the right is defined exercise date or maturity of the option. 5 The equity capital is traded over the financial markets through stocks which are representitive of the firm risk capital. 6 Plain vanilla option are defined as the basic ones, such as the call option and the put option. 7 Now we introduce the notation for the time of default τ , since this notation will be used also in the rest of the thesis in order to get an homogenous view of the different models. Anyway we remember that under this model’s assumptions the default may occur only at the debt maturity T , hence we get that P (τ < T ) = 0.
4

CHAPTER 1. STRUCTURAL MODELS probability is:

9

Pr (τ = T ) = Pr(V (T ) < L) = = Pr log(V (t)) + (µ − q − 0.5σ 2 )(T − t) + σ(W (T ) − W (t)) < log(L) = = Pr W (T ) − W (t) < ln( V L ) − (µ − q − 0.5σ 2 )(T − t) (t) σ (1.12)

Since W (t) is normally distribuited with zero mean and variance t we then obtain by substituting in the previous ln( V L ) − (µ − q − 0.5σ 2 )(T − t) (t) √ σ T −t

Pr (τ = T ) = Φ

(1.13)

Replacing µ with r we get the following risk-neutral probability of default

Pr (τ = T ) = Φ(−d2 )

(1.14)

Can be trivially proved that8 the implicit credit spread9 derived from the risky debt value, at time t is given by − ln Φ(d2 ) + s(t) =
V (t) Φ(−d1 ) LP (t,T )

T −t

(1.15)

With this model it is possible to strive out the term structure of the probability of default just letting T vary. The main drawback of this model is that it allows for the occurence of the default only at the debt maturity T , without considering the possibility that τ < T when there could be a firm’s capital restructuration or firm reorganization. Therefore we should consider a model which allows a non zero probability of default also before T , as this is the case as we can observe by quotes of the Credit Default Swaps (CDS) for which the reference
For a formal demonstration the intersted reader can see at Hull et al. (2003). The credit spread or yield spread is defined as the difference between the rate of return of the risky bond and the on of the risk-free bond with the same maturity and same coupons rate.
9 8

CHAPTER 1. STRUCTURAL MODELS entity can experience default before the debt maturity10 .

10

10

For more explanation of the CDS see chapter four.

CHAPTER 1. STRUCTURAL MODELS

11

1.2
1.2.1

First Passage Models
The Black and Cox’s Model

The Black and Cox (1976) model extends the previous framework allowing for the time of default to be also before the maturity of the debt. In their model the default occurs when the process followed by the assets value V (t) hits from above a fixed exogenous barrier. For these reasons the model is the first of the class of the default models which are the so called First Time Passage Models. In their model Black and Cox assume a lognormal distribution for the assets value and that the shareholders receive a continous dividend payment proportional to the assets valueof the firm. Analogously to the the Merton model, under the risk-neutral probability the process of V follows a geometric browian motion defined by the following SDE

dV (t) = (r − q)V (t)dt + σV (t)dW (t)

(1.16)

where the definition for r, q, σ, W are the same previously seen in (1.1). Since also in this model the interest rate r is still constant and deterministic, hence also the Black and Cox (1976) model does not include the interest rate risk. The barrier value, which determines the default everytime it is reached from above by the assets value, is completely determinited by the variable C1 (t) that is fixed exogenously and dipendent with both the passing time t and the debt maturity T , while in the Merton model the latter one was the only critical variable for the default determination. Such a barrier to trigger the default represents the level of the safety covenants imposed in the contract by the bondholders, through which the latters may ask for a reorganization or impose the firm to file for bankruptcy when the firm is in a very bad both economic and financial condition, that is when in the model the assets value hits the barrier. The level

CHAPTER 1. STRUCTURAL MODELS of the barrier C1 (t) is then a reasonable exponential function of the time11 :

12

C1 (t) = C exp(−γ(T − t))

(1.17)

where: • C is the value of the reorganized firm at the maturity T which value should be lower or equal than the nominal of the debt L • γ is implied as discount factor and is to be applied to the barrier value at the maturity T , hence it has a role similar to the one of the risk free rate r to discount the future cash amounts • C exp(−γ(T − t)) ≤ L exp(−r(T − t)) = P (t, T )L In particular Black and Cox assume a precise form for the barrier , C exp(−γ(T − t)) = ρP (t, T )L with the costant 0 ≤ ρ ≤ 1. Thereafter the time of default is defined as following:

τ = inf(t > 0 : V (t) ≤ C(t))

(1.18)

When the default occurs, we can consider the following relations for the payoff D(T, V (T )) of the debt with maturity T and which depends on the assets value, for the net equity value as a function of the time t and finally for the assets value V (t) when respectively either we reach the maturity without default before or eventually the default event is verified
The use of an exponential function form is adeguated since the expected value of the debt also assume such a functional form.
11

CHAPTER 1. STRUCTURAL MODELS before the date of the debt maturity:

13

D(T, V (T )) = min(L, V (T )) S(T, V (T )) = max(V (T ) − L, 0) D(t, C1 (t)) = C exp(−γ(T − t)) S(t, C1 (t)) = 0

(1.19) (1.20) (1.21) (1.22)

The first two relations replicates the ones present also in Merton’s framework in case the default can realize only at the maturity T ; whereas the last two relations define the payoff when the barrier is touched from above at time t, having the default before the maturity. In order to estimate the actual value of both the payoffs it is necessary to evaluate the risk neutral ditribution of the assets assets conditioning on its present value. Under Black and Cox assumptions as in Merton we obtain a lognormal distribution for the process of V (t) adding an absorbing barrier represented by the safety covenant barrier12 . In this context we may apply the approach developed in Cox and Ross (1976) to attack the barrier option pricing problem, hence Black and Cox obtain a closed formula for the expected present value of the debt D(t). Furthermore in this model the distribution of the risk neutral probability of default before τ is therefore:
V ln( C1(t)) ) + (r − q + 0.5σ 2 )(τ − t) (τ √ σ τ −t 1−(2−(r−q−γ)/σ 2

Pr(τ ≤ T ) =1 − Φ + Φ

V (t) C1 (t)

V 2 ln(C1 (t)) − ln( C1(t)) ) + (r − q + 0.5σ 2 )(τ − t) (τ √ σ τ −t

(1.23)

Black and Cox introduce also the possibility for the firm to have a debt structure with different seniority 13 . Under this context, after having computed the total value of the debt,
For an analytical formulation of the barrier and the explicit solution to the pricing problem for corporate bond the reader can refer to Black and Cox (1976) 13 The seniority is defined as the order of repayment in case of firm bankruptcy. The senior debt is the saftiest, while the junior debt is repayed only after all the other debts are satisfied hence it is the riskiest
12

CHAPTER 1. STRUCTURAL MODELS

14

we find the value of the senior debt without considering the presence of the junior debt, whose value is then computed as the difference between the the total and the senior debt. Despite the hypothesis of subordination is valid for CDOs product and for securitized products, it is not respected rigorously during the the bankruptcy procedures. Then should be necessary to consider a recovery rate for the debt which is indipendent with respect to the barrier value, whilst this is somehow correlated with seniority of the debt issued by the firm. The model allows for a default event to happen before the maturity, thus accounting for the contractual strenghts of the bondholders and as well as for the necessity of an optimal reorganization of the firm run by the shareholders against the present unefficient management. Notwithstanding such extension, this model is still based on constant and deterministic interest rate. Furthermore the model is not even realistic when we consider the presence of corporate bonds with different seniority to which is not completely applied the strict absolute priority14 in case a default is verified and the firm is then reorganized.

class of debt 14 The strict absolute priority principle is defined as the rule mainly followed by the USA courts when they settle on how the creditors issues should be fullfill during a bankruptcy or a reorganization procedure. The interested reader could refer to Eberhart et al. (1990) which deals with this subject.

CHAPTER 1. STRUCTURAL MODELS

15

1.2.2

Longstaff and Schwartz’s Model

In their framework Longstaff and Schwartz introduce two main extensions with respect to the models we have analyzed so far: the credit risk and the interest risk are now considered together and is assumed that deviations from the strict absolute priority are allowed. In order to introduce their model in the framework first proposed by Merton (1974) and later extended by Black and Cox (1976), they consider some assumptions somehow strongly linked with the ones present in the models previuosly considered15 . In particular in this section we will deal only with some assumption strictly necessary for an analytical presentation of the model, staring the attention at the features which differentiate this model with respect to the previous framework. For the first assumption, as in Merton (1974), the assets value V follows a geometric brownian motion defined by the SDE:

dV (t) = µV (t)dt + σV (t)dZ1 (t)

(1.24)

The second assumption states that instantaneous risk free rate r follows, as in Vasicek (1977), a mean reverting stochastic process defined by the SDE:

dr(t) = (ζ − βr(t))dt + ηdZ2 (t)

(1.25)

where ζ, β, η are costants, Z2 is a standard brownian motion such that dZ1 = ρdtdZ2 , with ρdt istantaneous correlation coefficient between the two motions Z1 (t) and Z2 (t). To model the interest rate is used the Vasicek model because, even if it could bring the presence of negative interest rates, with an adeguate choice of the parameters for the which push the probability of negative interest rate very close to zero. The latter allow to get a postive expected value of r(t), thus obtaining a coherent analysis of its influence over the spread. Furthermore from this choice we get formulas which are less analytically
15 For a complete discussion of the arguments of this model the reader could refer to Longstaff and Schwartz (1995)

CHAPTER 1. STRUCTURAL MODELS

16

complex with respect to what we would have get if we had chosen a model generally applied for r(t), such that the model of Cox et al. (1985). As in the previous models and in accordance to Modigliani and Miller (1958), the capital structure is assumed stationary and can be composed by a variety of liabilities, including debt contracts with coupon with different rates, seniority and maturity. The default occurs when the assets value reach the level of the barrier K < V (0), which is exogenous, deterministic and constant. In the case a firm experiences a default event restricted for a single debt instrument (i.e. the firm misses to meet its obbligations which arise from that instrument), then such a situation impose the default extended to the firm and hence to all the others issued debt instruments not already matured. The use of a constant barrier is justified by the fact that in their model K influences the default model only through the relation V (t)/K with the assets value and this choice is also consistent with the fact the insolvency could be either flow-based or stock-based16 . If the default occurs before the maturity, the debt holders receive a payoff given by a prespecified and constant fraction 1 − w of the nominal value of the debt; this fraction is also called recovery rate. Hence w ∈ (0, 1) correspond to the percentage constant loss over the debt when the firm is reorganized. Assume

D(r, T ) = exp(A(T ) − B(T )r)

(1.26)

to be the value of a risk free ZCB17 in accordance to the Vasicek (1977)’s model. We consider P (V, r, T ) as the value of a risky ZCB with maturity T and nominal value one. Its payoff is: 1 − wIτ ≤T
The interested reader could refer to Wruck (1990) and Kim et al. (1992) for a formal definition of this distinction. 17 The interested reader could look at Longstaff and Schwartz (1995) and Vasicek (1977) for furher details.
16

CHAPTER 1. STRUCTURAL MODELS

17

with I indicator function and τ first passage time over the barrier. Given X = V (t)/K, as prooved by Longstaff and Schwartz (1995) we get:

P (X, r, T ) = D(r, T ) − wD(r, T )Q(X, r, T )

(1.27)

where Q(X, r, T ) is equal to the risk neutral probability of default computed as the solution of a recursive system with n variables which converge to an unique value for n = 20018 . Thus the bond value depends on the assets value and the barrier value only through the ratio V (t)/K, which for this reason could be considered as a default risk measure and as a proxy the rating of the firm. We can observe how the bond value is driven by three main components: its default free value D(r, T ); the present value of the loss over the bond in case of default, wD(r, T ); the probability of default Q(X, r, T ). The bond value depends on the choice of the parameters which govern the dynamics of the assets value, µ σ, and the risk free rate, ζ, β, η. The price P (X, r, T ) is a function of X, r , T ; is increasing in K and decreasing in other two components. With a capital structure with several debt instruments, the main fact that the default depends only on the common variable X, let us apply the additivity principle in the pricing of risky coupon bonds, rather through the composition of a hedging portfolio that mimics the bond payoff and risk and which contains some risky ZCBs. From the explicit formula for the solution of the risky ZCB’s value, reported above, we can also determine the credit spreads. At this point is quite important to underline that in the Longstaff and Schwartz (1995) model, differently from Merton (1974) and Black and Cox (1976), the spread term structure is coherent with empirical data. In particular we obtain that the term structure is such that: • it is monotonically increasing for the bonds with an high rating, that is with an high value for X; • it shows hump shaped curve for the bonds with low rating, that is with a low X;
18

See Longstaff and Schwartz (1995) for the analytical details.

CHAPTER 1. STRUCTURAL MODELS

18

• it shows different levels for different debt seniorities, that is for different values of w19 ; • it is a decreasing function of the interest rate r, which influences the drift of the process of V (t) and hence also the default probability; • it is an increasing function of the correlation coefficient ρ, in fact the volatility level of V depends also on the covariance with interest rate. Furthermore Longstaff and Schwartz (1995) find also an explicit solution for the value of the bond with not fixed interest rate. Although, this model extends the precedent framework, relaxing the assumptions made in the two models analyzed so far, it still shows some cons and it does not take into account some necessary extensions. In fact, this model allows to find out only approximated formulas for the default probability, and needs to be impletend with simulations; under this model can also happen that the liquidation value of the assets is higher than their own values, for instance the latter at the default time could be less than 1 − w multiplied by the debt nominal value; it does not solve the problem of obtaining zero short-term spread; it considers an exogenous threshold, that is not facing the optimization problem for tyhe capital structure. In their paper Wei and Guo (1997) show that such a model is by far difficult to be estimated and its performance is less accurate than the Merton’s model one, this happen when for the latter we consider a volatility that varies with time, as it has been proposed by Hull et al. (2003). Nevertheless, as addressed by Wei and Guo (1997), the difficult and less performant calibration of the model is mainly due to exogenously given recovery rate 1 − w, that is of the barrier level.

We could consider w as a proxy for the debt seniority. Thus, high levels for w imply a low value recovery rate, to which usually correspond a low level of seniority.

19

CHAPTER 1. STRUCTURAL MODELS

19

1.2.3

Leland and Toft’s Model

In their model, Leland and Toft (1996), examine the optimal capital structure and its influence on the debt value. In their analysis they consider the fact that the firm management can optimally determine the total value and the maturity for each debt instrument to be issued, evaluating the trade-off between agency costs, default costs and tax concessions for the debt. In their model the default is endogenously determine, in fact the barrier is defined in an endogenous way through considerations cencerning the capital optimization objective problem. Thus, both the debt value and spread level are influenced by the financing choices and, for this reason, they depend on the influence that the leverage level has over them. In such a model is not taken into account a stochastic process for the risk free interest rate, contrary to Longstaff and Schwartz (1995), inasmuch, as asserted in the Leland and Toft (1996)’s paper, some academics have shown that this assumption acquit a realitvely low variation in the spreads with respect to a model with a deterministic rate, while it complicates a lot the research for analytical formulas and cloesd formulas. In a previous paper, Leland (1994) had analyzed the same problem of optimizing the capital structure, resulting in a closed form solution for the value of risky long-term debt and the spread. In the formulation of his model, he assumed a debt maturity T , tending to infinity, which is incompatible with the possibility for companies to freely determine the optimal amount and maturity of each debt instrument issued from time to time. Leland and Toft (1996) deviate from this limiting assumption, analyzing the relationship between debt maturity and its price, then between the spread and the optimal amount of debt. They obtain a model consistent with the empirical debt maturity structure, according to the different effect of the trade-off between costs and benefits in the choice of debt maturity, then the choice to issue debt in the short term or long term. Assume a stationary debt structure, in which till default the firm issues a constant amount of debt at the parity, with maturity T from the issuance moment and with a nominal an-

CHAPTER 1. STRUCTURAL MODELS

20

nual rate equal to p = P/T , with P total nominal value of debt issued not yet matured, and that the same amount p of capital will be withdrawn when the previously issued bonds will be matured. Then for each time s, before the moment of default, the value of total debt not accrued will always be equal to P and with uniform distribution with respect to the maturity in the time interval (s, s + T ) . We assume that the assets value follows a geometric brownian motion, defined by the SDE dV (t) = (µ(V (t), t) − δ)V (t)dt + σV (t)dW (t) where the drift factor is composed by • µ(V (t), t) expected yield for V (t) which depends on the assets value and on the time, and which under the risk neutral measure is replaced by the constant risk-free rate r; • δ constant payout factor proportional to the value of the assets. The barrier is represented by the variable VB determined endogenously, according to the assumptions of the optimization of capital structure. In the event that it is not touched by the process V (t), debt holders receive the value of the barrier VB multiplied by the recovery rate ρ(t). Consider a bond with maturity t, par value p(t) and a coupon that (1.28)

pays a constant c(t). We put V = V (t) to simplify the notation in the following formulas. Suppose initially that the barrier is determined exogenously, then the dynamics of the value of the bond will be defined by the following process: c(t) r c(t) ] [1 r c(t) r

dB(V ; VB , t) =

+ exp(−rt)[p(t) −

− F (t)] + p(t)VB −

G(t) (1.29)

CHAPTER 1. STRUCTURAL MODELS where: V VB
−2a

21

F (t) = Φ(h1 (t)) + t Φ(h2 (t))

G(t) =
0

f (s)ds

V − ln( VB ) − (r − δ − 0.5σ 2 )t √ h1 (t) = σ t V − ln( VB ) + (r − δ − 0.5σ 2 )t √ h2 (t) = σ t

with Φ(•), the CDF of the Normal, f (s) and F (s), respectively, pdf (probability density function) and the CDF of the distribution of first passage time. Considering now the

set of bonds with different maturity, t in[0, T ], we have that the set of annual payments is given by the value (C + (P/T )) independent of t. Also for simplicity we assume that ρ(t) to be equal to a constant annual rate ρ/T for each t20 ; this implies that ρ = (1 − α) is the sum of all the recovery rates on all the bonds not yet matured, where α corresponds to the loss the firm would suffer in case of default, expressed as a fraction of the value of the assets. So we get:

T

D(V ; VB , T ) = t=0 dB(V ; VB , t)dt C C + (P − ) r r zσ T 1 √ − V VB 1 − exp(−rt) − G(T ) + exp(−rt)F (T ) rT
−a+z

=

+ (1 − α)VB −

C r

Φ(q1 (T ))q1 (T ) +

V VB

−a−z

Φ(q2 (T ))q2 (T ) (1.30)

Leland and Toft (1996) stated in the notes that in their framework we can use a different formulation for ρ(t), for example, by proposing a decaying exponential form.

20

CHAPTER 1. STRUCTURAL MODELS where: (r − δ − 0.5σ 2 )2 + 2rσ 2 )t √ q1 (t) = σ t V − ln( VB ) + ( (r − δ − 0.5σ 2 )2 + 2rσ 2 )t √ q2 (t) = σ t (r − δ − 0.5σ 2 )2 + 2rσ 2 z = σ2
V − ln( VB ) − (

22

Once determined the firm’s market value, v(V ; VB ), equals to the value of the assets plus the taxation benefits, the equity value is given by S(V ; VB , T ) = v(V ; VB )−D(V ; VB , T ). The endogenous equilibrium value for the barrier21 is obtained by maximizing S(V ; VB , T ) with respect to V , that is as a solution to ∂S(V ; VB , T ) |V =VB = 0 ∂V . Also from this model the probability distribution of actual default is given by
V − ln( V )−(µ−δ−0.5σ 2 ) B √ σ s V − ln( V )−(µ−δ−0.5σ 2 )s B √ σ s

Φ

V + exp (−2(µ − δ − 0.5σ 2 )) ln( VB )Φ

(1.31)

As shown by Leland and Toft (1996), in the empirical analysis, the probability of default depends mainly from the value of the drift µ, the volatility σ of the value of the assets, as well as the level of endogenous barrier VB . Moreover, the path of the term structure of credit spreads is increasing with respect to interest risk-free rate r, similar to what occurred in Longstaff and Schwartz (1995). For higher maturity we will have higher spreads, confirming the tendency of firms to issue more debt in the short term than long-term, as the first dramatically reduces agency costs. If cash flows are expressed as a function

of the value of assets V , then considering the ratios C/δV and (P/T )/∆V where ∆V is a proxy for cash flows, default probabilities and spreads can be expressed in terms of
21

For the explicit solution, please refer to Leland and Toft (1996).

CHAPTER 1. STRUCTURAL MODELS

23

these relationships. For this reason the model can be interpreted as a formalization of the traditional rating models, which are based on financial ratios equivalent to those described above.

Even in their model, however, the presence of spread remains virtually zero for short-term debt. This situation is due to the fact that the stochastic process that governs the value of the company, for reasonable levels of volatility, will rarely touch the optimum barrier in the short term, implying low probability of default in the short term.

CHAPTER 1. STRUCTURAL MODELS

24

1.2.4

Zhou’s Model

The model of Zhou (1997) develops and generalizes the jump model with binomial amplitude previously proposed by Mason and Bhattacharya (1981). To apply the model, the more classical assumptions of structural models are used: the invariance of the value of the company compared to its capital structure, according to Modigliani and Miller (1958); the simplifying assumption of a risk-free interest rate constant and the presence of a perfect market with continuous trading activities and the absence of arbitrage opportunities, which implies the existence of a risk-neutral measure Q. The process followed by the value of the assets has two stochastic components: a continuous diffusive and a discontinuous jump, where the amplitude of the jump follows a lognormal distribution. The first component represents the trend of the market value of the assets, determined by the flow of continuous and normal information. The second jumping component determines the effect of suddenly important information, which can also cause immediate collapse of the firm’s market value. We have, therefore, that the value of assets V (t) evolves according to the following SDE dV (t) = (µ − λν)dt + σdW1 (t) + (Π − 1)dY (t) V (t) where: • µ, λ, ν, σ are positive constants; • W1 is a standard brownian motion; • Y is a Poisson process with parameter λ; it is the specific or idiosyncratic component of the firm, and which is also indipendent from the systematic default component (i.e. the one triggered by the market);
2 • Π > 0 ∼ LogN orm(µπ , σπ ) is the amplitude of the jump sach that E[Π] = ν − 1 2 • ν = E[Π] − 1 = exp(µπ + 0.5σπ ) − 1

CHAPTER 1. STRUCTURAL MODELS • W1 , Y, Π are indipendent.

25

We observe a default when the process V (t) touches or falls below the constant barrier K. In this situation the default extends to all bonds and there begins a phase of reorganization of the company, where the bondholders receive a portion 1 − w(Xs ) of the par value at maturity T of the bond, with X =
V (t) , K

s = min(τ, T ) 22 and 1 − w(Xs ) recovery rate on

the bond is is not decreasing function in Xs , depending on the rating class of bonds and the value of the company. We set Xs = X to simplify the notation in the following expressions. Then, under

the above assumptions and given some constraint conditions, we obtain the value H of a generic credit risk derivative , dependent on X, as a solution, when it exists, to the following partial differential equation (PDE, in the rest of the thesis):

0.5σ 2 X 2 HXX + (r − λν)XHX − rH + λEt [H(XΠ, T ) − H(X, T )] − HT = 0 (1.32)

where HX and HXX rispectively are the first and the second derivative of H with respect to X. In the event that the contingent claim H considered is a bond, then we have that H = B must satisfy the PDE (1.28). In this approach the model of Merton (1974) for the value of assets is extended assuming the jumps in the process, thus solving the longstanding problem of zero spreads in the short term. Now we see that the default is no longer a predictable stoppig-time
23

,

in fact, the dynamic process of the value of the assets can present jumps which may not
The time of default τ is defined, as in precedence, as the first instant at which the barrier is crossed, that is: τ = inf{t > 0|V (t) ≤ K} . In structural models the concept of predictablity is referred to us as the ability for investors to observe the phenomenon that in this type of models is the default event, given the complete information on the value of the assets and the value of the barrier. In fact, one can determine the evolution of the process V (t), approaching or moving away from the barrier level, it determines the forecast for a default time to be more or less remote from the instant of observation. Therefore, we have that the estimated probability of default is made by continuously assessing the quantity, the process of the assets and the barrier, empirically detectable, checking from time to time any deviations from the predictions or noting any increasing in default likelihood due to the bad conditions of the company dectuable from the balance sheet. In this type of models are impossible any sudden default, which would lead to the realization of stoppig-time in the short term, with estimated probability almost zero. For a formal definition refer to Sch¨ nbucher (2003). o
23 22

CHAPTER 1. STRUCTURAL MODELS

26

have been foreseen before and which are triggered by a certain jump process. Therefore, we have that the value of the assets evolves according to a diffusion process with jumps, jump-diffusion process, where the jumps are leading to periodic shocks in firm value. This implies the possibility to observe instantaneous and sudden default event, thus to get instantaneous positive spreads and spreads high even for companies which are not in an advanced state of financial distress.

While in the model of Merton (1974) is stated that the yield curve for the spread starts from zero and it is monotonically increasing, the model of Zhou (1997) admits that this can take several forms: flat, decreasing and hump-shaped for any financial status of companies. In addition, we also consider a recovery rate modeled endogenously and which depends on the assets value at default, unlike most of the structural models in which it is a constant value at default, except in the model of Merton (1974), but where the default can occur only at the maturity of the debt. Zhou considered two approaches: a simplified one in which the default occurs only at maturity T of the only instrument of debt issued and the recovery rate is a linear function of X; in the second, more general, is admitted the possibility of default to occur at any time before the maturity and w(X) to be any continuous function. For the first he derives a closed formula, while for the second Monte Carlo simulations are needed.

Semplified Approach

Given the bond with an unitary nominal value and the indicator

function I, we have that the price of the bond will be:

B(X, T ) = exp(−rT )E Q [IXT >1 + (1 − w(XT ))IXT ≤1 ]
Q = exp(−rT ) − exp(−rT )E Q [w(XT |XT ≤ 1]FT (1|X)

(1.33)

CHAPTER 1. STRUCTURAL MODELS with w(X) = w0 − w1 X, linear function of X, we then obtain
Q B(X, T ) = exp(−rT )1 − w0 FT (1|X) ∞

27

+w1 X i=0 exp(−λT )(λT )i 2 exp(µi + 0.5σi ) i!
2 ln(X) + µi + σi σi

1−Φ

(1.34)

with:

µi = r − 0.5σ 2 − λν + iµπ σi =
2 σ 2 T + i!σπ

Q and the probability of default under Q conditioned on the current value of X, FT (1|X) =

P rob(XT ≤ 1|X)

24

. Zhou also obtains the value of the bond in case we require via w

a constraint for limited responsability for the bond holders, with w(X) = min(0, w0 − w1 X). It is noted however that this constraint is not crucial, since the probability of obtaining negative value of 1 − w is very low and does not affect much the value of the spreads.

Generalized Approach time

Now we consider that the default is defined by first-passage

τ = inf(t|Xt ≤ 1, t ≥ 0)

(1.35)

where the payoff for the bondholders will be 1 − w(Xτ ) for τ ≤ T . Xτ will be dependent on a particular distribution of τ , in contrast to Longstaff and Schwartz (1995) where X assumes the value 1. The value of the bond that solves the PDE (1.28) will be:

B(X, T ) = exp(−rT ) − exp(−rT )E Q [w(Xτ )|Iτ ≤T ]
24

(1.36)

Refer to Zhou (1997) for the formulation and demonstration.

CHAPTER 1. STRUCTURAL MODELS Then for X > 1: n 28

B(X, T ) = exp(−rT ) − exp(−rT ) lim

n→∞

E Q [w(Xt∗i )|Ωi ]Qi i=1 (1.37)

where: i T n Xt∗i > 1 ∀j < 1

ti =

Ωi = Xt∗i ≤ 1 Qi = P rob(Ωi ) Xt∗0 = X

Xt∗i = Xti−1 exp(xi + yi + πi ) i = 1, . . . , n

with xi , yi , πi indipendent and with the following distributions: (r − 0.5σ 2 − λν)T σ 2 T , ) n n

xi = ∼ N (

(1.38) (1.39) (1.40)

2 πi = ∼ N (µπ , σπ    1 λT  n yi =   0 1 − λT  n

In this case there are no closed-form formulas, while to approximate the value of the bond we must carry out some Monte Carlo simulations. The risk arising from the jump of process leads to an increase in spreads, especially for bonds with low maturity holding constant the volatility process of the assets value. Zhou (1997) notes that for high values of the jump intensity λ and lower values of σπ , you have more continuity in V (t) associated with low spreads for short-term bonds and higher spreads for long-term bonds. This phenomenon is due to the relationship between the process of jumping and the probabilities of default which decrease with X. Zhou shows

CHAPTER 1. STRUCTURAL MODELS

29

that the jump process is more likely to cause default in the short term than in the long term compared to a diffusion process. In the paper Zhou (1997) presents a model that considers the Vasicek (1977)’s stochastic process for the risk-free interest rate. Although there are numerous possible extensions to the model, this represents a simplified framework to model the probability of default and spreads, when you consider the possibility that there may be sudden and otherwise unpredictable defaults, according to a common structural model with a conventional diffusion process for the stochastic firm value. It is therefore a model capable of capturing non-systematic shocks to the value of the company and to obtain non-zero spread in the short-term, unlike what happens for other structural models.

CHAPTER 1. STRUCTURAL MODELS

30

1.2.5

Random Threshold Model

The first to introduce a stochastic model that includes a barrier and a Vasicek dynamic for the interest rate were Nielsen et al. (1993). Later this model was generalized by Sa´ a Requejo and Santa-Clara (1999) admitting any choice for the dynamics of the interest rate. This framework was then revised in Hsu et al. (2004). In the latter it is propose a model in which the value of the company without default V (t) and the value of the barrier K(t) affect the probability of default only through their relationship, not imposing an analysis of the capital structure with which the firm is financed. This ratio is defined as an indicator of the solvibility of the firm (solvency ratio) in respect of the commitments with the bondholders. In this approach the authors consider that the value of the barrier has a stochastic dynamic which is influenced by shocks related to the market value of assets and interest rate trends. So the two processes of the firm’s market value V (t) and the barrier K(t) determine, trough their relationship, the value of corporate bonds, the values of spreads and the probability of default. In their model the barrier K(t) is defined as the value of the company in case of bankruptcy25 . Are then analyzed the equilibrium conditions of the default, rather than, as in other structural models, the causes that lead to financial difficulties. In this context, the bankruptcy code, the control of corporate governance and its mechanisms must be adequate and functional for the market, given the capital structure and actual governance, it should be able to efficiently assess the value of the company compared with the value after a reorganization. For these reasons the value of the barrier follows a stochastic process which covariates with V , rather than being deterministic or constant, reflecting both the value of the commitments and the effect of disputes between shareholders and creditors. In their model the firm value and the value of the barrier follow the following dynamics under the
Hsu et al. (2004) specify that this value depends on what happens in case of default. Then K can be either: the liquidation value of assets or the value of the recapitalized firm which continues its business.
25

CHAPTER 1. STRUCTURAL MODELS martingale or risk neutral measure Q:

31

dV (t) = [r(t) − δe (t, V, K, r) − δd (t, V, K, r)] dt + γv dZv (t) + γr dZr (t)(1.41) V (t) dK(t) = [r(t) − δe (t, V, K, r) − δd (t, V, K, r)] dt + βv dZv (t) + βr dZr (t)(1.42) K(t) where: • δe (t, V, K, r), δd (t, V, K, r) represent the pay-out rate respectively to shareholders and to bondholders; • Zv (t), Zr (t) are Brownian motions expressing shocks, respectively, relative to the value of the fundamentals V (t) and the level of risk-free interest rate; • instantaneous correlation between the Brownian motions is equal to ρrv dt • γv , γr , βv , βr are their respective loads to the erratic part of the Brownian motions. The barrier is constructed such that if the market is efficient, the default will occur the first time that the process V (t) crosses the barrier K(t) from above. As a proxy for K(t) we can use a fraction (1 − w) of the assets value 26 . To obtain a model for default that does not depend directly on the structure of the firm’s
V (t) capital, Hsu et al. (2004) choose to model the log-solvency ratio X(t) = log( K(t) ). X(t)

evolves according to a Brownian motion defined as follows:

dX(t) = µx dt + σx dZx (t)
26

(1.43)

For the formal specification of the value of K(t), see Hsu et al. (2004).

CHAPTER 1. STRUCTURAL MODELS where:

32

(σx dZx )2 = [(γr − βr )2 + (γv − βv )2 + 2ρrv (γr − βr )(γv − βv )]dt
2 2 µx = 0.5(σk − σv ) 2 2 2 σk = βr + βv + 2ρrv βr βv 2 2 2 σv = γr + γv + 2ρrv γr γv

corr < dZx , dZr > = ρxr dt =

ρrv (γv − βv ) − (γr − βr ) dt σx

The generalized SDE for the risk-free interest rate is as follows:

dr(t) = µr (r, t)dt + σr (r, t)dZr (t)

According to the specification of a model for r, we can obtain closed-form formulas or analytical approximations for the pricing of coupon bonds. The default time is τ = inf{t : X = 0} simultaneously for all debt instruments issued and not expired. The bondholders receive a fraction (1 − w) of the value of an equivalent risk-free bond 27 , according to the so-called principle of recovery treasury. The recovery rate (1−w) depends on the seniority of the specific bond held by the investor. In this case, then we have that for a coupon bond is valid the additivity principle28 , will therefore be sufficient to determine the price of individual corporate ZCB to get the price of corporate bond coupons. Then the debt of the company which is not yet expiered can be considerate as a portfolio of ZCBs with imposing the same date of default. Furthermore, the price of each coupon bond will be calculated individually, regardless of the specification of the firm’s capital structure. To qualify for this pricing is needed the specification of the term structure of interest rates and the probability of first passage time τ .
With the same maturity and same nominal value of corporate bonds. According to the additivity principle the value of a coupon bond corresponds to the value of a replication portfolio composed of ZCBs, and its value is the sum of the ZCBs prices.
28 27

CHAPTER 1. STRUCTURAL MODELS

33

For simplicity Hsu et al. (2004) take as numeraire the price in t of a ZCB risk-free P (t, T ) with maturity T . Then they consider as a probability measure QT , called Forward Measure. Under this measure the process of log-solvency rate is as follows:

dX(t) = (µx + ρxr σx s(t, T ))dt + σx dZx (t)

with Zx Brownian motion under QT and s(t, T ) volatility of P (t, T ) adjusted for interest rate risk. Then the price of a ZCB corporate under the forward martingale measure is given by the following equation:
T

C(t, T ) = P (t, T )(1 − wEtQ [Iτ ≤ T ]) = = P (t, T )(1 − wΠ(t, T ))

(1.44) (1.45)

where Π(t, T ) is the probability that there is default between t and T , defined forward default probability or risk-adjusted default probability. Π(t, T ) can be calculated with some simulations, or, with appropriate restrictions for certain parameters of the model, we can obtain closed-form formulas or formulas with analytical approximation. In particular, Hsu et al. (2004) showed that if: • ρxr = 0, we can find closed-form formulas given any dynamics of r; • s(t, T ) is a deterministic function of the time29 , we obtain analytical approximation. Following its definition, the spread is: 1 P (t, T ) 1 1 ln( )= ln( ) T −t C(t, T ) T −t 1 − wΠ(t, T )

y(t, T ) =

The spread is increasing in w and in Π(t, T ), and then decreasing with respect to seniority and increasing with respect to the risk of default. In their paper they also show the trend of the spread in relation to other variables.
29

As it happens in model of Vasicek (1977) and in the other models for the interest rates.

CHAPTER 1. STRUCTURAL MODELS

34

• For low initial values of leverage X we get a curve hump shaped for the term structure, while for high values a monotonically increasing curve. • With the use of a stochastic interest rate we note higher spreads. • The spreads are increasing with respect to ρxr . In particular, one can compare the effects on the spread for non-cyclical companies, with ρxr < 0, and cyclical business, with ρxr > 0, which belong to the same rating. • The spread is increasing with respect to the volatility σx . • Coherently with what stated and demonstrated by Longstaff and Schwartz (1995), the spread narrows as the rate r grows, but this time this relation is due to the fact that the process of K may be more sensitive compared to the process V to the shocks caused by the interest rate, that is βr > γr . This model, unlike those with a constant barrier, where the drift of the solvency rate is positive, show higher expected probability of default and higher spreads for corporate bonds, in accordance with what is the empirical evidence. Another strong perk of this model is that it admits that the rating of the firms may vary, having the the credit merit reduced as to the conditional probability of default decreses, while it is constant in the reduced form models. So you can see a hump in the curve for the term structure of spreads for firms with a low level of X, associated to the decreasing conditional probabilities of default. This model is suitable to capture adequately the default of a single firm.

The reduced form models are more appropriate with respect to this model to analyze the asset swap spread or the spread of a portfolio of bonds belonging to the same rating class. In addition, like all the structural models considered previously, it shows that spreads tend to zero for shorter maturities. Empirical evidence shows that this does not happen. As observed by Duffie and Lando (2001), this problem is coming from having assumed a market where there is perfect information of the value of the assets and liabilities among investors, and thus balance sheets that are transparent and correct.

Chapter 2 Modelli reduced form
The reduced form models or intensity models, assume that the default is exogenously determined by a Poisson-type process governed by an intensity λ(t), jump, or a unit increase of the stochastic process underlying the process of Poisson, described in (2.1); we assume, therefore, that the default occurs the instant when we observe the first jump of a poisson process. Depending on the choice made for the intensity the models can be characterized by homogeneous or non-homogeneous processes of Poisson. For instance, with respect to the above statment should be noted that although most of the reduced form models admit the existence of an intensity process for default, there are some who do not admit it 1 . These fall into the category of reduced form models, but can not be defined intensity models, while the latter is considered for most of the reduced form models.

Among the reduced form models we can also distinquish four types of them: basic models, where the default process is independent of the majority of economic factors or even independent from changes in the underlying; models that are based on the rating of the Bonds and their transition probabilities from one class to another, the so-called ratingbased models; some hybrid models that consider some aspects of structural models, in particular the performance of the value of the company; the market models that parallel
See as an example of reduced form model that does not admit an intensity, the model of Brody et al. (2005).
1

35

CHAPTER 2. MODELLI REDUCED FORM

36

to those developed for the pricing of derivatives on interest rates and stocks, seek to build models and transparent standards for the pricing of derivatives on credit risk.

As stated above, the default in these models is treated as a sudden event, and sometimes independent of economic events. In this approach we can model the default time as the time of the first jump of a Poisson-type process with a particular form for the intensity. The time that elapses between the instant of observation or of evaluation and the time of default, then, is a random variable with exponential distribution with parameter equal to the value of the intensity of the jump process.

2.1

Approach With An Homogenous Poisson Process

In a first approach to the model we consider a Poisson process Nt with constant intensity, λ(t) = λ > 0. If we consider an ordered series of stopping-times or jump times τ1 , τ2 , ..., τn , ..., the unitary Poisson process of jump can be expressed by the following stochastic process:


Nt = i=1 Iτi ≤t

(2.1)

where I is an indicator function, N (0) = 0 and the increments are stationary and indipendent, such that for 0 ≤ s ≤ t: exp(λ(t − s))(λ(t − s))k k!

P (Nt − Ns = k) =

(2.2)

where the increment Nt − Ns ∼ Po(λ(t − s)). Furthermore, for such a Poisson process we have that the time lags between the jumps are i.i.d. random variables with, τj − τi ∼ EXP(λ). We set that the instant of default τ is equal to time of of the first jump τ1 ∼ EXP(λ), with

CHAPTER 2. MODELLI REDUCED FORM τ1 = {t ∈
+

37

|Nt > 0}. From this we obtain that the probability of survival up to t is P (τ > t) = e−λt

(2.3)

Which gives that the probability of default in a infinitesimal interval [t, t+dt), conditioned by the fact that there has been no default up to time t is P (τ ∈ [t, t + dt) ∩ τ ≥ t) P (τ > t) P (τ > t) − P (τ > t + dt) = P (τ > t) exp(−λt) − exp(−λ(t + dt)) = exp(−λt) (2.4)

P (τ ∈ [t, t + dt)|τ ≥ t) =

= λdt

The factor lambda is also called hazard rate. Its generalized form is of the form h(t, T ), depending on the maturity T and on the instant t of evaluation. The conclusion therefore is that in this case this function is equal to the constant λ. For the properties of the exponential distribution we have that the expected time of default is 1/λ and variance 1/λ2 and that the probability of two jumps, that is two defaults, at the same point in time t is null. From (2.3) we observe that in the probability of survival the role of the intensity is comparable to that performed by the interest rate in the discount factors. For these reasons, in reduced form models default probabilities can be considered such as discount factors and therefore the intensities of default as credit spreads. This basic framework for the reduced form models, for example, allows us to use the binomial tree model of Litterman and Iben (1991) to estimate the probability of default by the quoted credit default swaps and then determine the intensity calibrated to the market prices for CDS spreads. The assumption of a constant intensity, however, does not allow to model a realistic and flexible term structure of spreads as it is observed on the market. In fact, the model considered in this section for h(t, T ) implies a constant term structure of spreads that

CHAPTER 2. MODELLI REDUCED FORM does not vary neither with t nor with T , hence a flat constant term structure.

38

CHAPTER 2. MODELLI REDUCED FORM

39

2.2

Approach With a Non-Homogenous Poisson Process

A possible solution to obtain a flexible model that can be calibrated to the term structure of the credit spreads is the assumption of an intensity λ(t) as a function of time t. In this way, the process of default is defined by the first jump of a Poisson process not homogenous over time. We assume λ(t) to be positive and define the hazard function or the cumulative hazard rate or cumulative intensity as: t Γ(t) =
0

λ(s)ds

Setting M (t) as a standard Poisson process with unitary intensity, we define the nonhomogeneous Poisson process in time with unit jump as:

Nt = MΓ(t)

(2.5)

In other words, a non-homogeneous Poisson process is equivalent to a Poisson process with standard time ”distorted” by the cumulative intensity of Γ(t); thereafter the increments of Nt are independent as in the model with constant intensity, but not identically distributed, since their distribution depends on Γ(t), which varies over time. For (2.5), we have that the instant τ of the first jump of Nt corresponds to the time Γ(τ ) of the first jump of Mt . It is assumed that the time lag between the jumps of Mt , with unit intensity, is distributed as a standard exponential ξ, then we have:

Γ(τ ) = ξ ∼ EXP(1)

from which, with Γ(t) invertible, we obtain:

τ = Γ−1 (ξ)

CHAPTER 2. MODELLI REDUCED FORM From this we deduce that the probability of survive till t is:

40

P (τ > t) = P (Γ(τ ) > Γ(t)) = P (EXP(1) > Γ(t)) = e−Γ(t) = e− t 0

λ(s)ds

(2.6)

From which the probability of default in a infinitesimal interval [t, t + dt) conditioned on the survival up to t, similarly to (2.4), is: exp(− t 0

P (τ ∈ [t, t + dt)|τ ≥ t) =

λ(s)ds) − exp(− exp(− t 0

t+dt 0

λ(s)ds) (2.7)

λ(s)ds)

= λ(t)dt

The conclusion therefore is that the hazard rate h(t, T ) = λ(T ) only depends on the maturity of T , thus admitting a curve that is not flat for credit spreads, which remains unchanged with respect to time t of observation. Still, like the previous approach, we observe that the probability of survival can be considered as a discount factor, where the cumulative intensity once again plays the role of discount rate and therefore can be considered a credit spread. By a suitable choice of

λ(t), we can obtain any desired shape for the term curve of spreads. One negative aspect of the model lies in the fact that the standard exponential random variable ξ, with which is modeled the process of default, represents an exogenous source of uncertainty, which is independent of any observable variable on the market, such as the rate of interest, thus making the model incomplete with respect to information available to investors. Also the use of a deterministic function of the intensity does not consider the volatility of credit spreads.

CHAPTER 2. MODELLI REDUCED FORM

41

2.3

Approach with a Cox’s Process

A possible generalization of the non-homogeneous Poisson process with stochastic intensity is given by Cox’s process. Considering the stochastic intensity λ(t) ≥ 0, the filtration {Gt }t≥0 it generates and which corresponds to the information on trends of the deafultfree market, will be given by the sequence of σ-algebras Gt = σ{λs : 0 ≤ s ≤ t}. Given this filtration, the Cox process conditioned to the flow of updated information available, Gt , can be seen as a non-homogeneous Poisson process with stochastic intensity λ(t). For this reason, to the Cox process can be applied all the results obtained in the case of a time-dependent intensity, provided we reason by conditioning to the information available. The default will occur, as usual, in the instant of the first jump: having two elements of uncertainty, the process of the intensity and the jump time, in fact the process is also called doubly stochastic Cox process. As mentioned above, Nt is a Cox process if, given a standard Poisson process Mt independent of the stochastic process of the intensity, it satisfies the relation

Nt = M

t 0

λ(s)ds

(2.8)

; it is therefore a Poisson process with a random change of time conditional on Gt . For this process it holds that: 1 ( k! t t s

P (Nt − Ns = k|Gt ) = E

λ(u)du)k e− s λ(u)du

(2.9)

With the hazard function:
T

Λ(T ) =
0

λ(s)ds

(2.10)

which is a random variable. Then given the standard exponential random variable ξ, the time of default can be expressed by

τ = Λ−1 (ξ)

(2.11)

CHAPTER 2. MODELLI REDUCED FORM

42

Applying the results seen for the previous approach in chapter (2.2), this time condtioning on Gt , we get for s > t, τ > t:

P (τ ≥ s) = P (Λ(τ ) ≥ Λ(s)) = P (ξ ≥ Λ(s)) = E [P (ξ ≥ Λ(s))|Gt ] = E e− s 0

λ(u)du

(2.12)

and P (τ ∈ [t, t + dt)|τ > t, Gt ) = λ(t)dt Assume that λ(t) is a sthocastic process described by the SDE (2.13)

λ(t) = µ(Xt )dt + σ(Xt )dW (t)

(2.14)

with µ, σ conveniently chosen so that λ(t) is positive and Xt is the process of the economy state variables, but without including also a variable which represents the series of default realizations, for instance the jump times of the process Nt .

The models that are based on the framework of a Cox process for modelling the time of default, base their effectiveness on the fact that, considering the conditional probabilities, not all the information is needed to be known, i.e. the one which also contains the information about the realizations of past defaults is not compoulsary for the estimates. It is sufficient to know the evolution of state variables, which determine the realization of λ(t), in order to estimate the probability of default and make the pricing without having to observe the realizations of the process Nt . In synthesis, we obtain that, through the use of conditional expected values, the probability depends only on the information available to investors, dynamically represented by the filtration {Gt }t≥0 .

Now, following Lando (2004), it is possible to show how it is suffcient enough to know

CHAPTER 2. MODELLI REDUCED FORM

43

such a reduced information, rather than the complete evolution of information, for the pricing of contingent claims in a non-default-free framework. Consider an economy arbitrage-free defined by the probabilistic space (Ω, F, Q) with Q martingale measure, and with F = d Ft being the complete information. Still assume Xt , with values in t≥0 , to be the process of state variables of the economy and the stochastic process for the

intensity to be a function λ(Xt ), non negative and measurable with respect to the filtration {Gt }t≥0 generated by the process Xt . Defined by {Ht }t≥0 the filtration generated by process of Cox Nt , we have that Ft = Gt ∪ Ht . Then, we have that for s > t, s 0

P (τ > s|Gt ) = P (Iτ >s |Gt ) = E e− = e− t 0

λ(Xu )du

|Gt s t

(2.15) λ(Xu )du

λ(Xu )du

E e−

|Gt

(2.16)

; while for s = t, t 0

P (τ > t|Gt ) = P (Iτ >t |Gt ) = e−

λ(Xu )du

(2.17)

. Given Z ∈ F such that E | Z |< ∞. Then can be proved that there exists a random variable Yt adapted to the filtration {Gt } such that

Iτ >t E [Z|Ft ] = Iτ >t Yt = Iτ >t E [ZIτ >t |Gt ] E [Iτ >t |Gt ] (2.18)

. From this we get that dynamic evolution of the default probability, for s = T > t, is E [Iτ >T |Ft ] E [Iτ >t |Gt ]
T t

P (τ > T |Ft ) = Iτ >t

= Iτ >t E e−

λ(Xu )du

|Gt

(2.19)

CHAPTER 2. MODELLI REDUCED FORM Finally from this can be shown that t 44

St = Nt −
0

λ(Xu )Iτ >u du

(2.20)

it is a martingale with respect to the information G.

With the martingale property and with the only available information about the state of the economy we can make the pricing of defaultable ZCB, the contingent claims involving a pay-off with either a payment only at the maturity, either with continous payments until the default or until the maturity either a payment exactly at the moment of default; using combinations of these we can manage to price more complicated instruments dependent on defaultable assets

CHAPTER 2. MODELLI REDUCED FORM

45

2.4

Bond and Spread Valuation

Now we present some formulas for the pricing of defaultable bonds 2 , for the value of some contingent claim with basic payoffs3 and for spreads.

Deterministic Hazard Function
We initially consider the case of non-homogeneous poisson process with deterministic intensity. In this case we assume that the default depends on the time of the first jump of the process Nt as in the above equation (2.5). Let P (0, T ) be the price at t = 0 for a unit risk-free ZCB with maturity T . Assuming that the process of the risk-free interest rate r(t) is independent of Nt and having a recovery rate of zero, then the price of a corporate unit ZCB B(0, T ) at t = 0 will be:
T

B(0, T ) = E exp(−
0 T

r(s)ds)INT =0 r(s)ds) E [INT =0 ]
0 T

= E exp(− = P (0, T ) exp(−

λ(s)ds)
0

(2.21)

Denote by X the unit payoff of a contingent claim. Assume that the payments provided by the structure of the contingent claim occur in intervals of width ∆k = Tk+1 − Tk , which corresponds to discrete variables that can be considered constant or to vary with the parameter k. In the event of experience a default in the time interval [Tk , Tk+1 ], the value at t = 0 of X with unit payoff at the end of the
We define defaultable bonds or corporate bonds, the bonds issued by firms, which are differentiate from the risk-free bonds, as they are subject to the risk of issuer’s default. 3 For the type of payoffs considered, see below in the paragraph.
2

CHAPTER 2. MODELLI REDUCED FORM period, Tk+1 , is

46

X(0, Tk , Tk+1 ) = P (0, Tk+1 )E INTk =0 − INTk+1 =0
Tk Tk+1

(2.22) λ(s)ds))
0 Tk+1

= P (0, Tk+1 )(exp(−
0 Tk

λ(s)ds) exp(− λ(s)ds))(1 − exp(−
0

= P (0, Tk+1 )(exp(−

λ(s)ds))
Tk

So if we consider the following positions: Tk = T and Tk+1 = T + ∆t, we obtain the following payoff in case of default at time T : X(0, T, T + ∆t) = ∆t→0 ∆t lim B(0, T )λ(T ) = X(0, T ) (2.23)

From the above, we have obtained that the credit spread is given by the average value of the hazard function, that is 1 T −t
T

λ(s)ds t (2.24)

Hence we observe that this value depends only on the time t. In fact, for a future date s > t, the value of the spread is already defined in t by the intensity λ(t), determined by calibrating the hazard function the at initial time t. As noted in section (2.2), we obtain a term curve for the spread deterministic and quite regular, which is a version that is neither realistic nor consistent with what is observed by the trend of prices of corporate bonds and CDSs. From these observations it is assumed most appropriate a model that considers a stochastic intensity, thus involving a flexible stochastic trend for the term structure of spreads.

Cox’s Model
In the framework of Cox are used iterated conditional expected values to obtain the prices of different types of contingent claim. We now present briefly the results obtained for

CHAPTER 2. MODELLI REDUCED FORM

47

the price of contingent claims and ZCB with generic payoffs, respectively, X(T ), g(t) = X(t)Iτ >t , X(Tk+1 ) in case of default in the time interval [Tk , Tk+1 ]:
T

B(0, T ) = E exp(−
0 T

r(s) + λ(s)ds) r(s) + λ(s)ds)X(T )
0 T

(2.25)

X(0, T ) = E exp(− g(0, T ) = E exp(−
0

r(s) + λ(s)ds)λ(t)
Tk+1

X(0, Tk , Tk+1 ) = E exp(−
0

r(s) + λ(s)ds)P (Tk , Tk+1 ) − B(0, Tk+1 )

Can be noted that, unlike the previous situation with deterministic intensity, now we could take out of the expectation the value of the risk-free ZCB, exp(− in which processes r(t) and λ(t) are independent. Using a model specification for the process of risk-free interest rate and for the intensity dynamic, we can obtain closed formulas or numerical approximations to the PDEs which should be satisfied by the corrispondent values of risky financial instruments. Specify a model for such processes is equivalent to define the multivariate process Xt for the variables of the state of the economy and how this affects the dynamics of interest rate and of default intensity.
T 0

r(s)ds), only in cases

For these models you can get the most suitable forms for the spread term curve, being able to model also the volatility. We therefore have a very flexible and apropriate model to be calibrated to market conditions. Still remains the problem of exponential random variable independent of driving factors of the economy, from which depends through (2.11) and (2.12) the likelihood of default, making, then, the default time also influenced by an exogenous source of uncertainty.

Chapter 3 Models For The Correlation Between Defaults
After having analyzed in the previous chapters the main approaches to the univariate analysis of defaults and their use for the pricing of the main financial instruments, in this chapter we will build the models for multivariate analysis of the default. The theory which involves the construction of models that can capture the dependence between the defaults of several companies is constantly changing. This development is especially crucial after the recent financial crisis, which has infected also most of the real economy, causing a succession of businesses’ crises concentrated over the past two years, and which sometimes led to the default of the companies involved. The firms were to be somehow related to each other, through commercial or financial relationship, or belonging to the same industry.

To introduce a dependence structure in default of several companies, can be considered two frameworks, respectively, defined bottom-up and top-down. In the first is modeled the correlation between the default, specifying the default dependence between the models of individual firms. So first, during the ”bottom” phase, univariate models are constructed for the default and then during the ”up” phase it is introduced a dependence structure

48

CHAPTER 3. MODELS FOR THE CORRELATION BETWEEN DEFAULTS

49

between individual defaults. In the second framework it is constructed directly a model for the default of the companies in the ”top” phase, and then afterwards in the ”down” phase, verify that the model calibrated to the market is also consistent with the prices of instruments dependent from the default of individual firms involved in the first phase analysis. The channels leading to a correlation between the spread of default, according to most models that have been developed, can be considered to be the following: • comovements related to risk factors that cause changes in the joint probability of default; • contagion effect on the financial condition of a company arising from the default of another entity; • review of the prospects of a company, necessary for the detection of previously hidden information that becomes known after the default of another. We present some approaches that have developed within the two frameworks, focusing mainly on the latest models for the risk of contagion and the so-called cluster of defaults. We should also point out the existence of a model recently presented by Duffie et al. (2009) and then reviseted by Azizpour et al. (2010), which is a model based on the socalled ”frialty” effect, where the correlation between the defaults is influenced by latent risk factors, whose presence after being detected involves jumps in the default probability of firms, whose intensity depends on those latent variables.

CHAPTER 3. MODELS FOR THE CORRELATION BETWEEN DEFAULTS

50

3.1

Bottom-Up Models

The bottom-up models trigger the correlation between the defaults, introducing a certain dependence structure among the variables that define the default processes of individual firms. Even in this case there can be considered different methodologies to approach the study of multivariate default, in fact they may differ in the type of framework which is used for both univariate default and for the dependence between the defaults. With regard to univariate modelling, the approaches are distinguished based on structural models, reduced form models, or on those models which seek to combine the two approaches, taking advantage of their strengths. On the side of the structure of dependence, this can be induced by the correlation of the processes that define the default (process assets, barriers, indicator functions of default, the default time, intensity or others) or by the use of a copula, which describes the dependence between the marginal univariate models. By analyzing the theory on the construction of models for the correlation of defaults and empirical studies on the results of some multivariate models, we could verify that the use of copulas is the most widely accepted in the theory of credit risk models, as well as the most used in practice. As for the univariate case, we initially treat the introduction of dependence according to the approach based on a structural model, then move on to analyze the reduced form approach, and finally treat the argument of copulas. For what it concerns the study of the correlation in the framework of structural models, another important approach, in addition to those presented in this thesis, we surely can include Hull and White (2001).

CHAPTER 3. MODELS FOR THE CORRELATION BETWEEN DEFAULTS

51

3.1.1

Structural Apporach

Reconsidering the first passage structural models, already seen in the first chapter, we have that their immediate multivariate extension might be possibly given by assuming that the processes of the assets value are correlated through the correlation between the sources of uncertainty introduced in their dynamic behaviour. If we consider a diffusion process of the type seen in (1.13) for the default of an individual firm, then there would be that the dependence between the defaults arises from the correlation between the standard Brownian motions.

Multivariate Model of Zhou Zhou (2001) introduces a bivariate model for the default of this type, so we get an analytical formula for the correlation of default and for the joint default probability distribution of a couple of firms. In the paper are initially presented the definitions of correlation between the defaults, of joint default probability and of disjoint probability of default event for two companies. So given the default indicator function for the two companies Di (t) with i = 1, 2, and given that for this function is E[Di (t)] = P (Di (t) = 1) and V ar[Di (t)) = P (Di (t) = 1)(1 − P (Di (t) = 1)), we have the following expressions for the correlation and the two probabilities, as defined above, as a function of the correlation: E[D1 (t)D2 (t)] − E[D1 (t)]E[D2 (t)]

V ar[D1 (t)]V ar[D2 (t)] P (D1 (t) = 1 ∩ D2 (t) = 1) = E[D1 (t)]E[D2 (t)] + Corr[D1 (t), D2 (t)] V ar[D1 (t)]V ar[D2 (t)] P (D1 (t) = 1 ∨ D2 (t) = 1) = E[D1 (t)] + E[D2 (t)] −P (D1 (t) = 1 ∩ D2 (t) = 1)

Corr[D1 (t), D2 (t)] =

(3.1)

(3.2)

(3.3)

CHAPTER 3. MODELS FOR THE CORRELATION BETWEEN DEFAULTS Then is defined the related processes as follows:      

52

 dln(V1 )   µ1   dZ1    =   dt + Ω   dln(V2 ) µ2 dZ2

(3.4)

with µ1 , µ2 average returns of the assets, dZ1 , dZ2 independent standard Brownian motions and   Ω×Ω =
2 σ1

 ρσ1 σ2 ρσ1 σ2   2 σ2

where Ω is a square matrix 2×2 of variances-covariances of the returns of the assets of two companies, in fact, ρ = Corr[d ln(V1 ), d ln(V1 )] is the correlation coefficient between the processes of the value of the assets. The univariate default for the two firms is defined by the passage of the exponential barrier Ci (t) = exp(−λi (t))Ki , similar to the one defined in Black and Cox (1976). Depending on the choice made for the value taken by λi , Zhou (2001) considers two situations: a simplified one in which λi = µi , so we have that the value of assets and debt grow at the same rate, so we are in the presence of a constant leverage ratio; a second one in which is considered that the two growth rates differ. For the first case we obtain analytical formulas, which are computationally tractable, for both for the correlation and for the bivariate default probability. In the second case we obtain analytical formulas also depending from a double integral of the Bessel function, which, as noted by the author, makes them computationally very complex1 . Moreover, with the implementation of the model, Zhou shows that the assumption of λi = µi has a negligible effect on the correlation of default, which is the reason why is sufficient to consider the simplified case. In Zhou (2001) is presented a theoretical and also an empirical analysis for the model. In particular is shown that there is a positive relationship over time between the correlation of returns on assets and the correlation of default to occur. This type of models with the diffusion process of the value of assets already had many
1

See the appendix of Zhou (2001) for a presentation and formal proofs of these formulas for both cases.

CHAPTER 3. MODELS FOR THE CORRELATION BETWEEN DEFAULTS

53

problems in the univariate framework, where for instance we could have observed null spreads in the short term. One possible remedy for this problem was proposed in the univariate context by Zhou (1997) with the introduction of a jump process, which described the sudden shocks in the value of the assets. By introducing jump processes correlated, it would result in a multivariate structural model that would make the default not predictable and at the same time would introduce within the multivariate framework the effects of the risk of contagion2 . This extension will, however, presents some complexity in the calibration phase of the jump components. Furthermore the model of Zhou (2001) considers only the cyclical component of the default dependence between firms.

See below in the thesis for an analysis of the phenomenon of contagion risk and the of the cluster of default.

2

CHAPTER 3. MODELS FOR THE CORRELATION BETWEEN DEFAULTS

54

Giesecke and Goldberg’s Model In the event of a default of a firm, the news of this event could lead to a contagion effect on other businesses directly related to that by commercial or financial relations. The contagion effect can result in a deterioration in the creditworthiness of companies, resulting in a change in the probability of default, which in some cases may even run out in default of other firms. Moreover, the effect of contagion also leads to the tendency to concentrate of default in certain periods, in which all the joint probability of default increase, and this phenomenon is called default clustering. Giesecke and Goldberg (2004b) extend the models of Giesecke (2004) and Giesecke and Goldberg (2004a), introducing the effect of contagion in multivariate structural models, assuming that investors do not have complete information3 neither on the processes of the value of firm’s assets nor on the default’s barriers. The default correlation is introduced by the correlation between the processes of the value of the assets and the dependence structure between the levels of barriers4 : the first is the cyclical component, while the second is the effect of the contagion. The model5 assumes that investors form a hypothetical joint distribution a priori, based on assumptions for the levels of the barriers and the values of the assets. When a default occurs suddenly, information about the true values of the assets and of the barrier allow investors to update, according to the formulas of Bayes (1763), the a priori distributions, resulting in an effect of contagion in the estimation of the joint probabilities of default. The main problem of this model concerns the estimation and calibration of the copula between the barriers.

The incomplete information in the structural univariate models was introduced by Duffie and Lando (2001), to cope with the default predictability. 4 This dependence structure between the barriers is introduced through the use of a copula. 5 See the papers Giesecke (2004), Giesecke and Goldberg (2004a), Giesecke and Goldberg (2004b) for the presentation of the model and the resulting analytical formulas.

3

CHAPTER 3. MODELS FOR THE CORRELATION BETWEEN DEFAULTS Approach of Duan, Gauthier, Simonato and Zaanoun

55

In their approach Duan et al.

(2002) deal with the problem of estimating parameters of structural models, which are used for the portfolio analysis of credit risk, when sometimes is assumed the presence of stochastic interest rates. This problem arises from the fact that the necessary parameters for the implementation of models are usually not directly stripped from the market. In fact, neither processes of the values of the assets, from which we should get the drift, volatilities and correlations, nor the the parameters of the barriers nor the parameters of stochastic process of the interest rates are observable.

Duan et al. (2002) after building a likelihood function based on a transformation6 of observable values for the stocks, to estimate the parameters they apply the maximimum lieklihood method in the context of credit risk7 . The authors formalize the likelihood function8 and then the log-likelihood both in the framework of Merton (1974) with constant interest rates, and within the framework of Longstaff and Schwartz (1995) with interest deterministic or stochastic rates. After obtaining the maximum likelihood estimated parameters, with these values we could run Monte Carlo simulations to verify the performance in a finite sample inference, then using the asymptotic properties of estimators of maximum likelihood, such as the consistency and convergence in probability to a normal, to comment also on their behaviour in the limit. Moreover with this approach we obtain estimates of the parameters directly from market prices and therefore under the real or physical probability measure.

This transformation consists in the use of the formula (1.8) of Merton (1974) or Longstaff and Schwartz (1995) for the pricing of the equity value as a function of the value of the assets. 7 See also Ericsson and Reneby (2001) for maximum likelihood estimation applied to models for credit spreads. See Duan (1994) for an application to models for the pricing of insurance reserves. 8 Please refer to Duan et al. (2002) for explicit formulas of the likelihood, and for estimation and simulation procedures.

6

CHAPTER 3. MODELS FOR THE CORRELATION BETWEEN DEFAULTS

56

3.1.2

Intensity Models Approaches

Conditionally Indipendent Models The first multivariate approach for modeling the default in the intensity models framework consists in the so called conditionally independent models. The dependence between the defaults is induced by the correlation between the intensities, which in turn depends on a process of the economy state variables related to each other and on an idiosyncratic factor different for each company. These models are defined conditionally independent models because when we condition on a realization of the process of the state variables, the intensities and default times are independent, as all the dependence structure is derived only from the correlations between the variables of the state of the economy.

Duffee’s Model

In the model proposed by Duffee (1999) to estimate the yield curve of

the defaultable bond, we have that the interest rate follows a stochastic diffusion process of the so called ”translated two factor square-root diffusion” type, while the process of intensity is defined by a so called single factor translated square-root diffusion process, modified so that the default processes depend also on the term structure of risk-free rates. Then we get that the risk-free interest rate follows the stochastic process

r(t) = αr + s1,t + s2,t

(3.5)

where αr is a constant and the two factors s1,t , s2,t , representing the state variables of the economy, follow two indipendent sthocastic process defined by the SDE: √ dsi,t = ki (θi − si,t )dt + σi si,t dZi,t

(3.6)

where the deterministic component converges on average to a constant θi with a rate of convergence equals to ki and where Zi,t , i = 1, 2 are indipendent standard Brownian motions.

CHAPTER 3. MODELS FOR THE CORRELATION BETWEEN DEFAULTS

57

From these relations we can be obtain closed-form formulas for the prices of risk-free ZCBs, whose yields are linear with respect to the two-term factors s1,t , s2,t , which can be interpreted respectively as the slope and intercept of the level in t of the term curve of the risk-free rate. From the yield curve obtained from the quotations of the risk-free ZCBs, we can estimate the values of the two state variables and their sample means s1,t , s1,t . With these estimates are constructed, together with a stochastic firm-specific factor h∗ , the default intensity j,t processes. We have that the diffusive stochastic process followed by the intensity hj,t of the j-th firm is

hj,t = αj + h∗ + β1,j (s1,t − s1,t ) + β2,j (s2,t − s2,t ) j,t

(3.7)

where αj is a constant, and the coefficients β1,t , β2,t capture all the correlation between the intensity and r, while the idiosyncratic component follows a stochastic process independent of r and defined by the SDE

dh∗ = kj (θj − h∗ )dt + σj j,t j,t

h∗ dZj,t j,t

(3.8)

with Zi,t , i = 1, 2 indipendent standard Brownian motions. In this model we have that the two common state variables, which appeare in the default intensity processes, are defined by the two factors that influence the dynamic of risk-free rate. In particular, since these two factors are latent, i.e. can not be directly observed, their time series must be estimated from the yield curve of risk-free bonds before they can be used to build up the intensity of the default processes. Also the only independent factor between companies is present in every different process of intensity h∗ , which represents j,t the specific component of the randomness of the default for a specific firm. So we get a model in which the dependence structure of defaults is given by the different relationship that each intensity has with respect to the common factors, which define the term structure of interest rates, while the idiosyncratic component of default is governed by the specific

CHAPTER 3. MODELS FOR THE CORRELATION BETWEEN DEFAULTS independent factor different for each firm’s default intensity.

58

This family of conditionally independent models, as stated by Yu (2002), results in levels of default correlation which are not sufficiently high. This fact stems from the impossibility of an accurate and specific choice of state variables involved in the process of intensity, for which in Duffee (1999) we consider only two factors that govern the evolution of the yield curve of risk-free rates .

CHAPTER 3. MODELS FOR THE CORRELATION BETWEEN DEFAULTS

59

Approach of Duffie and Singletone Within the conditionally independent models Duffie and Singleton (1999) consider the problem of low levels of correlation as seen in Duffee (1999), proposing two possible extensions: the possibility that there are joint defaults caused by the same event or the presence of joint jumps in the intensity of default9 . In the first approach we model the intensity of arrival of joint events relevant to the situation of the credit merit of a firm, which might cause the default of several companies simultaneously. These events are defined as credit events, for which in Duffie and Singleton (1999) there are some examples. Upon the occurrence of certain combined events the intensity of some firms may vary, leading in some cases even to the default of one or more firms or otherwise to a change in the probability of this oppurtunity. Then the default intensity for each firm i is

hi,t = pi,t Jt + Hi,t

(3.9)

where Hi,t is the specific intensity of the i-th firm, Jt and pi,t are respectively the intensity of the arrival of credit events and the joint probability that they cause the default of the firm i. In this case the correlation between the defaults is triggered either through the joint variations of the default intensities or through the probability that certain joint events, common to all firms, even cause simultaneous defaults. In the second approach is assumed that the intensities of default of individual firms follow a mean-reverting process, to which is added a jump process with a component differently related to the various companies. So we have that the intensity of default hi of the i-th firm has a diffusion component defined by a mean-reverting process, to which is added a process of jump ji with constant intensity λi , independent jump size distributed as an exponential variable with mean J. Then we have dhi,t = ki (θi − hi,t )dt + dji (t) (3.10)

where the diffusion component converges on average to a constant θi with a rate of con9

Other extensions have also been proposed by Kijima (2000) and Kijima and Muromachi (2000)

CHAPTER 3. MODELS FOR THE CORRELATION BETWEEN DEFAULTS

60

vergence ki . The jump process of each firm is comprised of two components: an idiosyncratic jump process independent among firms with an intensity γi and a joint jump component common to all the firms with intensity γc and differently related to the firms from using the probability pi , which influences the intensity λi . Moreover, to obtain that the intensity of the jump is λi ∼ exp(J), there must result that λi = γi + pi γc and that all the intensities have an exponential distribution with mean J. We have, therefore, that the jump times have a multivariate exponential distribution and that they are related through the likelihood that the intensities are influenced by the effects of a joint jump. The dependence structure between default is induced by correlation in changes in intensities, due to the occurence with different probabilities of joint jumps, which, together with the diffusion component, governs the processes of the intensity of default of individual firms. These two alternative approaches, in which the correlation of default is conditional on the occurrence of credit events or joint jumps in the intensities of default, they came under criticism due to the fact that both admit either that more than one default can occur exactly at the same instant either that the default of some firm does not make the intensity of the associated companies to vary significantly. In addition, the calibration and the model implementation is quite complex.

CHAPTER 3. MODELS FOR THE CORRELATION BETWEEN DEFAULTS Contagion Models

61

Another approach to model the correlation of defaults within the intensity models are the so-called contagion models. These models extend the conditionlly independent models including the risk of contagion of default and the risk of cluster of default, i.e. we consider the possibility that the default of a company may cause the default of related companies and that the defaults tend to be concentrated in certain periods, where the probability of default of any business increases. Now we present two models: in the first Davis and Lo (1999) is considered the contagion of defaults among firms, and in the second of Jarrow and Yu (2001) is included the possibility to observe clusters.

Approach of Davis and Lo

In Davis and Lo (1999) and Davis and Lo (2001) we ana-

lyze the influence that the risk of contagion has on the estimation of default correlation, considering two classes of probabilistic models: a static and a dynamic one. In the first class is constructed the probability distribution of the number of defaults, so that it incorporates the effects of interaction between the defaults. The default of an entity, a bond or generalizing a company belonging to a specific sector, it activates a sort of mechanism of ”infection” of the default within the same sector, so there might be an increased likelihood of default. This model evaluates the diffusion of the so-called ”infectious defaults” between companies or bonds belonging to the same sector within a given time interval. It is therefore a static model to estimate the number of defaults in a portfolio of entities belonging to different sectors10 .

In the second class of models is revisited the static approach, extending it to obtain a dynamic version of the effect of ”infection” of the default. In this model, is constructed a stochastic process continuous in time called ”enhanced-risk model”, as the occurrence of a default results at the beginning of a period of increased risk of default with random duration, in which all the probabilities of default increase. While in the static model is
It extends to the BET model(Binomial Expansion Technique) developed by the agency for investment services Moody’s, see Moody’s (1997)
10

CHAPTER 3. MODELS FOR THE CORRELATION BETWEEN DEFAULTS

62

estimated the number of defaults, with this dynamic model we can try to determine when these take place, building a stochastic process that provides a sequence of random times of default for multiple entities, for which we consider some mechanism of infection . Initially we assume that each firm i has a given process λi (t) for the default intensity. When there is the default for i, the intensities of all other companies j = i, which have not experienced a default, increase by a certain multiplicative factor a > 1, defined enhanced factor. This factor continues to remain at a for a period of time distributed as an exponential with a given mean µ. Elapsed this time period, in which all firms are more likely to default than what is observed in normal conditions, then the factor a becomes equal to 1 until another default occurs, with which begins another period called enhanced-risk period, in which the default probabilities reflect the risk of infection resulted from the occurrence of default.

Approach of Jarrow and Yu With the use of conditionally independent models we have that the correlation, depending on joint influence of risk factors, does not take into account the presence of the risk of contagion and the cluster of defaults in certain periods, such as in particular situations of economic and financial crisis and global downturn. Jarrow and Yu (2001) generalize these models including the risk that derives from the structure of the counterparts of a firm. This risk, depending on the set of relationships that a company has with its counterparties, is defined counterparty risk. The risk of default of a counterparty, together with that arising from changes in macroeconomic variables relevant to the default, they affect the probability of default of a company, making it more prone to default in times of crisis among all firms. Thus we have that the counterparty risk tends to concentrate defaults in times of recession or when financial crisis spreads across multiple businesses. In this way Jarrow and Yu (2001) consider in their model for related defaults the presence of clusters of defaults, due to the tight web of interdependencies among firms, so that also the default of a company can trigger a cascade of defaults. In their paper they present some examples of historical events, in which the default of a

CHAPTER 3. MODELS FOR THE CORRELATION BETWEEN DEFAULTS

63

counterparty has caused many other companies linked together to default. The type of relationship between counterparties may be of financial type (e.g. possession of the assets of another company) or of commercial type (e.g. suppliers of the company). With the counterparty risk we introduce an additional source of dependence between the defaults with respect to that found in the conditionally independent models, incorporating the contagion and the cluster of defaults. Their model extends the reduced form models, making the process of the intensity to be a stochastic process that depends on the state variables of the economy11 and on jump processes, which capture the interdependencies between firms, including in this way the risk of the counterparty in the model. Taking the framework of a Cox process for the default, presented in chapter (2.3), we assume that the uncertainty of the economy is represented by the probabilistic space Ω, F, {Ft }T , P , where F = FT and P is an equivalent martingale measure, unt=0 der which the discounted values of bonds are martingales. Furthermore given the process of the d state variables Xt which takes values in d and Cox processes Ni , i = 1, 2, . . . , I,

whose first unit jump represents the default of the I firms considered. The complete information on the economy is represented by the filtration Ft = FtX ∨ Ft1 ∨ Ft2 ∨ · · · ∨ FtI , where FtX = σ{Xs , 0 ≤ s ≤ t} and Fti = σ{Ni (s), 0 ≤ s ≤ t} represent the information relative to the state variables and to the processes of default of the firms. In addition, we
−i X introduce the filtration Gti = Fti ∨ FT ∨ FT representing the information to an i-th firm

at time t about the realizations of its default process given the knowledge untill time T of the series of the default for other businesses and of the state variables of the economy, in which Ft−i = Ft1 ∨ · · · ∨ Fti−1 ∨ Fti+1 ∨ · · · ∨ FtI is the filtration generated by the processes of default of the other companies j = i. We get, therefore, that at the initial i time t = 0, G0 contains the complete information on the state variables of the economy

and on the realiztions of the default processes of other companies. Then we define with Ni (t) the Cox process for the default of firm i, and with λi (t) the intensity of the jump
11

See Section (2.3) for a definition of these variables.

CHAPTER 3. MODELS FOR THE CORRELATION BETWEEN DEFAULTS process adapted to the filtration Gti , such that the condition t 0

64

λi (s)ds < ∞ is satisfied

and that the intensity is defined by a process that depends on the state variables and the default of other firms. Then we have that the conditional probability and the unconditional probability of default of the i-th firm at time τi (defined as the instant of the first jump of Ni ), respectively are: t i t|G0 )

P (τi >

= exp(−
0

λi (s)ds), t ∈ [0, T ] t (3.11) (3.12)

P (τi > t) = E exp(−
0

λi (s)ds) , t ∈ [0, T ]

We obtain a series of Cox processes for the default of companies, where the default intensity may also depend on the state of all firms of the economy. In this general framework, as noted by the Jarrow and Yu (2001), it may happen that the complexity of the model becomes unmanageable when there are ”loops” in the structure of the counterparties, making it impossible or extremely complicated to construct a joint default probabilities model. This situation with a possible loop refers also to the symmetric dependence between companies, where the intensity of default of a company depends on the state of default or non default of other firms and vice versa. This situation occurs for example when you have cross-holdings of debt, or when each firm has a market share of debt issued by other firms. To overcome this problem Jarrow and Yu (2001) introduce a restriction on the structure of the counterparts in the model. Then they distinguish primary businesses defined by the subset S1 ⊂ I, from secondary firms defined by the subset S2 ⊂ I complement of S1 . The intensities of the primary business depend only on the state of the economy FtX , while the second group ones are dependent both on the state of the economy and on the state of the other companies and therefore their default processes. Given a set of exponential random variables {ξ i , 1 ≤ i ≤ S1 } independent of each other and with respect to the process Xt , then we define the default time τi of the i-th primary

CHAPTER 3. MODELS FOR THE CORRELATION BETWEEN DEFAULTS firm as t 65

τi = {t :
0

λi (s)ds ≥ ξ i }, 1 ≤ i ≤ S1

(3.13)

which is distribuited as t X P (τi > t|FT ) = exp(− 0

λi (s)ds), t ∈ [0, T ]

(3.14)

where λi (t) is measurable with respect to FtX . Then we introduce a further set of exponential random variables {ξ j , S1 + 1 ≤ j ≤ I} independent of each other and with respect to both the process FtX and to set of the default times of the primary firms {τi , 1 ≤ i ≤ S1 }. Then the time of default τj of the j-th secondary firm is t τj = {t :
0

λj (s)ds ≥ ξ j }, S1 + 1 ≤ j ≤ I

(3.15)

Whose distribution of probability is t S X 1 P (τi > t|FT ∨ FT ∨ · · · ∨ FT 1 ) = exp(− 0

λj (s)ds), t ∈ [0, T ]

(3.16)

where now the intensity of default λj (t) of the secondary firm is adapted to FtX ∨ Ft1 ∨ · · · ∨ FtS1 . Among the secondary firms the counterparty risk structure is introduced trough the intensity λj (t), which is assumed to have the following form
S1

λj (t) =

aj 0,t

+ k=1 aj It≥τk , S1 + 1 ≤ j ≤ I k,t

(3.17)

where the indicator function of default It≥τk = 1 − Nk (t), ∀k, aj is adapted to FtX , aj 0,t k,t which represents the component of the intensity indipendent of the state of default of the other firms and it is adapted to FtX ; moreover we assume that the firm j holds only assets of the primary firms i.

In this model the primary companies have independent default, while the asymmetric

CHAPTER 3. MODELS FOR THE CORRELATION BETWEEN DEFAULTS

66

counterpart structure between the primary and secondary firms defines the dependence structure of defaults among secondary firms and between secondary and primary firms. This dependency is defined according to the sign given by aj , which binds the default k,t intensities of the secondary firms with indicator functions of default of the primary firms. This model, as observed by Yu (2002), despite it introduces counterparty risk as a new source of correlation between the defaults, allowing the analysis of default probability to take into account also the risk of contagion and the cluster of defaults, it still keeps the conditionally independent model setting to model the default probabilities of primary businesses.

CHAPTER 3. MODELS FOR THE CORRELATION BETWEEN DEFAULTS

67

3.1.3

Approaches with Copulas

The third approach in the multivariate models to introduce a structure of dependence between the defaults is the use of copulas. According to this approach, contrary to what we have already discussed above for multivariate models both structural and based on the intensity, we separate the definition of the univariate models of the default from the structuring of the multivariate model for defaults. The formulation of the joint distribution of default occurs in two separate steps: at first we construct the marginal distributions of default times of individual firms, while in the next step we introduce a copula that links the marginal distributions, thus forming the joint distribution of default with a specific dependence structure defined by the copula introduced. This division allows us to calibrate and imply any model at the univariate level and then with the introduction of the copula calibrate the model to multivariate level. This makes the modeling and calibration of the joint distribution to be less complex than the multivariate models in which the dependence structure should be introduced already in default models for the single entities. The main and essential step of the approach is now in the careful choice of the copula, in its formulation and calibration, making it the focal point of the approach and therefore the most attention demanding and delicate to be addressed in the joint modeling of default. The copula takes as input estimates of marginal probability distributions of default times, transforming them into a joint probability distribution of default times, in which the dependence structure is completely introduced by the copula by linking the marginals. The copulas have been introduced in the probabilistic field by Sklar (1959)12 , and their use has been growing strongly, especially in recent years. The use of copulas was introduced in the actuarial field for estimating the probability of survival by Frees and Valdez (1998) and in finance by Embrechts et al. (1999), while in the models for the dependence of credit risk, among others, we remind Li (2000), Frey and McNeil (2001), Sch¨ nbucher o and Schubert (2001) and Schmidt and Ward (2002). Initially we introduce the use of copFor more theoretical treatment about copula, see also Sklar (1996), Nelsen (1999), Sch¨ nbucher (2003) o and McNeil et al. (2005).
12

CHAPTER 3. MODELS FOR THE CORRELATION BETWEEN DEFAULTS

68

ulas to tie univariate structural models, then afterwards we analyze their introduction in the univariate models for the intensity.

Inroduction to the Use of Copulas in the Credit Risk Models. Given the probabilistic space {Ω, F, P }. Consider n firms whose default times are defined as τi , i = 1, . . . , n and whose default indicator functions at time t are Ii (t), which are also defined as    1 τ ≤t  i   0 τ >t  i It is defined with Gi = {Gi (t), t ≥ 0} the filtration generated by the stochastic process of default of individual firms, so we have the sigma algebra Gi (t) = σ{Gi (s), 0 ≤ s ≤ t}. Then the marginal probability of default at time t, calculated at time 0, for the i-th firm is equal to Fi (t) = P (Ii (t) = 1|Gi (0)), while the corresponding marginal probability of survival up to time t is Si (t) = 1 − Fi (t). The joint distributions of default probabilities and survival, respectively, are

Ii (t) =

(3.18)

F (t) = P (I1 (t) = 1, . . . , In (t) = 1|G(0)) S(t) = P (I1 (t) = 0, . . . , In (t) = 0|G(0)) n (3.19) (3.20)

where G =

Gi . Assuming the continuity of the marginal, we admit, according to i=1 Sklar’s theorem, that these joint distributions can be expressed by means of n-dimensional copulas, which in this case exist and are unique, and of the marginals Fi (t) and Si (t) ∀i = 1, . . . , n. Then we have the following expressions for the joint distributions of the probabilities of default and survival:

F (t) = C(F1 (t), . . . , Fn (t)) S(t) = Cs (S1 (t), . . . , Sn (t))

(3.21) (3.22)

CHAPTER 3. MODELS FOR THE CORRELATION BETWEEN DEFAULTS

69

where C, Cs are two copulas wich describe the dependence structure of the probability of default and survival. We can note that by the definition of the copula and of the time of default, we have the following links between the marginal probabilities and the joint distributions expressed through the copula:

Fi (ti ) = F (∞, . . . , ti . . . , ∞) = C(1, . . . , ti . . . , 1) Si (ti ) = S(0, . . . , ti . . . , 0) = Cs (1, . . . , ti . . . , 1)

(3.23) (3.24)

In general we have that the copulas are parametrized by measures of dependence, including the most known coefficient of linear correlation ρ, which alone characterizes the Gaussian copula, while together with the degrees of freedom g they define the Student’s-t copula13 .

13

See Nelsen (1999) for more details.

CHAPTER 3. MODELS FOR THE CORRELATION BETWEEN DEFAULTS Copulas in the Structural Framework

70

In the structural framework the copula is introduced by first defining the process followed by the value of assets for each firm and the relative marginal probability that it is touched or crossed the barrier, depending on the type of process followed by the value of the assets, then in the next step bind the marginal distributions by means of a copula, thus obtaining the joint distribution of the probability of default. Within the framework of Merton (1974) for univariate default, we assume that the default can only occur at debt maturity. Assuming that this date is equal to t equal for all firms i = 1, . . . , n, we have that the marginal probability of default for the i-th company is

Fi (t) = P (Vi (t) ≤ Ki (t))

(3.25)

with Vi (t), Ki (t) respectively, the value at time t of the process of the value of the assets of the firm i and the value of the respective barrier. As discussed in Chapter (1.1), in the model of Merton (1974) we have that the marginal probability is equal to

Fi (t) = Φ(−di,2 (t))

(3.26)

where still Φ is the Standard Normal CDF, while we have
V ln( Kii(0) ) + (r − q − 0.5σ 2 )(t) (t) √ di,2 (t) = σ t

(3.27)

with the same interpretations for r and q already discussed in the chapter (1.1). Then the joint distribution of default probabilities can be expressed, through the use of a given copula, as follows

F (t) = P (V1 (t) ≤ K1 (t), . . . , Vn (t) ≤ Kn (t)) = C(Φ(−d1,2 (t)), . . . , Φ(−dn,2 (t))) (3.28)

CHAPTER 3. MODELS FOR THE CORRELATION BETWEEN DEFAULTS

71

In the model of Merton ln(Vi (t)) have an univariate normal distribution derived from the fact that Vi (t) follows a geometric Brownian motion. If we assume that they are also jointly normal, to obtain the joint distribution function we have to introduce the Gaussian copula ΦR with R matrix of correlations. Setting ui = Fi , we obtain

F (t) = ΦR (Φ−1 (u1 ), . . . , Φ−1 (un )) = ΦR (−d1,2 (t), . . . , −dn,2 (t))

(3.29)

If, however, keeping the marginal as above normal, we introduce the Student’s-t copula instead of the Gaussian one, thus considering another dependence structure, we then obtain the following joint probability distribution for the default

F (t) = tR,g (t−1 (u1 ), . . . , t−1 (un )) g g

(3.30)

where t−1 is the quantile function of the Student’s-t standard, tR,g is the CDF of the g multivariate standard t-Student, and g are the degrees of freedom. If instead the model of Merton (1974) we consider an univariate approach for the default, which admits the default to occur also before the debt maturity, such as Black and Cox (1976)’s model, then we would get that the marginal probability would be

Fi (t) = P ( min (Vi (t) ≤ Ki (t)))
0≤s≤t

(3.31)

Hence now we have that the probability would depend not only on the process Vi (t) but would depend as well on the minimum process, making it impossible to obtain normal distributions at the univariate level. We have other cases in which the assumption of normality is not fulfilled, for example when is introduced stochastic dynamics for the interest rates, as it is assumed in the model of Longstaff and Schwartz (1995). These extensions make no more acceptable the assumption of multivariate normal joint distribution. At the multivariate level, we can still introduce structures of dependency also described by

CHAPTER 3. MODELS FOR THE CORRELATION BETWEEN DEFAULTS

72

the Gaussian copula, as well as other elliptical copula, such as the Student’s-t. We may also consider additional functions for the copula, such as those belonging to the family of Archimedean copulas, chosen only by the type of dependency that you want to introduce regardless of the estimated marginals.

CHAPTER 3. MODELS FOR THE CORRELATION BETWEEN DEFAULTS Copulas in the Framework of Intensity Models

73

As part of the intensity models for the univariate default, we have the default time for the company i can be expressed as follows t τi = inf{t :
0

λi (s)ds ≥ ξi }

(3.32)

where ξi ∼ Exp(1) for each i independent of each other and of the information on the state of the economy available to investors. These exponential random variables represent a kind of barrier for the stochastic hazard function, which if crossed it involves the default of the firm. Making a change of variable by the position ξi = − ln(Ui ), with Ui ∼ U (0, 1), uniformly distribuited in [0.1] for each i independent of each other and of the information available. Then we obtain: t τi = inf{t : exp(−
0

λi (s)ds) ≥ Ui }

(3.33)

Recalling what has been obtained in Chapter (2) for the marginal probability of default and survival in the case of deterministic intensity, we get t Fi (t) = 1 − exp(−
0 t

λ(s)ds)

(3.34) (3.35)

Si (t) = exp(−
0

λ(s)ds)

While in case of a stochastic intensity, conditioning with respect to information available in t = 0, defined by G0 14 , we get t Fi (t) = 1 − E exp(−
0 t

λ(s)ds)

(3.36) (3.37)

Si (t) =
14

exp(−
0

λ(s)ds)

See Section 2.3 for its definition.

CHAPTER 3. MODELS FOR THE CORRELATION BETWEEN DEFAULTS Li’s model

74

Li (2000) can be considered one of the first to use a copula to introduce the

structure of dependence between the defaults, whose marginals are estimated by means of the formulation of univariate models based on the intensity of default. In this approach the joint distribution is built up using a copula as dependence link between the marginal probability of survival and of default of firms. As noted in paragraph ”Introduction to the copoulas in credit risk model”, this procedure is considered analogous to the consideration of a copula between the marginal joint probability of default. According to this approach, we consider the stochastic independent barriers, obtaining thus a conditionally independent model for the default. For the estimation of correlated default times, Li (2000) use the Gaussian copula with correlation matrix R to bind the marginals of the joint probability of survival. Thus in order to obtain a realization for the vector, (τ1 , τ2 , . . . , τn ), of default times for firms, will be sufficient to simulate a multivariate normal vector, (Y1 , Y2 , . . . , Yn ), with the same matrix of coefficients of correlation R; then using the relation τi = Fi−1 Φ(Yi ), we retrieve a simulation of the vector of default times with the the given correlation matrix R.

Schonbucher e Schubert’s model In the approach of Sch¨ nbucher and Schubert (2001) o are admitted not conditionally indipendent default, assuming that the stochastic barriers, either ξi or Ui , are mutually dependent through the introduction of a copula between their marginals, but they still are independent from the information of the state variables of the economy. In this case, the default time of the i-th firm is defined from (3.33) as t τi = inf{t : exp(−
0

λi (s)ds) ≥ ui }

(3.38)

where ui is a realization of the uniform Ui in [0.1]. Sch¨ nbucher and Schubert (2001) o consider the intensities λi , i = 1, . . . , n, adapted to the respective filtrations Fi (t), representing the information available on both state variables of the economy and on the default state of the firm i, and where the intensities are called ”pseudo default intensi-

CHAPTER 3. MODELS FOR THE CORRELATION BETWEEN DEFAULTS

75

ties”. Anyhow investors also observe the status of other companies, thus such intensities are not adapted to information actually available to investors, which is represented by the filtration F(t). The information on the status of other companies in the model of Sch¨ nbucher and Schubert (2001) is introduced by the copula linking the barriers which o triggers defaults. For the estimation of default probabilities based on all information available, would be necessary to find the real intensities hi (t), i = 1, . . . , n adapted to the filtration F(t), by combining pseudo-intensities with the specification of the copula between the barriers. For the simulation of a vector of default times for the n companies in the economy, Sch¨ nbucher and Schubert (2001) apply the same procedure described o above for the model of Li (2000), except that in this case we use the actual intensity to estimate the marginals of the joint probability of default. This approach by using the copula between the barriers can also introduce a level of risk of contagion in default, but differently from what we found in Davis and Lo (1999) and Jarrow and Yu (2001), we find that the risk of contagion derives endogenously from the use of the copula between the barriers. In their approach is formalized the general expression of the real intensity for Archimedean copulas and in particular for the Gumbel and Clayton copula. They also present the results of the calibration of their model by introducing a Gaussian copula on the barriers in the presence of a univariate conditionally independent model for the intensity, however allowing for a different specification for the univariate intensity model. In a further extension to this approach, Rogge and Sch¨ nbucher (2003) use an Archimedean o copula instead of the Gaussian, since they state that the elliptical copulas are not appropriate to calibrate a real joint dynamic of the intensity of default.

CHAPTER 3. MODELS FOR THE CORRELATION BETWEEN DEFAULTS

76

3.2

Top-Down Models

Instead of defining the dependence structure, introducing it after having defined in a first step the univariate models for default by one of the techniques discussed above, we could initially ignore the univariate distributions, and formulate directly the multivariate model for the default of firms. We therefore consider a model for the total loss and for the counting processes of the number of defaults, building a model for the aggregate loss, associated with the same level of loss or with any particular rate of loss. In this type of approach, a model after being calibrated with derivatives on multivariate credit risk, will also be implemented for the pricing of products dependent on the default of a single entity. The latter is needed to verify the consistency of estimates even with respect to the univariate risk of default. In general this phase, called ”down”, it is crucial for the overall adequacy of a top-down model. For this reason it is extremely difficult to analyze the an ex post consistency of estimates for the univariate default, derived from a model initially constructed at a multivariate level. The first top-down models, among others, have been proposed by Sch¨ nbucher (2005), Giesecke and Goldberg (2005) and o Errais et al. (2006), while the first who perform a calibration to quotes of the indices and other derivatives on multivariate credit risk have been Brigo et al. (2007). Regarding the problem of the ”down” phase there have been some proposals, among which we point up the technique of the random thinning, which is used to decompose the intensity of default at portfolio level in the sum of the intensities of the components of the portfolio. This technique was initially proposed by Errais et al. (2006) and later extended by Ding et al. (2009), Halperin and Tomecek (2008), Zhou (2009) and Giesecke et al. (2010), who analyse the relationship between portfolio risk and the risk of its individual components, whose analysis is needed to evaluate the sensitivity of the value of a credit risk portfolio with respect to the value of a derivative on the univariate credit risk, in order to asses the correct hedging strategy for the portfolio positions, without further specification for the top-down model at which it applies random thinning.

Chapter 4 Credit Risk Derivates
The credit risk derivative instruments have been developed especially in the last ten years, infact those products have been established themselves among investors, as they respond to the need to acquire a hedge against the risk of default or to another credit event, such as voluntary restructuring of the capital of a company, which could detoriate the solvency or the credit rating of a security held by the investor, such as a corporate bond or a government bond. With regard to the credit events against whose occurrence can be purchased a hedging derivative contract, there has been formalized a definition by the ISDA (International Swaps and Derivatives Association), under whose rules are defined the characteristics of most derivative contracts on the credit risk, both those traded on regulated markets, ant those negotiated OTC (over the Counter) or through private contracts. In the thesis we use the term default to define the credit event that determines the complete non-fulfillment of the obligations with respect to the creditors of a company, in particular as regards of corporate bonds holders. The definition of default considered can be related to the definition of events relating to credit risk, which are proposed by ISDA and used for the settlement of derivatives, if at least such a credit event occurs prior to maturity. Using the definition of the default proposed in the report Moody’s (2001), which summarizes the definitions of the credit risk event according to the ISDA and its links with the definition of default as considered by Moody’s, to which we refer to for the defini-

77

CHAPTER 4. CREDIT RISK DERIVATES

78

tion of the models presented for the default risk valuation. The first derivatives on credit risk that have been introduced in the early 1990’s were bilateral contracts, through which they allow for the negotiation of the risk associated with the creditworthiness of a third party, the debtor to whose solvibility is referred the hedging purpose of the derivative contract. The settlment of such contracts (their pay off), depends on the occurrence of specific credit events relating to the debtor to which the derivative contract is referred. In those contracts the underlying consists of an asset issued by the same debtor of reference of the contract. The regulation of the contract may be done in cash (cash settlement) or physically (physical settlement), with the delivery of the underlying security done by the buyer of the derivative to the seller in exchange of the pair value of the same underlying financial instrument. The main credit risk derivatives are the follows: 1. Asset Swaps 2. Credit Default Swaps (CDS) 3. Credit-Linked Notes 4. Total Return Swaps 5. Credit Spread Options 6. Basket Instruments For a definition of all those listed here, please refer to books or specialized sites, such as the ISDA website which is a good source for their detailed definition; while now we introduce the features of the CDS and also of CDSs Index, as these represent the types of credit risk derivatives most liquid, since liquitity is also necessary to consistently reflect the sentiment of the market participants on the probability of default of a specific firm.

CHAPTER 4. CREDIT RISK DERIVATES

79

4.1

The Credit Default Swaps

Credit Default Swaps are bilateral contracts in which the contractor (protection buyer) who wants to acquire an hedge against the credit risk relating to a financial underlying (reference obligation), he pays a periodic premium (CDS premium or simply fair spread), applied on the notional of the contract, to the seller of the contract (protection seller), which in turn is committed to a final payoff in the event of default by the issuer of the reference obligation. The final payoff can be done by the protection seller through a payment in cash, cash settlement, or through the purchase at par of the financial underlying delivered by the protection buyer, physical settlement. In the cash settlement procedure, the most common for derivatives traded on regulated markets, the protection seller reimburse the protection buyer by an amount equal to the notional of the contract multiplied by the loss on the financial underlying asset, computed as the difference between the par value of the underlying and its market or realizable value after the default or as a quote of the par value specified in the contract, where this proportion is also defined as Loss Given to Default (LGD). Below, in Figure (4.1), we present a graphical scheme of the contract with cash settlement or physical settlement.

4.2

CDSs Index

In order to negotiate and transfer the credit risk on a basket of financial instruments issued by several companies which also belong not necessarily to homogeneous areas, without incurring in an excessive cost due to the purchasing of a portfolio of CDSs on the OTC market or negotiated on the regulated market. For this main reason the CDSs indices products have been constructed, since they are by far less costly than buying separately each CDSs, and with which we can be covered against the risk of default of counterparties belonging to the index. These indeces also provide the agent both a measure of the portfolio spread of the CDSs and even a useful tool for the negotiation of the CDSs. In particular, the CDS market indices, hugely developed in recent years, has had further success

CHAPTER 4. CREDIT RISK DERIVATES

80

Figure 4.1: CDS Scheme in 2004, when there was a consolidation in the sector through agreements between the companies that had set up the indeces. In particular, the most popular and liquid indices, belonging to the two main economic regions, Europe and North America, respectively, are the indices: • iTraxx Europe, regarding the 5 and 10 years spreads of a basket of 125 European companies from different sectors and with high credit worthiness; • CDX NA IG, relating to 5 and 10 years spreads of a basket of 125 companies in North America (NA) with high credit quality, i.e. investment grade (IG), as defined in the index name.

iTraxx Europe Index

This index is the most liquid iTraxx indix, owned, managed,

compiled and published by International Index Company (IIC), which provides the licenses for the market makers. The iTraxx Europe index is composed of the 125 most liquid CDSs with reference credit instruments issued by investment grade European companies, subject to certain rules of the sector as determined by the IIC and the SEC (U.S.

CHAPTER 4. CREDIT RISK DERIVATES

81

Securities and Exchange Commission). The iTraxx index composition is divided in finance sector, in turn divided into Sub Financials and Senior Financials, and non-financial sector, to which belong the field of technology, media and telecommunications (TMT: Technology, Media, Telecommunications), the auto and industry sector (Autos and Industrials), the sector of consumer goods (Consumers) and the energy sector (Energy). In addition, each CDS has the same weight, equal to 0.8% of the total value of the index. There is also a significant volume, in terms of liquidity, in the negotiation of the indeces HiVol and Crossover, which are part of the iTraxx indices. The HiVol index is a subset of the main index, the iTraxx Europe, consisting of what are considered the thirty most risky components of the index at the time it is updated. The Crossover index is constructed in a similar way, but is composed of fifty sub-investment grade firms references. The components of the indeces are updated every six months, through a process known as rolling index. The rolling or rotation dates are March 20 and September 20 of each year. For example, the index series number 13 was launched on March 20, 2010, with maturity on June 20th, 2015 for 5 years contract. The maturities for the iTraxx Europe index and the HiVol index are at three, five, seven and ten 10 years, while for the Crossover index are only at five and at ten years. These indices are instruments traded at a predetermined fixed rate, and the prices of which, corresponding to the fair spreads on the indices, are determined by supply and demand of the market. The official quotation of the prices are made available on behalf of the IIC by Markit Group Limited on a daily basis, formed by the collection of information on prices, provided by the trading desks of the banks which are licensed as market makers.

Currently, the iTraxx CDS contract negotiation is limited to the OTC market. A bank, acting as market maker, quotes on its trading desk the bid and ask spread for the index on the basis of the requests received from investors, according to these two quotations, investors may decide to participate in the contract as counterparties of the market maker, selling or by buying protection on the index for a given notional amount on which is

CHAPTER 4. CREDIT RISK DERIVATES

82

applied the quoted spread of the index. In case do not verify any credit event for any of the companies issuing the reference securities of the CDSs that belong to the index, the protection buyer continue to perform the due payments until the maturity, computed as the spread multiplied by the notional value defined at the beginning of the contract. However, in case a credit event occurs for one or more index reference firms, from that time the subsequent payments done by the purchaser of the contract would be computed on the notional reduced by an amount equal to the percentage of the index that those firms represent. Thus in this iTraxx index case there would be a reduction equal to 0.8n%, with n equal to the number of the firms for which a credit event occurs. Alongside the market maker or the other part who is entitled as the protection seller, for each company for which a credit event occurs, he must make a payment calculated as the product of the notional amount and a certain percentage, which differs according to the settlement procedure set in the contract: in the case of cash settlement, the percentage due for each firm will be equal to (1 − R)p, with p equals to the percentage represented by the firm in the index and R representing the recovery rate on the reference financial instrument of the CDS and issued by the same specific firm; while in the case of physical settlement the buyer pays the seller a percentage p of the notional, in exchange of the delivery of the financial instruments issued by the firm of reference with a nominal value equal to the same amount paid.

4.3

The Collateral Debt Obbligation

For instance, another very common type of securities dependent on credit risk are the Credit Debt Obbligations (CDOs). These securities are made to share the credit risk on a portfolio of securities underlying the CDO, whose portfolio is divided into several classes of securities, in which to each class is assigned a different regulation of insolvency. A particular type of CDO is represented by the synthetic CDO whose underlying portfolio consists of CDSs contracts.

Chapter 5 Empirical Implementation
After having analyzed and discussed the different ways to tackle the problem of constructing a model for estimating the probability of default in univariate and multivariate setting, as well as having presented some of the most common types of derivatives dependent on the risk of default of a single firm, or more companies, now we present the construction of a model1 for the default intensity based on the framework of factor models. Under this type of models, we have that the intensity of occurrence of the default event, for each company, will be a function of some observable factors, for which we can observe historical realizations. For the determination of the coefficients, which determine the relationships between these factors and the levels of intensity, we estimate them by running some regression applied to reasonably motivated models and whose construction is also well established among the academics. Before estimating the coefficients of the univariate models of the intensity of default of individual firms considered, we deem to be compoulsary to perform a preliminary analysis of what are the factors affecting, and, without loss of generality, determine the trend in iTraxx Europe CDS index spreads. This is done in view of a use of the model in a multivariate framework, in which the relationship between the intensities derived from different dependencies that every company shows in relation to macroeconomic factors that represent the general economic trend.
For a discussion of estimation methods and tests carried out in the chapter, see Hamilton (1994), Fox (2008) and Gallo and Pacini (2002).
1

83

CHAPTER 5. EMPIRICAL IMPLEMENTATION

84

The companies considered for the construction of the factor models for the intensity are some2 of the companies in the financial sector, whose CDSs are part of the reference components of series 13 of the more liquid index of European CDSs presented in chapter (4.2), the iTraxx Europe. The data used for the analysis and construction of models have been fully downloaded from the Datastream database, while the estimates and analysis were performed using the freeware R-labstat.

5.1

Analysis of the Trend for the iTraxx Europe

In this section we construct a model for estimating the determinants of logarithmic changes, or logarithmic yields, of the spreads of iTraxx Europe index. Bystrom (2005) was the first to propose a linear regression model to study the link between the spread of a set of CDSs, related to several firms, and the stock market, verifying the presence of a significant positive autocorrelation between the yield of the spread of the iTraxx indices, i.e. that they are autoregressive (AR). Other authors, including Alexander and Kaeck (2008), have shown that there is a negative relationship with risk-free interest rates, and the presence of a positive link with the volatility of stock returns, which in turn is positively associated with the volatility of the logarithmic changes of the value of the firms’ assets. All these models assume, however, that the error terms of the estimated linear regressions have a normal distribution, when in fact, as noted in the literature for financial time series of stock returns, the returns on the CDS show different trends: in fact can be observed the presence of the phenomenon of volatility cluster, which had already been addressed by the Autoregressive Conditional Heteroskedasticity(ARCH) model proposed by Engle (1982) and the Generalized Autoregressive Conditional Heteroskedasticity(GARCH) model proposed by Bollerslev (1986). The presence of volatility cluster implies large tail (heavy tail)3 in the empirical distribution of the residuals, which is incompatible with the use of
I have not been able to build models for all financial firms in the index iTraxx Europe, because for some of them I did not have the necessary data. 3 An indicator of the presence of the so-called fat tail or heavy tail in a distribution is the kurtosis (Kurtosis).
2

CHAPTER 5. EMPIRICAL IMPLEMENTATION

85

a theoretical normal distribution for the errors, but which makes more appropriate the use of a Student’s-t distribution, which permits the presence of thick tails in the distribution of residuals. Furthermore, empirical evidence shows the presence of high asymmetry, that is a level of the skewness4 very different from 0, whise level, in order to be considered in the analysis of the residuals, make necessary the use of a distribution that admits a flexible choice for the skewness level, such as the asymmetric Student’s-t distribution proposed by Hansen (1994). The residuals analysis concludes with the presentation of the main tests that verify the ”robustness” of the considerations made above. Finally, in addition to an implementation on the entire sample period of data available in the database, we present also comparison with two subsamples, in fact we split the data in the period before the crisis and in the crisis period.

Analysis of the Data for the Model The daily data used for my analysis are: 1. the spreads of the iTraxx Europe index, expressed in basic points (BP, 10−4 ), with which it is calculated both the time series of the logarithmic return (spread return), which represents the dependent variable of the models, and the time series of lagged spread return (spread lag-return) used as independent variable; 2. the quote of the Stoxx Europe 600, which is an European stock index of 600 leading European companies; 3. quotations, expressed in percentage points (10−2 ), of the Volatility Index, Vstoxx, which is an index of the implied volatility derived from options on the shares of the main European stock index, Stoxx Europe 600. The Vstoxx index is a useful tool to represent the forecast of the market concerning the short-term volatility of stock returns. This index is used as an independent variable in the final model;
The degree of skewness of a distribution is defined as the value of the parameter λ, which is an indicator of the level of symmetry or asymmetry of the distribution considered. In particular, with λ = 0 we have perfect symmetry, as is the case for the Normal distribution and the Student’s-t distribution, while with λ > 0 and λ < 0 we have respectively positive asymmetry and negative asymmetry, or equivalently if the mode is shifted towards the minimum or the maximum of the distribution.
4

CHAPTER 5. EMPIRICAL IMPLEMENTATION

86

4. the quotes of the EMU Benchmark index, which is an index of government bonds with five year maturity, used as an independent variable in the model; 5. quotes for the 12, 6 and 3 months Euribor, but the 12 months one loses significance when is introduced in the models the independent variable EMU Benchmark; 6. the quotes of the EONIA rate, not significant as an independent variable 7. the quotes of other indicators for the risk-free rates, for the trend of stock prices and other macroeconomic indicators, which result not to be significant as independent variables of the model. The complete time period considered for the analysis is from 2005-03-23 to 2010-11-11 for a total of 1472 daily observations available, and the period for the the pre-crisis analysis goes from 2005-03-23 to 2007-03-07 and for the the crisis period the observations range from 2007-03-08 to 11/11/2010 for a total of 961 and 511 daily data considered. The macroeconomic factors, included as independent variables in the multivariate model, are all resulted significant as determinants of the CDS spread returns at the univariate level. The variables 12-months Euribor and one year EONIA swap index, although they are found to be significant at the univariate level, when it is introduced as an independent variable representing the performance of risk-free interest rates, the EMU benchmark index of government bonds with maturity 5 years, both the other variables become insignificant or at least not very significant, but in any case highly non-significant compared with the index of government bonds, which are linked by a negative relationship characterized by a slight negative correlation. The variables considered as determinants in the final model for estimating the dependent variable corresponding to the logarithmic returns of the iTraxx Europe index spreads, are logarithmic returns/changes of: 1. index Stoxx Europe 600 2. Vstoxx Volatility Index 3. index EMU for the benchmark government bond with maturity 5 years

CHAPTER 5. EMPIRICAL IMPLEMENTATION

87

The table (5.1) presents some descriptive statistics of the dependent variable and independent variables. Figure (5.1) show the trends of the variables. iTraxx EU Stoxx EU 600 Vstoxx Vol. Ind. Emu Bench. 5YR -0.32586 -0.07930 -0.24919 -0.01143 -0.01518 -0.00553 -0.03384 -0.00118 -0.00037 0.00046 -0.00365 0.0000 0.00069 0.00003 0.00036 0.00006 0.01679 0.00606 0.027038 0.00128 0.25536 0.09410 0.32767 0.00905 0.03929 0.01372 0.05785 0.00211 -0.28267 -0.07873 0.94745 -0.09333 9.79360 7.41218 3.88415 2.07370 Table 5.1: Descriptive Statistcs of the Logarithmic Returns Afterwards in the table (5.2) we consider both the test statistics that verify the absence of a Normal distribution behaviour of the empirical distributions of the variables, the JarqueBera normality test (JB test), and those that show the absence of a mean-reverting trend in the returns, the Augmented Dickey-Fuller test (ADF test). From the results of the p-values of the test statistics can be observed that all variables have a distribution significantly different from the Normal, and that trends of the variables are significantly mean-reverting, that is they can now be considered stationary. Figure (5.2) shows the possible fit to empirical distributions through the use of theoretical distributions, Normal and Student’s-t, noting that the Student’s-t (green curve) has a more appropriate fit than the Normal (red curve) for the empirical distributions of all variables, except for the performance of the Benchmark Emu 5YR, so only in the latter case it seems appropriate a Normal. iTraxx EU Stoxx EU 600 Vstoxx Vol. Ind. Emu Bench. 5YR 5923.33 3384.09 1150.46 267.65 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 greater greater greater greater -10.32 -11.09 -11.41 -11.10 stationary stationary stationary stationary 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.01 Table 5.2: Normality test and Mean Reverting test

Min. 1st Qu. Median Mean 3rd Qu. Max. Std.Dev Skewness Kurtosis

J-B Test p-value Alternative ADF Test Alternative p-value≤

CHAPTER 5. EMPIRICAL IMPLEMENTATION

88

Analysis and estimation of the model In Figure (5.3) can be observed the graphs representing the relationships between independent variables and the dependent variable, graphically checking the presence of a particular relation. In particular, we note that, as stated previously, the trend of the dependent variable is positively associated with both the returns of the volatility index and with the returns of the index of government bonds, as these are negatively linked to the performance of risk-free interest rate, while the relationship with the returns on the stock turns out to be negative. This link between the independent variable and the dependent variable suggested in the data analysis and verified graphically in Figure (5.3), turns out to be confirmed by the linear regression estimation, whose results are shown in Table (5.3), in which are also included as independent variable one day lagged returns (lag1-return) of the CDSs index spread. The addition of this variable in the regression was carried out because, by testing the Durbin-Watson test for autocorrelation of residuals in the table (5.4), we noted the presence of first-order autocorrelation in the residuals, while after that is added the variable lag1-return spread, we do not note further significant autocorrelation in the residuals. Finally, the model considered is the following:

Yt = α1 X1,t + α2 X2,t + α3 Yt−1 + α4 X3,t + εt

(5.1)

where the dependent variable Yt is the log-return of the iTraxx Europe CDSs index, the independent variables X1,t , X2,t , Yt−1 , X3,t are respectively the Stoxx Europe 600 Index log-returns, the log-returns of the Vstoxx Volatility Index, the one day lagged log-return of the dependent variable and the log-return on the EMU benchmark for the government bonds with 5 years of maturity, while α1 , α2 , α3 , α4 are the linear coefficients of the respective independent variables and εt is the error term of the model, i.e. the residuals that will be analyzed at the end of chapter. From the the p-values, all the independent variables included in the model are significant at a 0.1% significance level, confirming to be highly determinants with respect to the the pattern of the iTraxx Europe index spread.

CHAPTER 5. EMPIRICAL IMPLEMENTATION

89

The value of R2 -adjusted, which represents the degree of explanation of the time series of the dependent variable captured by the estimated model, is 0.39. This value for R2 adjusted is sufficiently high for this type of models, in which it is estimated the trend of a portfolio of CDS spreads, in addition, this value is consistent with what is found by the academics for other estimation models of multivariate spreads, which may include other determinants of macroeconomic factors as independent variables. Estimate Std. Error t value Pr(> |t|) (Intercept) 0.0003 0.0006 0.5534 0.5800 Stoxx Europe 600 -1.0688 0.0697 -15.34 0.0000 Vstoxx Volatility Index 0.0686 0.0156 4.39 0.0000 Lag iTraxx Europe 0.1394 0.0148 9.39 0.0000 Emu Benchmark 5YR 3.0079 0.3192 9.42 0.0000 Table 5.3: Estimated regression model with robust Standard Errors Model with Lag spread return Model without Lag spread return statistic 1.88 2.10 method Durbin-Watson test Durbin-Watson test alternative true autocorrelation is greater than 0 true autocorrelation is greater than 0 p.value 0.01 0.97 Table 5.4: Autocorrelation Test of residuals Finally, with the residual of the model we verify that, along with first-order autocorrelation, there is also heteroscedasticity in the variance (volatility heteroskedasticity) of the residuals of the final model. For this analysis, using the test of Breusch and Pagan (1979) for the null hypothesis of homoskedasticity, we observe that this hypothesis can be rejected because the p-value of the test statistic is equal to 1.678e−10 , making acceptable the assumption of heteroscedasticity in the variance of the residuals of the model, as confirmed also by the significant parameters of the GARCH(1,1) estimated over the residuals, for which we have not reported the results. The model estimates were also carried out in the two subperiods of the sample of the available data. The first period, called pre-crisis, in which the financial crisis had not yet unleashed in all its drama, but it was only the beginning of the series of write-downs

CHAPTER 5. EMPIRICAL IMPLEMENTATION

90

and failures induced by the increasing difficulty of the subprime mortgage market, to be passed up well in adverse impact on the entire financial sector, starting from Wall Street. This period covers the time period between the initial date of the sample, the 2005-03-23 until the date 2007-03-07. The latter date was chosen because in the following weeks of March, 2007, there were the first signs of the sharp deterioration of the crisis, which began to be felt heavily on quotes on major markets, as stated in Repubblica (2007). Moreover, in the same month, the first U.S. real estate companies to succumb to the crisis, due to the huge rescaling properties values in the U.S.A., were New Century Financial and Accredited Home Lenders Holding, and finally there was a weak increase in retail sales in February, below expectations, which has contributed to a loss of 1.98% on the U.S. Dow Jones stock index. The second period covers the time period from 2007-08-03 to 2010-11-11, when the financial crisis has made us feel its worst effects, derailing many banks, companies, without excluding even sovereign debt, we can recall the bankruptcy of Lehman Brothers and Iceland among all the events that followed, till have a also negative impact on real economy. The table (5.5) presents the results of the estimates in the periods described above, noting that even in this case, all coefficients are significant now at the 5% for both periods. The value of R2 -adjusted amounted respectively to a lower value of 0.181 in pre-crisis period, and to an higher value of 0.42 during the crisis. Furthermore, may be observed that: • the negative influence of the trend of the Stoxx Europe index is more than halved in absolute terms in the pre-crisis period than both the period of the crisis and the entire sample of observations;

• the coefficient of returns of the volatility index, Vstoxx Volatility Index, is higher, as expected, during the crisis period compared to the pre-crisis period, while the coefficient in the pre-crisis period is quite close to the value for the entire period;

CHAPTER 5. EMPIRICAL IMPLEMENTATION

91

• the trend of European government bonds index, Emu Benchmark 5YR, has a positive effect on the spreads in a more pronounced way during the crisis and in the complete sample, compared to that observed for the pre-crisis period;

• the positive coefficient of one-day lag-returns of the spread of the index, Lag iTraxx Europe, confirms the presence of positive first order autocorrelation in the spreads, which appear to be more sensitive to this phenomenon in the pre-crisis period, rather than during the crisis and during the entire sample. Pre-crisis Model Estimate Std. Error t value Pr(> |t|) (Intercept) -0.0003 0.0006 -0.47 0.6400 Stoxx Europe 600 -0.4581 0.1318 -3.47 0.0006 Vstoxx Volatility Index 0.0651 0.0191 3.41 0.0007 Lag iTraxx Europe 0.2448 0.0280 8.73 0.0000 Emu Benchmark 5YR 1.1788 0.4058 2.91 0.0000 Crisis Model Estimate Std. Error t value Pr(> |t|) (Intercept) -0.0007 0.0009 -0.79 0.4310 Stoxx Europe 600 -0.9934 0.0952 -10.44 0.0000 Vstoxx Volatility Index 0.1193 0.0236 5.06 0.0000 Lag iTraxx Europe 0.1257 0.0196 6.40 0.0000 Emu Benchmark 5YR 3.2851 0.4576 7.18 0.0000 Table 5.5: Comparison between pre-crisis and crisis model After having verified that the residuals of the estimated model for the evolution of the returns of the spreads of the CDSs index show first order autocorrelation, AR(1), and having found that the conditional variance of the estimates do follow a GARCH(1,1) process, we estimate the AR(1)-GARCH(1,1) models for the entire period. The estimate of the latter, having been implemented using the usual normal distribution for the residuals of the regression, is tested with some test-statistcs, which we will discuss later, for the presence of a different distribution for the residuals. For these reasons, it is initially considered a standard Student’s-t distribution, then we consider a more suitable asymmetric distribution, the Skewed Student’s-t proposed by Hansen (1994), whose higher performance was

CHAPTER 5. EMPIRICAL IMPLEMENTATION confirmed by the tests we carried out.

92

From Table (5.8) can be observed that the coefficients of the first order autocorrelation of the conditional mean of the spreads returns, ar1, of first-order ARCH effect, α1, and of the first-order GARCH effect, β1, of the conditional variance are all significant at the 1% level and positive. As is usual for financial time series, we observe that the sum of the estimated parameters for the ARCH and GARCH effects, equals to 0.9989, is close to the unit and we also have that the parameter of the GARCH effect, that is the influence of lagged conditional variance on the conditional variance, is much higher than the ARCH effect parameter, namely the effect of lagged squared residuals, this implies the presence of the phenomenon of persistence in the volatility of the CDS index spreads returns, i.e. there is presence of the so-called clusters of volatility, for which certain levels of volatility persistently affect its levels in subsequent periods. All the three periods models AR(1)-GARCH(1,1) estimated for the residuals of the model for the index CDSs spreads are well specified, as both the Ljung-Box tests for the presence of additional autocorrelation in the conditional mean and in the conditional variance, and the test ARCH-LM for the presence of additional heteroscedasticity, are highly significant at a level of 5%, as shown in Tables (5.6), (5.7), (5.8). Concerning the more appropriate distribution to be used for the regression AR(1)-GARCH(1,1), as can be seen from the results of the highly significant level both for the estimates of the degrees of freedom, ν (shape), which with a value of 6.03 reveals the presence of large tails in the empirical distribution, and for the estimate in the case of Skewed Students’s-t distribution of the skewness value λ (skew), which with a value of 1.05 shows a positive asymmetric tendency of the residuals distribution. For this reason we state that between the use of either a Normal or a standard Student’s-t or a asymmetric Student’s-t distribution, the use of the latter is the more appropriate for the estimation.

The above statement is confirmed by the other tests carried out. From the tables (5.6), (5.7), (5.8), we can observe that the test diagnostic Pearson goodness-of-fit (GOF) to ver-

CHAPTER 5. EMPIRICAL IMPLEMENTATION

93

ify that the theoretical distribution used is consistent with the empirical distribution of standardized residuals, is significant only in the case of Skewed Student’s-t. Furthermore, the values of the Akiko Information Criteria (AIC) and of the Lof-Likelihood (LogLik) to test the goodness of the fit of the model, confirm that the model with Skewed Student’s-t is the best, while the model with the Normal is the worst in terms of performance.

Finally, we perform some tests on the residuals of the AR(1)-GARCH(1,1) model in order to test the adequacy of the choice of the theoretical distribution. In the table (5.9) are reported the results of the Jarque-Bera test to verify the normality of the distribution of the residuals of the model, in which the theoretical distribution used is the Normal, and the corresponding Kolmogorov- Smirnov (KS) test to verify both the use of Standard Student’s-t and the use of the Skewed Student’s-t. From the results of the tests is confirmed, once again, that the use of the Skewed Student’s-t is the more appropriate for the construction of a model AR(1)-GARCH(1,1), which is able to capture the cluster in the volatility and the autocorrelation in the residuals of the model for the trend of the spread.

CHAPTER 5. EMPIRICAL IMPLEMENTATION

94

5.2

Factorial Model for the Intensity of Default
After having analyzed the factors determining the behavior of

Model Presentation

iTraxx Europe index spreads, we build up a model at the univariate level for the intensity of default of certain financial companies, which are part of the CDSs reference portfolio of the index, to which are added two Italian banking firms, Mediobanca and Banca Popolare di Milano. Those intensities are considered to be determined by both time-varying macroeconomic factors, which are in accordance with what is found in the previous chapter (5.1), and by a specific factor of the firm’s risk which varies over time.

The model considered for the intensity of default is a model with an exponential acceleration factor, which is determined by macroeconomic factors common to all firms and by a specific factor for each firm. The acceleration factor determines the positive or negative shocks to the normal trend (or base value), where the latter is the average trend observed for the intensity. The use of an exponential form for the acceleration factor can prevent the intensity from taking negative values, and this assumption for the construction of estimation models for the intensity of default is also very common among the academics, in fact this functional form was used, among the others, by Azizpour et al. (2010). Therefore, we have that the intensity λi for the i-th firm at time t is t λi = λi Υt t Υt = exp αi + γi Sti + θi Ct + εi (5.2)

where Υt corresponds to the acceleration factor that determines the deviations at time t of the intensity of default with respect to its base value of λi . In addition, this acceleration factor is assumed to be an exponential function, depending on: • the specific factor for the firm i, Sti • the macroeconomic factor that affects all the firms, Ct , which is constant in time,

CHAPTER 5. EMPIRICAL IMPLEMENTATION

95

• the values of the coefficients αi , γi and θi , estimated for each firm at the initial evaluation time t. Thus we assume that the acceleration factor varies with changing conditions of the environment in which the companies operate, and that the influence that those changes have on the value of the acceleration factor remain constant over time, since the coefficients in the model are assumed to be constant, this implies that the acceleration factor maintains constant its exponential functional form. For these reasons, we can consider Υt as a random variable, whose distribution depends on the distribution of the factors Sti , Ct . What we are interested in building a model for the default intensity concerns the estimation of a probability distribution for the default of a company or of a portfolio of companies, for which we may want to evaluate a risky bond or a credit risk derivative. Therefore we want to try to forecast what could be the future default probability over a given time horizon. Considering the reduced form models presented in chapter (2), we assume an exponential form for the probability of default that has ”no memory”, which means that it should not depend on the time passed without the company is bankrupt, that is independent of the ”operational seniority” of the firm. From equation (2.6) for the probability of survival, we obtain the probability of default before time τ to be equal to

P (τ ≤ t) = 1 − P (τ > t) = = 1 − e− t 0

λ(s)ds

(5.3) t 0

Assuming that there has been no default up to t and that Γ(t) =

λ(s)ds, we obtain that

the conditional probability of default in the interval [t, t + ∆t] is5 P (τ ∈ [t, t + ∆t]) P (τ ≥ t) t+∆t P (τ ∈ [t, t + ∆t]|τ ≥ t) =

= 1 − exp(− t 5

λ(s)ds)

(5.4)

We remind that in (2.7) we found the conditional default probability relative to an infinitesimal interval, by the use of the formula for first order approximation of Taylor.

CHAPTER 5. EMPIRICAL IMPLEMENTATION

96

This exponential form for the probability of default is with ”no memory” if and only if it does not depend on time t, i.e. if and only if Γ(t) does not depend on the time passed over the interval, hence considering that the intensity remains constant in the interval ∆t considered. Therefore, we have that the intensity will have a particular form piecewise constant for each time horizon [t, T ], for which the estimated probability of default within a specified maturity T , will change depending on the value assumed by the intensity at time t, which in turn, after having set a base value, λ for the level of the intensity during ”normal” conditions of the economy, will depend on the value assumed in t by the acceleration factor of the state economy Υt defined above.

As a final result we obtain a model in which once defined the probability distribution of the acceleration factor and its determinants (macroeconomic factors and firm-specific factors), we obtain the probability distribution for the future value of the intensity, which gives us the probability of default for a specified time horizon, assuming that during this period the intensity remains constant. This procedure ensures that at any point in time where we know the value of the macroeconomic factors and firm-specific factors, we are able to determine either an hypothetical probability of default present at that moment, either its expected value for the next instant, obtained from the forecasted probability distribution of future values for the intensity.

Model Estimation The data used to estimate the model have a daily basis frequence and cover the period from 2007-12-176 until 2010-11-11, for a total of 759 daily observations. As macroeconomic variable we consider the index of European government bonds with maturity 5 years, Emu Benchmark 5YR, Ct , already used in chapter (5.1), while has been excluded with respect to the model of the trend of iTraxx Eurpoe index spreads, the trend
We have taken out of the sample the first observation of 2007-12-14, as this was used to estimate the GARCH(1,1) one-step-ahead volatility of the return of the firms’ stocks.
6

CHAPTER 5. EMPIRICAL IMPLEMENTATION

97

of the Stoxx Europe 600 index for stock prices, which in this case resulted not significant at both univariate and multi-level, the index of the European equity market volatility, Vstoxx, since in some cases it was not performing well as an independent variable of the model. As a specific factor, Sti , we use the index of the riskiness of the firm-specific returns, represented by the implied annual volatility, which we estimate with a GARCH(1,1) applied to the residuals of the Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM)7 for the expected excess return for the company in relation to the risk-free return. The model for the CAPM is estimated using the following linear regression for each firm i

R i − R f = a + β i R m − R f + ui

(5.5)

where • Ri is the daily return for the firm i, equal to the daily logarithmic changes in the prices quoted • Rf is the daily logarithmic change for the risk-free rate, for which we used the risk-free rate EON IA • Rm is the daily return of the reference stock index for the firm i • ui are the residuals of the regression for the firm i As can be seen from equation (5.5), the residuals of the CAPM can be considered as an adequate proxy for firm-specific return, as they capture the share of performance of the excess of return not captured by the model, for instance by the Market Beta and the beta Market Premium. After having obtained the residuals we checked that their variance presented autocorrelation and heteroscedasticity, that is statistically significant parameters for both the ARCH and GARCH factor of the estimated GARCH (1,1). Then with this model we compoute the one-step-ahead forecasts for the conditional variance of
7

See Fama and MacBeth (1973) for a presentation of the model.

CHAPTER 5. EMPIRICAL IMPLEMENTATION

98

the residuals of the CAPM, from which we obtain the annual implied volatility for each firm. The model presented in equation (5.2) can then be rewritten as follows λi t λi

ln

= αi + γi Sti + θi Ct + εi

(5.6) λi t , λi

The dependent variable of the model appears to be the logarithm of the ratio

that

can be calculated from the time series of the prices of CDSs spreads for each firm i. This statement comes from the fact that, as in Walker (2005), we are in the context of the simplified case of piecewise constant hazard rate, which is approximated at the first order of the Taylor expansion formula for a very small values of the spreads. The latter approximation is admissible since the spreads are usually quoted in bp, hence very close to zero. Then without considering the counterparty risk we get that the spread at the time t for a time to maturity T , can be expressed as a function of λt , through the following equation st = (1 − ρ)(λt T ) (5.7)

where ρ is the recovery rate. From this relation, assuming a constant recovery rate for each company i in the observed time period, then the dependent variable of our model can be estimated from time series of spreads with time to maturity of five years, since the following relation is valid for the initial intensity at time t = 0 λi 0 = λi ⇓ λi si 0 = 0 λi si (5.8) si 0 (1−ρ)T si (1−ρ)T

where si is the value of the spread for the firm i, stripped from quotes at the time t = 0 0 of the CDSs, while si is the average spread for the firm i in the sample period. The CDSs considered have a 5 years maturity, coherently with the maturity of the spread for the index

CHAPTER 5. EMPIRICAL IMPLEMENTATION

99

of CDSs analysed in the chapter (5.1). In the table (5.10) are presented in alphabetical order the firms of the financial sector, with the estimates of the parameter γi for the firmspecific factor, the parameter θi for the macroeconomic factor, with the respective standard error and t-statistic, and also the R2 -adjusted as an indicator of the level of explanation of the dependent variable captured by the estimated model. From the estimation results we may observe that all the parameters of the independent variables, which determine the course of the acceleration factor, are positive. With regard to macroeconomic factors, this result is consistent with what is found in section (5.1) for the multivariate case, while for the firm-specific factor is logical to expect that an increase in the volatility, i.e. the risk of a company, involves an acceleration of the intensity of default, thus an higher probability of default. Almost all the parameters are significant at a level of 0.01%, with the exception of the parameter of the specific factor γi for Credit Agricole, which it is still significant at a satisfactory level of 5%, generally accepted as discriminant significance level in the inference of linear regression models. We also note that the values of R2 -adjusted, are on average high, with an average value for it of 0.408 and a maximum value for Aegon of 0.676, while we also find for Commerzbank and Hannover Ruck, respectively, 0157 and 0.162, which are fairly low level compared to the rest of the sample, but even not too much low for this type of model. After having performed the estimation for the model of the acceleration factor of the intensity, we want to forecast the distribution probability of default for a specified time to maturity or to default. For example, suppose we want to estimate the probability of default within a year valid at a future date. Assuming that the intensity does not change until that date, then the future probability is estimated using a simulation of the possible values that the acceleration factor could take. The acceleration factor’s distribution in turn depend on the multivariate distribution of the factors Sti and Ct , for which usually no one knows neither the univariate nor the joint distribution. To get their univariate distributions, we have made tests using some theoretical distributions to fit the empirical univariate distribution, for which no satisfactory results have been obtained, we therefore

CHAPTER 5. EMPIRICAL IMPLEMENTATION

100

decided to use the empirical distributions from the hystoric series. From the other hand to estimate the joint distribution, we chose to fit a theoretical copula to their univariate empirical distributions. The copula that shows the best fit among those considered8 is the Gumbel copula with estimated parameter s = 1.8413. After the estimation of the copula and having simulated with this a series of 1000 realizations, then from this series by applying the univariate empirical quantiles of the 199 variables of the model, we obtain a series of realizations for the acceleration factor. Then we derive the realizations of the intensity with which we calculate as many values for the probability of default within one year for each company i. We are therefore able to forecast the probability distribution of a future default, for which the graphs for each company sorted in alphabetical order, as shown in the Table (5.10), can be found in Figure (5.5) and are comparable with the historical distribution plots shown in Figure (5.4). In Table (5.11) we show for each firm, the average value of the probability distribution of the default, with their standard error and, for comparison, the value of the current default probabilities, calculated with the data availble up to 2010 − 11 − 11.

Finally, we show in Figure (5.6) the graph of the joint distribution for three of the major players in the insurance industry, Assicurazioni Generali, Allianz, Swiss Re. This distribution can be compared with the joint distribution of the estimated probability of future default, whose graph is shown in Figure (5.7), in which may note common trend for the default probabilities of the firms, which also unveils high likelihood for low values of the marginal probability of default of individual firms. Furthermore, by comparing these graphs with the graph (5.8) of a simulation of the threevariate fitted theoretical copula, it can be confirmed that we have correctly specify the copula to represent the trend of the multivariate probability of default. We also note that the joint probabilities of default tend
We have used the following copulas: from the family of the Archimedean copulas the Gumbel, the Clayton and the Frank, while among the elliptical copulas we have considered the Gaussian and the Student’s-t. 9 We consider the 18 specific factors, and the only macroeconomic common factor.
8

CHAPTER 5. EMPIRICAL IMPLEMENTATION

101

to dispose along a diagonal with positive slope with respect to the univariate probabilities, even if compared to the Gumbel the joint probabilities tend to take more frequently low values. The latter observations represent the possibility of a contagion among firms, also for low levels of default risk. In Figures (5.9), (5.10) and (5.11) are reported the graphs of the bivariate joint densities, estimated through the copula. We observe a trend compatible with the assumption of the Gumbel copula to model the dependence of the variables that determine the acceleration factor and then the joint probabilities of the default of the firms. Finally we, once again, observe that the joint probability density, represented by the coloured surface, assumes high values also for low values of the univariate default probabilities of firms, still confirming the so far addressed contagion of the risk of default among firms.

CHAPTER 5. EMPIRICAL IMPLEMENTATION

102

Figure 5.1: Graphs for the variables’ trends

CHAPTER 5. EMPIRICAL IMPLEMENTATION

103

Figure 5.2: Graphs of the fitting distributions

CHAPTER 5. EMPIRICAL IMPLEMENTATION

104

Figure 5.3: Graphs of the relations with dependent variable

CHAPTER 5. EMPIRICAL IMPLEMENTATION

105

Conditional Dist. mu ar1 omega alpha1 beta1 LogLik AIC Q-Statistics SR Lag10 Lag15 Lag20 Q-Statistics SSR Lag10 Lag15 Lag20 ARCH LM Tests ARCH Lag[2] ARCH Lag[5] ARCH Lag[10] GOF Test: 1 2 3 4

Normal Estimate Std. Error -0.001443 0.000677 0.189487 0.032946 0.000023 0.000012 0.189852 0.037856 0.807865 0.034321 3110.309 -4.2192 statistic 8.218 17.694 21.138 statistic 9.317 9.917 13.627 Statistic 6.599 6.857 9.350 group 20 30 40 50 p-value 0.6075 0.2791 0.3890 p-value 0.5023 0.8250 0.8489 DoF 2 5 10

t value -2.1330 5.7515 2.0075 5.0151 23.5383

Pr(> |t|) 0.032926 0.000000 0.044692 0.000001 0.000000

P-Value 0.03689 0.23150 0.49928

statistic p-value(g-1 ) 83.03 5.562e-10 82.17 5.548e-07 91.37 4.346e-06 104.43 6.923e-06

Table 5.6: Normal AR(1)-GARCH(1,1)

CHAPTER 5. EMPIRICAL IMPLEMENTATION

106

Conditional Dist. t-Studend standard Estimate Std. Error t value mu -0.001639 0.000538 -3.0474 ar1 0.188104 0.029967 6.2770 omega 0.000009 0.000004 2.1625 alpha1 0.186755 0.031528 5.9234 beta1 0.812245 0.034538 23.5172 shape 6.028991 0.942216 6.3987 LogLik 3188.953 AIC -4.3247 Q-Statistics SR statistic p-value Lag10 7.246 0.7021 Lag15 16.120 0.3741 Lag20 19.731 0.4748 Q-Statistics SSR statistic p-value Lag10 6.098 0.8070 Lag15 6.700 0.9654 Lag20 8.755 0.9856 ARCH LM Tests Statistic DoF P-Value ARCH Lag[2] 3.481 2 0.1754 ARCH Lag[5] 4.055 5 0.5415 ARCH Lag[10] 6.011 10 0.8144 GOF Test: group statistic p-value(g-1 ) 1 20 52.84 4.954e-05 2 30 49.07 1.134e-02 3 40 64.58 6.158e-03 4 50 72.02 1.777e-02 Table 5.7: Standard Student’s t AR(1)-GARCH(1,1)

Pr(> |t|) 0.002309 0.000000 0.030578 0.000000 0.000000 0.000000

CHAPTER 5. EMPIRICAL IMPLEMENTATION

107

Conditional Dist. t-Studend skewed Estimate Std. Error t value mu -0.001381 0.000590 -2.3423 ar1 0.186734 0.029377 6.3564 omega 0.000009 0.000004 2.1370 alpha1 0.184933 0.031926 5.7925 beta1 0.814067 0.034817 23.3815 skew 1.046347 0.034503 30.3266 shape 6.030570 0.959776 6.2833 LogLik 3189.885 AIC -4.3246 Q-Statistics SR statistic p-value Lag10 7.249 0.7017 Lag15 16.265 0.3647 Lag20 19.864 0.4664 Q-Statistics SSR statistic p-value Lag10 6.172 0.8006 Lag15 6.760 0.9640 Lag20 8.858 0.9845 ARCH LM Tests Statistic DoF P-Value ARCH Lag[2] 3.600 2 0.1653 ARCH Lag[5] 4.152 5 0.5278 ARCH Lag[10] 6.082 10 0.8083 GOF Test: group statistic p-value(g-1 ) 1 20 40.47 0.002835 2 30 40.76 0.072283 3 40 51.86 0.081544 4 50 64.96 0.063030 Table 5.8: Skewed Student’s-t AR(1)-GARCH(1,1)

Pr(> |t|) 0.019165 0.000000 0.032601 0.000000 0.000000 0.000000 0.000000

Normal Standard Student’s-t Skewed Student’s-t method Jarque-Bera Normality Test Kolmogorov-Smirnov Test Kolmogorov-Smirnov Test statistic 8762.89 17.13 17.48 p.value 0.00 0.00 0.45 Table 5.9: Test for the consistency of the theoretical distribution

CHAPTER 5. EMPIRICAL IMPLEMENTATION
Firm Aegon N.V. Assicurazioni Generali S.p.a. Allianz SE Axa Banca Monte dei Paschi di Siena Banco Popolare di Milano Banco Santander Barclays Bank PLC BNP Paribas Commerzbank Credit Agricole Credit Suisse Group Ltd Deutsche Bank Hannover Ruck AG Mediobanca Societe Generale Swiss Reinsurance Comapny Ltd Zurich Financials γi 0.0135 0.0195 0.0144 0.0162 0.0102 0.0087 0.0118 0.0048 0.0027 0.0011 0.0013 0.0107 0.0067 0.0059 0.0207 0.0037 0.0162 0.0154 Std.Error 0.0003 0.0015 0.0006 0.0006 0.0017 0.0012 0.0012 0.0003 0.0005 0.0003 0.0007 0.0005 0.0004 0.0008 0.0013 0.0004 0.0006 0.0007 = 0.5 t-stat 38.84 12.58 25.82 25.33 6.12 7.03 9.50 18.57 5.70 3.751 1.918 22.89 15.08 7.61 15.77 8.25 19.69 22.85 = 0.01 θi 0.0331 0.0462 0.0173 0.0169 0.0606 0.0488 0.0560 0.02509 0.0456 0.0225 0.0373 0.0263 0.0322 0.0265 0.0515 0.0383 0.0283 0.0096 = 0.001 Std.Error 0.0021 0.0021 0.0016 0.0021 0.0022 0.0024 0.0018 0.0022 0.0018 0.0019 0.0019 0.0021 0.0017 0.0024 0.0024 0.0018 0.0035 0.0016 t-stat 16.07 22.10 10.54 7.88 28.03 20.62 30.51 11.46 25.19 11.90 19.69 12.31 19.03 11.028 21.86 21.55 8.19 5.88 R2 adjusted 0.676 0.426 0.475 0.461 0.508 0.361 0.556 0.358 0.460 0.157 0.349 0.430 0.413 0.162 0.462 0.391 0.360 0.407

108

Significance Level

Table 5.10: Estimates for the intensity of default’s model Firm Average probability Standard Error Present probability Aegon N.V. 0.02101 0.01353 0.01577 Assicurazioni Generali s.p.a. 0.00903 0.00300 0.01127 Allianz SE 0.00795 0.00253 0.00741 Axa 0.01174 0.00454 0.01007 Banca Monte dei Paschi di Siena 0.00901 0.00280 0.01145 Banco Popolare di Milano 0.00923 0.00277 0.01164 Banco Santander 0.01114 0.00370 0.01499 Barclays Bank PLC 0.01185 0.00440 0.01172 BNP Paribas 0.00724 0.00183 0.00910 Commerzbank 0.00904 0.00119 0.01027 Credit Agricole 0.00958 0.00180 0.01188 Credit Suisse Group Ltd 0.01061 0.00409 0.01020 Deutsche Bank 0.01045 0.00274 0.01147 Hannover Ruck AG 0.00719 0.00144 0.00795 Mediobanca 0.00957 0.00412 0.01207 Societe Generale 0.00961 0.00227 0.01157 Swiss Reinsurance Compant Ltd 0.01656 0.01278 0.01535 Zurich Financials 0.00978 0.00235 0.00852 Table 5.11: Estimated default probability

CHAPTER 5. EMPIRICAL IMPLEMENTATION

109

Figure 5.4: Empirical distribution of the default probability

CHAPTER 5. EMPIRICAL IMPLEMENTATION

110

Figure 5.5: Distribution of forecasted future default probability

CHAPTER 5. EMPIRICAL IMPLEMENTATION

111

Figure 5.6: Joint historical probability distribution of default

Figure 5.7: Joint forecasted probability distribution of default

CHAPTER 5. EMPIRICAL IMPLEMENTATION

112

Figure 5.8: Simulated Gumbel Copula with estimated parameter s = 1.8413

Figure 5.9: Joint Density for Generali-Allianz

CHAPTER 5. EMPIRICAL IMPLEMENTATION

113

Figure 5.10: Joint Density for Generali-Swiss RE

Figure 5.11: Joint Density for Allianz-Swiss RE

Chapter 6 Conclusion
In the thesis we discussed the use of models for estimating the risk of default, with a focus on the spread, which expresses the implied probability of default for a company. The quoted spread is, therefore, the market assessment for the probability of default of a risky asset issued by a company, thus the risky asset requires a certain level of return higher than the risk-free return. The aim of the thesis is to identify some methods for building up a model which could be imply to estimate the probability of default for single entity and multiple entities, based on statistical techniques widely accepted in literature, which include the use of a default intensity model for a single firm and copulas to consider a particular dependence structure of defaults by several firms. The approach eventually applied in the last part of dissertation is considered by some recent studies on the credit risk subject to be the most appropriate, even for its ease of implementation. In the first part of the dissertation we have discussed the theoretical framework of default models for the valutation of single default risk and single firm spread, explaining the reasons for the choice made for the estimation model and proposing possible alternatives, for which we have analyzed the strengths and drawbacks that arise in their implementation. Moreover we have analyzed some approaches to model the dependence between the defaults of several firms. In fact the joint default risk is reported to be widespread interest and fundamental study, especially in light of the events over the last years, when a single firm default, namely the

114

CHAPTER 6. CONCLUSION

115

increased risk of this, triggers a default contagion effect over several firms, leading to the phenomenon of default clustering. In recent years the use of copulas to model dependence is also stated in the credit risk models, because of the flexibility of the copula, which is explained by the consideration that we can build models for multiple default risk in two separated steps: first building single firm models; secondly introduce a certain structure of dependence through the copula. Thereafter we can obtain a multivariate model for the credit risk of a portfolio of firms, which is consistent both with the estimation of individual default risks and with the the presence of contagion between different levels of default risk. In the last part of the dissertation we have built a model for estimating the intensity of default, which in my opinion is the most appropriate amongst the multiple entities default’s models. The model is based on a factor model with an acceleration factor, the intensity of default, which is consistent with the market sentiment originated from the credit risk derivatives quotations. For this purpose We have used two different types of credit risk derivatives: the single firm CDSs of some European companies in the financial sector as a proxy for the single firm default; and the index of CDSs, the iTraxx Europe from whose spread we bootstrap the implicit multiple default risk. In particular We have tried to detect the presence of some trend in critical periods, selected with financial and economic criterion. We have implied the model to estimate the probability of default of a group of European banks and insurance companies. First we have estimated and forecast the single entities default of the firms, then in a second moment we have introduced an estimated and calibrated copula to model the joint probability of default. The result of my empirical application then verified the presence of contagion between the probability of default, resulting in a trend of significant joint default risk for several firms. The model outcomes also confirm what I had found also for the iTraxx index analysis, previously performed in the dissertation. Finally, from the arguments treated in the dissertation and the final empirical application, we can state that the cluster of default brings about persistent trends of spread changes in some critical periods, when a cluster is due to the variation of the joint probability of default of a group or a index of reference entities, furthermore the

CHAPTER 6. CONCLUSION

116

multiple default probability is also linked to the single entity default probabilities, which tend to jointly change because of contagion effects which last over some time, depending on the financial and economic enviroment condition.

Bibliography
Alexander C.; Kaeck A. (2008). Regimes dependent determinants of credit default swap spreads. Journal of Banking and Finance, 32, 1008–1021. Azizpour S.; Giesecke K.; Schwenkler G. (2010). Exploring the sources of default clustering. Relazione tecnica, Stanford University. Bayes T. (1763). An essay towards solving a problem in the doctrine of chances. by the late rev. mr. bayes, f. r. s. communicated by mr. price, in a letter to john canton. A. M. F. R. S., Philosophical Transactions, Giving Some Account of the Present Undertakings, Studies and Labours of the Ingenious in Many Considerable Parts of the World., 53, 370–418. Black F.; Cox J. (1976). Valuing corporate securities: Some effects of bond indenture provisions. Journal of Finance, 31, 351–367. Black F.; Scholes M. (1973). The pricing of options and corporate liabilities. Journal of Political Economy, 81, 637–654. Bollerslev T. (1986). Generalized autoregressive conditional heteroskedasticity. Journal of Econometrics, 31, 351–367. Breusch T.; Pagan A. (1979). A simple test for heteroscedasticity and random coefficient variation. Econometrica, 47, 1287–1294. Brigo D.; Pallavicini A.; Torresetti R. (2007). The dynamical generalized-poisson loss model, part one. introduction and cdo calibration. Risk Magazine, June. 117

BIBLIOGRAPHY

118

Brody D.; Hughston L.; Macrina A. (2005). Beyond hazard rates: a new framework for credit-risk modelling. working paper. Relazione tecnica, King’s College London and Imperial College London. Bystrom H. (2005). Credit default swaps and equity prices: the itraxx cds index market. Relazione tecnica, Working Papers, Lund University, Department of Economics. Cox J. C.; Ross S. A. (1976). The valuation of options for alternative stochastic processes. Journal of Financial Economics, 3(1-2), 145 – 166. Cox J. C.; Ingersoll J. E.; Ross S. A. (1985). A theory of the term structure of interest rates. Econometrica, vol. 53, n. 2, 385–407. Davis M.; Lo V. (1999). Modelling default correlation in bond portfolios, working paper. Relazione tecnica, Tokyo-Mitsubitshi International. Davis M.; Lo V. (2001). Infectious defaults. Quantitative Finance, 1, 382–386. Ding X.; Giesecke K.; Tomecek P. (2009). Time-changed birth processes and multi-name credit derivatives. Operations Research, 57(4), 990–1005. Duan J. (1994). Maximum likelihood estimation using price data of the derivative contract. Mathematical Finance, 4, 155–167. Duan J. C.; Gauthier G.; Simonato J. G.; Zaanoun S. (2002). Maximum likelihood estimation of structural credit spread models: Deterministic and stochastic interest rates. Relazione tecnica, Working Paper. Duffee G. R. (1999). Estimating the price of default risk. The Review of Financial Studies, 12(1), 197–226. Duffie D.; Singleton K. J. (1999). Simulating correlated defaults, working paper. Relazione tecnica, Graduate School of Business, Stanford University.

BIBLIOGRAPHY

119

Duffie D.; Eckner A.; Saita G. H. L. (2009). Frialty correlate default. Journal of Finance, 83, 635–665. Duffie J.; Lando D. (2001). Term structure of credit spreads with incomplete accounting information. Econometrica, 69,3, 633–664. Eberhart A.; Moore W.; Roenfeldt R. (1990). Security pricing and deviations from the absolute priority rule in bankruptcy proceedings. The Journal of Finance, 45(5), 1457– 1469. Embrechts P.; McNeil A.; Straumann D. (1999). Correlation and dependence in risk management: Properties and pitfalls. Relazione tecnica, Preprint ETH Zurich. Engle R. (1982). Autoregressive conditional heteroskedasticity with estimates of variance of united kingdome inflation. Econometrica, 50, 987–1008. Ericsson J.; Reneby J. (2001). Estimating structural bond pricing models. Relazione tecnica, Working paper McGill University. Errais E.; Giesecke K.; Goldberg L. (2006). Affine point processes and portfolio credit risk. working paper. Relazione tecnica, Stanford University. Fama E.; MacBeth J. (1973). Risk, return and equilibrium: Empirical tests. Journal of Political Economy, 81, 115–146. Fox J. (2008). Applied Regression Analysis and Generalized Linear Models, Second Edition. Sage. Frees E. W.; Valdez E. A. (1998). Understanding relationships using copulas. North American Actuarial Journal, 2, 1–25. Frey R.; McNeil A. J. (2001). Modelling dependent defaults, working paper. Relazione tecnica, Department of Mathematics, ETHZ, Zurich. Gallo G. M.; Pacini B. (2002). Metodi quantitativi per i mercati finanziari. Carocci.

BIBLIOGRAPHY

120

Giesecke K. (2004). Correlated default with incomplete information. Journal of Banking and Finance, 28, 1521–1545. Giesecke K.; Goldberg L. (2004a). Forecasting default in the face of uncertainty. The Journal of Derivatives, 12(1), 1–15. Giesecke K.; Goldberg L. (2005). A top down approach to multi-name credit. Relazione tecnica, Working paper. Giesecke K.; Goldberg L. (2006). Default and information. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 30(11), 2281–2303. Giesecke K.; Goldberg L. R. (2004b). Sequential defaults and incomplete information. Journal of Risk, 7, 1–26. Giesecke K.; Goldberg L.; Ding X. (2010). A top-down approach to multi-name credit. Relazione tecnica, Operations Research, forthcoming. Halperin I.; Tomecek P. (2008). Climbing down from the top: Single name dynamics in credit top down models. Relazione tecnica, JP Morgan quantitiative research. Hamilton J. (1994). Time Series Analysis. Princeton University Press, Princeton. Hansen B. (1994). Autoregressive conditional density estimation. International Economic Review, 35, 705–730. Hsu; Sa´ -Requejo; Santa-Clara P. (2004). Bond pricing with default risk. working paper. a Relazione tecnica, UCLA. Hull J.; White A. (2001). Valuing credit default swaps ii: Modelling default correlations. Journal of Derivatives, 8, 12–22. Hull J.; Nelken I.; White A. (2003). Merton’s model, credit risk, and volatility skews, working paper. Relazione tecnica, University of Toronto.

BIBLIOGRAPHY

121

Jarrow R.; Yu F. (2001). Counterparty risk and the pricing of defaultable securities. Journal of Finance, 56, 1765–1799. Kijima M. (2000). Valuation of a credit swap of the basket type. Review of Derivatives Research, 4, 81–97. Kijima M.; Muromachi Y. (2000). Credit events and the valuation of credit derivatives of basket type. Review of Derivatives Research, 4, 55–79. Kim; Ramaswamy; Sundaresan (1992). The valuation of corporate fixed income securities, working paper. Relazione tecnica, New York University. Lando D. (2004). Credit Risk Modeling: Theory and Applications. Princeton University Press. Leland H. (1994). Corporate debt value, bond covenants, and optimal capital structure. Journal of Finance, 49, 1213–1252. Leland H. E.; Toft K. B. (1996). Optimal capital structure, endogenous bankruptcy, and the term structure of credit spreads. Journal of Finance, 3, 987–1019. Li D. X. (2000). On default correlation: A copula function approach. Relazione tecnica, The Risk Metrics Group. Litterman R.; Iben T. (1991). Corporate bond valuation and the term structure of credit spreads. The Journal of Portfolio Management, Spring, 52–64. Longstaff F.; Schwartz E. (1995). A simple approach to valuing risky fixed and floating rate debt. Journal of Finance, 50, 789–819. Mason S. P.; Bhattacharya S. (1981). Risky debt, jump processes, and safety covenants. Journal of Financial Economics, 9(3), 281 – 307. McNeil A.; Frey R.; Embrechts P. (2005). Quantitative Risk Management: Concepts, Techniques, Tools. Princeton University Press, Princeton.

BIBLIOGRAPHY

122

Merton R. (1974). On the pricing of corporate debt: The risk structure of interest rates. Journal of Finance, 29, 449–470. Miller H. (1988). The modigliani-miller propositions after thirty years. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 2(4), 99–120. Miller M. (1977). Debt and taxes. Journal of Finance, 32, 261–275. Modigliani F.; Miller M. (1958). The cost of capital corporation finance, and the theory of investment. American Economic Review, 48, 261–277. Moody’s I. S. (1997). The binomial expansion technique. Moody’s S. R. (2001). Understanding the risks in credit default swaps. Relazione tecnica, Moody’s Investors Service, New York. Nelsen R. B. (1999). An Introduction to Copulas. Springer, New York. Nielsen L. T.; Sa´ -Requejo J.; Santa-Clara P. (1993). Default risk and interest rate risk: a The term structure of default spreads. Relazione tecnica, INSEAD. Repubblica L. (8 Marzo 2007). Rogge E.; Sch¨ nbucher P. J. (2003). Modelling dynamic portfolio credit risk, working o paper. Relazione tecnica, Department of Statistics, Bonn University. Sa´ -Requejo J.; Santa-Clara P. (1999). Bond pricing with default risk. working paper. a Relazione tecnica, UCLA. Schmidt W. M.; Ward I. (2002). Pricing default baskets. Risk, January, 111–114. Sch¨ nbucher P. (2005). Portfolio losses and the term structure of loss transition rates: o a new methodology for the pricing of portfolio credit derivatives. Relazione tecnica, Department of Mathematics, ETH Zurich.

BIBLIOGRAPHY

123

Sch¨ nbucher P. J. (2003). Credit Derivatives Pricing Models: Model, Pricing and Impleo mentation. John Wiley and Sons. Sch¨ nbucher P. J.; Schubert D. (2001). Copula-dependent default risk in intensity models, o working paper. Relazione tecnica, Department of Statistics, Bonn University. Semmler W.; Bernard L., (A cura di) (2007). The Foundation of Credit Risk Analysis. Edward Elgar Publishing. ` Sklar A. (1959). Fonctions de r´ partition a n dimensions et leurs marges. Publ. Inst. a Statist. Univ., 8, 229–231. Sklar A. (1996). A Personal Look Backward and Forward published in Distributions with Fixed Marginals and Related Topics,, capitolo Random Variables, Distribution Functions, and Copulas, pp. 1–14. Institute of Mathematical Statistics, Hayward, CA. Vasicek O. (1977). An equilibrium characterization of the term structure. Journal of Financial Economics, 5, 177–188. Walker M. (2005). Credit default swaps with counterparty risk: A calibrated markov model. Relazione tecnica, Department of Physics, Univresity of Toronto. Wei D. G.; Guo D. (1997). Pricing risky debt: An empirical comparison of the longstaff and schwartz and merton models. Journal of Fixed Income, 7 (2), 8–28. Wruck K. H. (1990). Financial distress, reorganization, and organizational efficiency. Journal of Financial Economics, 27(2), 419 – 444. Yu F. (2002). Correlated default in reduced-form models, working paper. Relazione tecnica, University of California, Irvine. Zhou C. (1997). A jump-diffusion approach to modeling credit risk and valuing defaultable securities. Relazione tecnica, Finance and Economic Discussion Series, No. 15, Federal Reserve Board, Washington.

BIBLIOGRAPHY

124

Zhou C. (2001). An analysis of default correlations and multiple defaults. The Review of Financial Studies, 14(2), 555–576. Zhou R. (2009). A multi-portfolio model for bespoke cdo pricing. working paper. Relazione tecnica, DTCC.

Similar Documents

Premium Essay

Credit Risk : Merton Model Limitations

...Evaluate of the Merton Model for credit risk analysis The KMV-Merton model proposed by Robert Merton(1974)is an application of classic option pricing theory and as a logical extension of the Black-Scholes(1973)option pricing framework.Merton’s approach assess the credit risk of a firm by characterizing the firm’s equity as a call option on the underling value of the firm with a strike price equal to the face value of the firm’s debt and a time-to-maturity of T.By put-call parity,the value of the firm’s debt is equal to the value of a risk-free discount bond minus the value of a put option written on the firm with a strike price equal to the face value of debt and a time-to-maturity of T. To some extent,our calculated probability of default is reasonable.In fact,dynamics of default probability comes mostly from the dynamics of the equity values.KMV model can always quickly reflect deterioration in credit quality.Normally, changes in EDF tend to anticipate at least one year earlier than the downgrading of the issuer by rating agencies such as S&P’s and Moody’s.It recognizes that the market value of debt is unobservable and thus use equity to infer debt value. The calculated probability of default is more related to the firm’s characteristics than credit rating approach and thus more sensitive to change in the quality of obligors.Because stock price information is predictive and highly responsive, the use of market information to compute credit risk can gain more accurate...

Words: 605 - Pages: 3

Free Essay

Risk

...Credit Risk Management Ken Brown Peter Moles CR-A2-engb 1/2012 (1044) This course text is part of the learning content for this Edinburgh Business School course. In addition to this printed course text, you should also have access to the course website in this subject, which will provide you with more learning content, the Profiler software and past examination questions and answers. The content of this course text is updated from time to time, and all changes are reflected in the version of the text that appears on the accompanying website at http://coursewebsites.ebsglobal.net/. Most updates are minor, and examination questions will avoid any new or significantly altered material for two years following publication of the relevant material on the website. You can check the version of the course text via the version release number to be found on the front page of the text, and compare this to the version number of the latest PDF version of the text on the website. If you are studying this course as part of a tutored programme, you should contact your Centre for further information on any changes. Full terms and conditions that apply to students on any of the Edinburgh Business School courses are available on the website www.ebsglobal.net, and should have been notified to you either by Edinburgh Business School or by the centre or regional partner through whom you purchased your course. If this is not the case, please contact Edinburgh Business School at the address below:...

Words: 21029 - Pages: 85

Free Essay

Credit Risk and Asset Volatility

...Volatility Estimation for Corporate Credit Rating 1009611462 LUFEI Xiaoxin 1009611301 HE Yao Abstract The market-based credit models make use of market information such as equity values to estimate a firm’s credit risk. The Merton model and the Black-Cox model are two popular models that link asset value with equity value, based on the option pricing theories. Under these models, the distance to default can be derived and thus the default probability can be mapped to as long as a large database of companies is provided. The difficulty, however, is that some parameters, including asset values and asset volatilities, which are required in calculating the distance to default, are unobservable in market. Therefore, statistical methods need to be developed in order to estimate the unobservable parameters. In this project, our focus is on using KMV method, which has been widely used in the industry, to estimate corporates’ asset values and asset volatilities. We implemented two models and did numeric study by simulation, which shows that the KMV method gives generally accurate estimates under both models. We also analyzed the model risk under different circumstances. The barrier sensitivity analysis gives the result of how sensitive the Black-Cox model is in choosing different barriers, in the relation with asset volatility and debt level. Furthermore, the models are applied to real companies with different leverage ratios, which shows that structural models are more dynamic and accurate...

Words: 10259 - Pages: 42

Premium Essay

An Analysis of the Impact of Risk Exposure to the Performance of Banks in Nigeria

...AN ANALYSIS OF THE IMPACT OF RISK EXPOSURE TO THE PERFORMANCE OF BANKS IN NIGERIA CERTIFICATION I certify that this research work was carried out by MR ABOYARIN SALAMI TUNDE with Matriculation No.; 109025160 of the Department of Finance, Faculty of Business Administration, University of Lagos, Akoka, Lagos. __________________________ ______________ DR. LEKAN OBADEMI DATE _______________________ ____________ PROF. W. IYIEGBUNIWE DATE HOD DEPARTMENT OF FINANCE _______________________ ____________ EXTERNAL EXAMINER DATE DEDICATION This project work is dedicated to the Glory of ALMIGHTY ALLAH (SWT) to Him I say as always; ALHAMDULILAHI ROBIL ALAMIN!!! Special dedication also goes to the memory of my late father; Alhaji R.S.A Aboyarin. I pray his soul finds forgiveness and mercy before Allah (Amin. ACKNOWLEDGEMENT CHAPTER ONE 1.0: INTRODUCTION AND BACKGROUND TO THE STUDY Banks are germane to economic development through the financial services they provide. Their intermediation role can be said to be a catalyst for economic growth and development. The efficient and effective performance of the banking industry over time is an index of financial stability in any nation. The extent to which a bank extends credit to the public for productive activities accelerates the pace of a nation’s economic growth and its long-term sustainability. Amongst the...

Words: 14126 - Pages: 57

Free Essay

Bidv Vietnam Improving Credit Risk Management by Internal Rating Systems

...ADVANCING CREDIT RISK MANAGEMENT THROUGH INTERNAL RATING SYSTEMS At Bank for Investment and Development of Viet Nam JSC (Transaction office no.8 ) Table of Contents Foreword Part I : Overview of Bank Credit risk management and The theoretical basis of Internal rating systems 1. The activities of commercial banks 1.1. The concept of a commercial bank. 1.2. Operation and Performance of Commercial Banks 2. Managing Operational risk in banking 3. Definition of an Internal Rating System 4. Rating models 4.1. Outlines of Rating Models 4.2. Validation of Rating Models 4.3. Adjusting Rating Models 5. Uses of Internal Rating Systems 6. Benefits of Using an Internal Rating System Part II : Current situation of Credit activities and Internal rating systems at BIDV ( Transaction office no.8 ) 1. General introduction of Bank for Investment and Development of Viet Nam JSC ( BIDV ) 2. Current business status of BIDV 2.1. Socio-economic situation in the period of 2008-2012 2.2. Situation of BIDV business operations in the period of 2008-2012 3. Situation of BIDV Credit quality in the period of 2008 – 2012 3.1. Current situation of BIDV Credit quality 3.2. Achivement of BIDV Credit activities 3.3. SWOT analysis on Credit activities of BIDV branches 4. Current situation of Internal rating systems at BIDV 4.1. Current situation of Credit Risk Management at BIDV 4.2. Current situation of Customer rating systems at BIDV (Transaction office no. 8) ...

Words: 398 - Pages: 2

Free Essay

Risk and Rate of Return

...Financial Risk: Key Fundamentals and Case Studies Leonard Chumo, CFA, FRM Strathmore University GARP Chapter Meeting 29th July 2011 Agenda 1. Background 2. Credit Risk and the Case of Washington Mutual 3. Operational Risk and the Case of Rogue Brokers in Kenya and Barings 4. Market Risk and the Case of LTCM 5. Liquidity Risk and the Case of Northern Rock 6. Q&A BACKGROUND Main Types of Financial Risk Risk Type Definition Credit Risk The potential that a bank's borrower or counterparty will fail to meet its obligations in accordance with agreed terms. Market Risk The risk that movements in market prices will adversely affect the value of on- or off-balance sheet positions. The risk is attributable to movements in interest rates, foreign exchange (FX) rates, equity prices or prices of commodities. Operational Risk Risk of loss resulting from inadequate or failed internal processes, people and systems, or from external events. The definition includes legal risk, but excludes reputational and strategic risk. Liquidity Risk Liquidity is the ability to fund increases in assets and meet obligations as they become due. It is crucial to the ongoing viability of any organization. Source: Financial Stability Institute CREDIT RISK AND THE CASE OF WASHINGTON MUTUAL Sources of Credit Risk Apart from traditional types of loans, credit risk can also be found in a bank's: Investment portfolio ...

Words: 1684 - Pages: 7

Free Essay

Eco 595 Research Paper 1

...Abstract This research assesses the fundamental causes of the current financial crisis that hit the USA in 2008. A Close look at financial analysis specifies that theoretical modeling based on unrealistic anticipations led to serious problems in mispricing in the enormous unregulated market for credit default swaps that exploded upon catalytic rises in residential mortgage defaults. Latest academic research suggests solutions to the economic crisis that are appraised to be far less costly than bailing out investors who made poor decisions with respect to credit analysis. Introduction The financial crisis that occurred in 2008 is of such epic proportions that even astronomical amounts spent to address this issue have by far been not able to resolve it. This economic crisis is the worst to ever hit USA since the great depression and is utmost important to economists since this led to 2.6 million unemployed furthermore 3.4 trillion dollar were lost in real estate wealth and the stock market also lost 7.4 trillion according to the Federal Reserve. Besides the $700 billion bill approved by Congress, the Federal Reserve has bailed out institutions and markets by generating about $1.3 trillion in investments in various risky assets, also including loans to otherwise bankrupt organizations & collateralized debt obligations which were completely backed by subprime mortgages that were defaulting at rapid rates. Furthermore a $900 billion is in the process of being proposed...

Words: 2121 - Pages: 9

Free Essay

Credit Risk

...Commercial Banking The first category of credit risk models are the ones based on the original framework developed by Merton (1974) using the principles of option pricing (Black and Scholes, 1973). * the default process of a company is driven by the value of the company’s assets and the risk of a firm’s default is therefore explicitly linked to the variability of the firm’s asset value. * The basic intuition behind the Merton model is relatively simple: default occurs when the value of a firm’s assets (the market value of the firm) is lower than that of its liabilities. * The payment to the debt holders at the maturity of the debt is therefore the smaller of two quantities: the face value of the debt or the market value of the firm’s assets. * Assuming that the company’s debt is entirely represented by a zero-coupon bond, if the value of the firm at maturity is greater than the face value of the bond, then the bondholder gets back the face value of the bond. * However, if the value of the firm is less than the face value of the bond, the shareholders get nothing and the bondholder gets back the market value of the firm. The payoff at maturity to the bondholder is therefore equivalent to the face value of the bond minus a put option on the value of the firm, with a strike price equal to the face value of the bond and a maturity equal to the maturity of the bond. Following this basic intuition, Merton derived an explicit formula for risky bonds which can...

Words: 1011 - Pages: 5

Premium Essay

Zhang Hao

...savings. C) Credit contraction from systemic crises can severely damage the economy. x D) All of the above. E) Only a and b of the above. 2. The process of deposit withdrawal, usually because of lower interest rates paid by FIs, for reinvestment elsewhere is called x A) disintermediation B) regulator forebearance. C) Regulation Q ceilings. D) off-balance-sheet financing. E) none of the above. 3. The portion of the income statement that reflects money set aside for possible future credit losses is A) the reserve for loan losses. B) net interest income. C) non interest expense. x D) the provision for loan losses. E) net interest margin. 4. Investment banking includes A) corporate finance activities such as restructuring existing corporations. B) corporate finance activities such as advising on mergers and acquisitions. C) raising debt and equity securities for corporations. x D) all of the above. E) only two of the above. 5. FIs that pool financial resources and invest in diversified portfolios of assets are A) mutual funds. B) open-ended mutual funds. C) bond funds. D) equity funds. x E) all of the above. 6. Adjusting the balance sheet asset values to reflect current market values is called A) asset valuation. x B) marking-to-market. C) determining NAVs. D) risk minimization. E) two of the above are correct. 8. The risk that occurs when the maturities of an FI's assets and liabilities are mismatched is A) credit risk. B) operational risk. C) liquidity risk. x D) interest...

Words: 1440 - Pages: 6

Free Essay

Risk Compared with Australia Banks and Hsbc

...banks are exposed to big challenge and face many risks like credit and liquidity risk. Given this situation, APRA outlines the regulations to ensure and consolidate the safety for Australian banking system, such as Liquidity and Credit quality. This report will analyse the difference between credit risk and liquidity risk at the beginning, then the regulations from APRA in terms of credit risk for the major and smaller banks will be discussed. Next, there will be 3 ratios of credit risk of the “big four” contrast to a major commercial bank in the UK. This report will be end with evaluating the credit risk of 5 major banks and give some findings are regarding with the credit risk of 5 banks. 1. Explain the difference between credit risk and liquidity risk for a bank. 1.1 Credit risk Credit risk is the risk that the promised cash flows from loans and securities held by FIs may not be paid in full (Lange & Saunders, 2013). Normally, all financial institutions have probability to face this risk. However, if borrowed principal is paid on maturity and interest payments are paid on the due date, FIs can eliminate credit risk. Additionally, credit risk can be subdivided into firm-specific credit risk and systematic credit risk. Firm-specific credit risk affects a particular company and can be eliminated by good diversification, while systematic credit risk involves macroeconomic. 1.2 Liquidity risk Liquidity risk is the risk that a sudden surge in liability withdrawals may...

Words: 2315 - Pages: 10

Free Essay

Introduction to Credit Metrics

...Introduction to CreditMetrics™ The benchmark for understanding credit risk New York April 2, 1997 • • • A value-at-risk (VaR) framework applicable to all institutions worldwide that carry credit risk in the course of their business. A full portfolio view addressing credit event correlations which can identify the costs of over concentration and benefits of diversification in a mark-to-market framework. Results that drive: investment decisions, risk-mitigating actions, consistent risk-based credit limits, and rational risk-based capital allocations. J.P. Morgan Co-sponsors: Bank of America Bank of Montreal BZW Deutsche Morgan Grenfell KMV Corporation Swiss Bank Corporation Union Bank of Switzerland Table of Contents 1. Introduction to CreditMetrics 2. The case for a portfolio approach to credit risk 3. The challenges of estimating portfolio credit risk 4. An overview of CreditMetrics methodology 5. Practical applications 3 9 12 14 30 Introduction to CreditMetrics Copyright © 1997 J.P. Morgan & Co. Incorporated. All rights reserved. J.P. Morgan Securities, Inc., member SIPC. J.P. Morgan is the marketing name for J.P. Morgan & Co. Incorporated and its subsidiaries worldwide. CreditMetrics™, CreditManager™, FourFifteen™, and RiskMetrics™ are trademarks of J.P. Morgan in the United States and in other countries. They are written with the symbol ™ on their first occurance in the publication, and as CreditMetrics, CreditManager, FourFifteen or RiskMetrics thereafter...

Words: 14906 - Pages: 60

Premium Essay

Credit Appraisal of Sbi

... January 2013, ISSN 2278‐0629     CREDIT APPRAISAL PROCESS OF SBI: A CASE STUDY OF BRANCH OF SBI IN HISAR NANCY ARORA*; DR. ARTI GAUR**; MS. BABITA*** *Student, Department of Business Administration, CDLU, Sirsa. **Assistant Professor, Department of Business Administration, CDLU, Sirsa. **Teaching Associate, Department of Business Administration, CDLU, Sirsa. ABSTRACT             Pinnacle Research Journals                   10       http://www.pinnaclejournals.com                                                                                        Credit risk is a risk related to non repayment of the credit obtained by the customer of a bank. Thus it is necessary to appraise the credibility of the customer in order to mitigate the credit risk. Proper evaluation of the customer is performed this measures the financial condition and the ability of the customer to repay back the loan in future. Credit Appraisal is a process to ascertain the risks associated with the extension of the credit facility. It is generally carried by the financial institutions which are involved in providing financial funding to its customers. In this paper, we study the Credit Risk Assessment Model of SBI Bank and to check the commercial, financial & technical viability of the project proposed & its funding pattern. Also to observe the movements to reduce various risk parameters which are broadly categorized into financial risk, business risk, industrial risk and management risk. The scope of the paper is...

Words: 5018 - Pages: 21

Free Essay

Accounting in Context

...Module name: Accounting in Context Course title: ELEMENT CW2 (LJ) Credit Risk Management Name of Supervisor: Anthony John Bray Student: Dieu Linh Cao. ID number: 12028548. Word count: 4,467 words. Date: 06/03/2013 Executive summary Every day when reading the financial newspapers or news on TV, I notice that the bad debt still has been the big problem of many economics. Bad debt increases which influences to the bank first, and then to the all of the economy. So, I want to do the research about the Credit Risk Management because in my opinion, this is the way to reduce bad debt effectively. In this report, I have researched about 3 models in Credit Risk Management: CreditMetrics, KMV, and Credit Risk Plus. In each model, I explain and analysis the case study from other document sources. Besides, I also compare and contrast the features or the use of them. In addition, critical thinking is applied in this report, when I have found the other idea, from opponent opinion to agreement. Because of the limitation of knowledge and timing, my report still has had many mistakes. Therefore, if I could do this topic again, may be in the dissertation of the master course, I will make it better, with my experience from AIC subject. Table of Contents Executive summary 2 Declaration 4 Content 5 1. CreditMetrics: 7 2. Portfolio Manager of KMV: 11 3. Credit Risk+: 14 Appendix 18 References 20 Declaration I declare that this research report...

Words: 5372 - Pages: 22

Free Essay

Management

...A MODEL FOR RISK BASED PRICING FOR INFRASTRUCTURE FINANCING BY BANKS By Prof Ajay Pathak* Infrastructure development is the new buzzword for India Inc.Policy makers are putting emphasis on development of roads, ports, airports, and urban infrastructure to facilitate growth. The government is opening up private investment in the infrastructure through Special Purpose Vehicles (SPV). With the changing regulations, however, infrastructure finance so far has been untouched by the commercial banks. but this is the new avenue to gear up their fund based activities. With increased exposure in infrastructure, banks need to be cautious about the credit risks inherent in the projects with long gestation periods. It was found that infrastructure development has a high correlation with the macroeconomic factors like GDP growth rate of the country. Such macroeconomic trends actually influence income generation and timely recovery of the credit extended. So for greater risk sensitivity a model pricing mechanism has been developed to address the macroeconomic changes in the economy for better risk management. It is an obvious fact that risk is inherent in every action. In extending credit to other parties one of the main risks of the Bank is Credit Risk. The possibility of losses associated with diminution in the credit quality of borrowers/counter parties is called credit risk. In a simpler way, credit risk may be defined...

Words: 4387 - Pages: 18

Free Essay

Credit Risk

...IDENTITY CARD NO. : 3505543 NAME : GEORGE S. OGUTU CONTACT : P. O. BOX 11873-00400, NAIROBI. CELL PHONE : 0722 736 054 OCCUPATION : CIVIL SERVANT EMPLOYER : GOVERNMENT OF KENYA, MINISTRY OF ROADS DISTRICT : SIAYA LOCATION : USONGA SUB-LOCATION : USONGA VILLAGE : NYANDORERA RESIDENCE : RONGAI STATES: I am the above mentioned male adult Kenyan of the above given address, aged 52years. I am employed by the Government of Kenya, Ministry of Roads as a Technologist based in Nairobi’s Industrial Area. I am the owner and Policy Holder of Motor Vehicle Registration Number KAA 572R Nissan Sunny Saloon. I had insured the said Vehicle with M/S Gate-way Insurance Company ** policy Number 010/070/1/140134/2008/11. The cover which was on display as on 1st September, 2012 was valued from 14th November, 2009 to expire on 13th November, 2012. I wish to state as follows:- I do recall that on the 1st day of September, 2012, I gave my vehicle to Keziah Ogutu who is my young sister. She was to use the vehicle to go to her office. At about 8.00 am, she called me and informed me that she had been involved in an accident along Mombasa Road at Bellevue while driving to her office. She further told me that a Pedestrian ran on the road when she collided with the vehicle. She told me that the Pedestrian sustained injuries. I then rushed to the scene and found the Police at the scene. The victim had already been removed from the scene and taken to hospital by an ambulance. After Police...

Words: 3863 - Pages: 16