Free Essay

Efficient Markets Hypothesis

In:

Submitted By wangamanda
Words 6063
Pages 25
© 2002 American Accounting Association Accounting Horizons Vol. 16 No. 3 September 2002 pp. 233–243

COMMENTARY

The “Incomplete Revelation Hypothesis” and Financial Reporting
Robert J. Bloomfield
Robert J. Bloomfield is an Associate Professor at Cornell University. INTRODUCTION The most common form of the Efficient Markets Hypothesis (EMH) states that market prices fully reflect all publicly available information (Fama 1970). The EMH has been highly influential among academics, but practitioners and regulators appear unconvinced. Investors work hard to identify mispriced stocks on the basis of public data, or pay others to do so, even though the EMH asserts that such efforts are wasted. Managers seek to boost stock prices by hiding bad news in footnotes, and regulators work hard to defeat such efforts, even though the EMH asserts that information is reflected in prices no matter how obscure its presentation. Beliefs about inefficiency play a central role in the debate over recognizing expenses for incentive stock options. Opponents of expensing argue that the resulting lower net income will inappropriately reduce market prices, while proponents argue the market does not fully recognize compensation costs reported only in footnotes. In efficient markets, however, expensing these costs has no direct effect on prices, as long as the details of the compensation are included in footnotes. The decision to expense option costs could reduce stock price indirectly, even in efficient markets, by affecting the terms of contracts between the reporting firm and other parties (Watts and Zimmerman 1986). However, few of the parties to the debate appear concerned about these effects. The academic community is showing increasing dissatisfaction with the EMH, swayed partly by evidence that prices underreact to large earnings changes, ratios of prices to fundamentals, and other statistics derived from fundamental accounting analyses. However, the EMH is still influential because there is no alternative theory that explains why we observe the inefficiencies we do. For example, why should the market underreact to large earnings changes, rather than overreact? Without a theory predicting how and why markets are inefficient, studies showing mispricing can be viewed as statistical flukes resulting from fishing expeditions (Fama 1998; Kothari 2001).
This paper in an outgrowth of presentations at the 2001 P. D. Leake Lectures at Oxford University, the 2001 AAA Doctoral Consortium, the 2001 Conference on Experimental Methods at Harvard University, and Cornell University. Thanks to Paul E. Fischer, John Hand, David Hirshleifer, Mark Nelson, Maureen O’Hara, and Tom Dyckman for helpful comments.

Corresponding author: Robert J. Bloomfield Email: rjb9@cornell.edu

Submitted: August 2001 Accepted: April 2002

234

Accounting Horizons/September 2002

In this paper, I present an alternative to the EMH called the “Incomplete Revelation Hypothesis” (IRH). The IRH asserts that statistics that are more costly to extract from public data are less completely revealed in market prices. The IRH can account for many of the phenomena that are central to financial reporting but inconsistent with the EMH. It predicts that investors devote substantial resources to identifying mispriced stocks on the basis of public data, that managers seek to boost stock prices by hiding bad news in footnotes, and that regulators may wish to defeat such efforts, because information that is hard to extract from financial statements will not be reflected in stock prices. The IRH also provides a number of novel and testable predictions that distinguish it from the EMH. THE INCOMPLETE REVELATION HYPOTHESIS The IRH is based on equilibrium outcomes in “noisy rational expectations” models.1 In these models, rational agents choose whether to collect information about the value of an asset. Those who choose to collect the information then trade the asset in a market that also includes “noise” traders. Noise traders are so named because they trade randomly, in response to liquidity shocks, portfolio rebalancing needs, or even irrational whims. This noise keeps prices in the market from revealing information completely, because traders who observe only price cannot tell whether prices are high because informed traders have good news, or because noise traders happen to be buying heavily. This uncertainty allows the informed traders to profit from their information advantage. A key result of noisy rational expectation models is that there is an equilibrium in which just enough traders collect information to make their trading gains equal to their collection costs. Assume for simplicity that all traders have the same amount of money to place at risk in the market, and the same limited tolerance for risk. In this case, the more traders who collect information, the more completely prices reveal information, and the lower the gain to collecting information. If too few traders collect information, then more prefer to do so, because the gains from informed trading outweigh the costs of collecting the information. If too many traders collect information, then some will regret this decision, because the gains from informed trading are too small to cover collection costs. The equilibrium outcome therefore requires that some but not all traders incur the costs to collect information. In equilibrium, fewer traders collect more costly information. The greater resulting inefficiency allows those who collect the information trading gains sufficient to cover the higher collection costs. I extend this intuition to financial reporting by distinguishing statistics from data. Data are ink spots on sheets of paper, or bits stored in a computer file. Statistics are the useful facts extracted from that data, such as earnings figures and financial ratios. While public data are often free, it takes time and effort to extract statistics even as widely publicized as earnings growth. Given that thousands of companies report earnings every quarter, extracting the relevant statistics is not a trivial task. Hirshleifer and Teoh (2002) provide an excellent discussion of the causes and effects of “limited attention,” which keeps traders from considering all available data in making their trading decisions. Applying this perspective to the equilibrium described above, fewer investors base their trading decisions on statistics that are more costly to extract from public data, and market prices reveal those statistics less completely.

1

See, in particular, Grossman and Stiglitz (1980).

The “Incomplete Revelation Hypothesis” and Financial Reporting

235

In formulating the Incomplete Revelation Hypothesis, I recognize that traders have varying tolerances for risk and money to place at risk. Instead of referring to the number of traders collecting information, appropriate only if all traders are identical, I refer to the “trading interest” driven by a statistic. Trading interest is defined as the additional shares traders are willing to trade for given deviations of market price from the value indicated by the statistic in question.2 A statistic can drive more trading interest if more traders collect it, if those who collect it have more money to place at risk, or if those who collect it have greater tolerance for risk. IRH: Statistics that are more costly to extract from public data are less completely revealed by market prices. This association is driven by the following causal chain: • Statistics that are more costly to extract from publicly available information drive less trading interest. • Statistics that drive less trading interest are less completely revealed by market prices. In addition to having a sound theoretical basis, the IRH is well supported by numerous experiments finding that market prices incompletely reflect information not held by all traders.3 Because it is derived from models assuming that investors are rational, the IRH clarifies that informational inefficiency need not imply irrationality. Statistics that are costly to extract from data are not completely revealed by prices precisely because trading on those statistics does not generate profits sufficient to cover the extraction cost. Proponents of efficient markets have long recognized this point, but typically invoke extraction costs only as a last resort, to reinterpret evidence of mispricing to be consistent with rationality (Ball 1992). In contrast, the IRH uses these costs as the foundation for specific and testable predictions about the nature and form of inefficiencies, and their implications for financial reporting research, practice, and regulation. The following section discusses these implications in detail. IMPLICATIONS OF THE IRH FOR FINANCIAL REPORTING RESEARCH, PRACTICE, AND REGULATION Linking Price Reactions and Extraction Costs Some of the most basic implications of the IRH are similar to key implications of the EMH used commonly in accounting research. Event studies use the EMH to predict that prices rise after good news and fall after bad news, and price-association studies use the EMH to infer investors’ interpretations of data from observed price responses, pioneered by Ball and Brown (1968). The IRH provides the same qualitative predictions. Because information is at least partly revealed in prices, prices rise after good news is released and fall after bad news is released, and price movements are positively correlated with investor interpretations of public data. Thus, researchers relying on
2

3

In most rational expectation models, traders enter a linear demand function of the form “Demand = b(market price-reservation price),” where the reservation price indicates the value the trader places on the asset, given his or her information. The slope of this line, b, measures the trader’s trading interest. See, for example, Bloomfield (1996). Libby et al. (2002) provide a review of this literature. Interestingly, little experimental research examines the link between the degree of efficiency and the cost of information collection. See Sunder (1992) for a rare example.

236

Accounting Horizons/September 2002

these qualitative predictions of the EMH to conduct event studies or price-association studies lose little by relying on the IRH instead. The IRH goes beyond the EMH by predicting that prices react more strongly to statistics that are more easily extracted from public data. The EMH makes no such prediction, because it ignores extraction costs. The link between extraction cost and price reaction also requires changes in the inferences drawn from price movements. Assume that a firm’s stock price rises by 5 percent (adjusted for risk) in response to a public announcement. Researchers could use the EMH to infer that the announcement suggests a 5 percent increase in value. Under the IRH, a 5 percent price reaction is possible only if investors who trade on the statistics included in the announcement perceive more than a 5 percent increase in value, because price changes reflect those perceptions incompletely. The smaller the trading interest driven by the information, the more it must influence traders’ perceptions to create a 5 percent increase in price. The IRH can alter inferences in another way. Francis et al. (2001) find that reported earnings numbers are more closely associated with prices than cash flows, sales and other financial statement data. Using the EMH, they infer that investors view earnings information as more relevant than the other data. The IRH implies a similar result if more investors analyze earnings data than analyze the other statistics. Thus, researchers need to control for differences in investor attention to the statistics before attributing the short-term price effects solely to the beliefs of investors who choose to analyze the statistics. Testing the link between extraction costs and price behavior requires good measures of these costs. Different perspectives on the nature of extraction costs lead to different measures. One perspective is that extraction costs reflect the cash costs of identifying, collecting, compiling, printing and processing data, or hiring others to do so. Media dissemination and analyst coverage represent inverse measures of costs of identifying and collecting relevant information. News releases that are more widely disseminated and analyzed in the popular press or through corporate press releases should show greater price reactions. Because more informative statistics tend to be more widely published, controls for information content are studies using such measures. Another perspective is that extraction costs reflect the cognitive difficulty of extracting information from data that has already been identified and collected. Experiments find that professional analysts often fail to recall and respond appropriately to information in complex financial disclosures, suggesting that these costs are not trivial (Hirst and Hopkins 1998). Maines and McDaniel (2000) provide a framework in which data’s placement, labeling, isolation, and degree of aggregation in financial statements all influence the cost of extracting information. Future research could expand on this framework to identify statistics that are more difficult to extract from given reports, or reporting formats that make it more difficult to extract given statistics. Appropriate research designs can sidestep the most difficult problems in measuring extraction costs. The most effective research designs examine how differences in extraction costs are associated with differences in price reactions or other aspects of market behavior. For example, a researcher might examine whether markets react more strongly to a dollar of incentive stock option costs included in earnings than the same dollar of costs buried in a complex footnote. Evidence of such a difference would support the IRH, even though the research design does not measure the actual cost of extracting the information from either type of disclosure.

The “Incomplete Revelation Hypothesis” and Financial Reporting

237

Research designs can also simplify measurement issues by tying market behavior to the dissemination of information among investors. The IRH links extraction costs to market behavior because extraction costs influence dissemination. Survey methods may be effective at determining how many investors base their trading strategies on particular statistics such as earnings growth or footnotes about off-balance-sheet financing. Evidence that statistics driving more trading interest are revealed more completely in stock prices provides strong support for a key prediction of the IRH without measuring extraction costs. Return Predictability (Drift) The most common way to demonstrate informational inefficiency is to form goodnews and bad-news portfolios based on whether a particular statistic is favorable or unfavorable. Researchers then test whether risk-adjusted returns for the two portfolios “drift” apart after the market has an opportunity to react to the news. Such drift indicates a failure of the market price to reveal the statistic completely when the data in question are first released. Prices drift predictably as the information is revealed more completely, either through the cumulative effect of trades based on that information, or through the ultimate resolution of the events that the statistic is able to predict. The IRH predicts greater drift for statistics that are more costly to extract. Sloan (1996) provides support for this prediction that is particularly relevant to financial reporting. He finds that prices incompletely reveal financial statement ratios indicating the proportion of earnings driven by accruals. These ratios are presumably more costly to extract than total earnings. The IRH also predicts systematic underreaction to information contained in footnotes and statistics derived through fundamental analysis, with larger underreactions to footnotes that are more complex or to statistics that require more complex analyses. The IRH can also potentially account for underreactions to large earnings changes (Bernard and Thomas 1990). It may seem unlikely that the costs of extracting statistics about earnings surprises are high enough to generate measurable returns. However, prices in noisy rational expectations models react completely to a statistic only if all market participants base their trading strategies on that statistic. While the out-ofpocket costs of collecting earnings statistics may be small, the costs of collecting information include opportunity costs. Most investors base their trading strategies on only a subset of available information. Thus, as long as opportunity costs keep some investors from basing trading decisions on earnings, perhaps because they trade on statistics reflecting market share, industry power, or technological advances, the IRH predicts that markets will incompletely reveal earnings information. Researchers might test whether earnings drift and other forms of drift are larger for firms for which earnings information is less widely disseminated, or for which information collection is generally more costly, perhaps due to limited analyst coverage.4 Earnings drift may also be larger in industries in which non-earnings information is more relevant, increasing the opportunity cost of extracting earnings-based statistics. The IRH places limits on the form of inefficiencies, because it predicts underreactions to statistics, rather than overreactions. I discuss overreactions in a later section of the paper.
4

Bhushan (1994) provides evidence consistent with these assertions.

238

Accounting Horizons/September 2002

Financial Analysis and Investment Practice The EMH presents a paradoxical view of the demand for financial analysis: perfectly efficient markets reveal information so completely that no one will bother collecting it, but if no one collects it, then the information is not revealed.5 The IRH uses the insights of rational expectations models to make explicit the relationship between the degree of inefficiency and the demand for costly information. It measures the demand for information in terms of the trading interest that information drives, and predicts that demand declines as the costs of extracting information rises. A number of theoretical papers, including Lundholm (1991), use noisy rational expectations models to explore demand for costly private information. The IRH suggests that similar models could shed light on decisions to extract costly statistics from public data. Assuming that all investors have identical wealth and risk aversion, and face identical analysis costs, as in Grossman and Stiglitz (1980), the IRH implies that fewer investors collect more costly information. Market features that reduce extraction costs— such as the presence of analysts or an active financial press—tend to increase information collection. Variation across investors also yields some interesting predictions. Information held by investors with more capital to put at risk or less risk aversion drives more trading interest; such investors can benefit more from information, and should be more willing to devote resources to analysis. This suggests that information tends to be concentrated in the hands of those managing large portfolios. The equilibrium models underlying the IRH imply that traders will extract statistics more actively in markets with more noise trade, because the greater noise allows informed traders to profit more from their information. However, noise should not affect the level of efficiency, which will always equate trading gains with the cost of information collection. Managers’ Financial Reporting Behavior Managers usually prefer high stock prices and high returns for the firms they manage. High prices and returns can increase the value of their stock options and stock holding, increase cash compensation, and improve their chances of retaining their current jobs or landing positions with other firms. Consistent with the IRH, managers make many decisions motivated, at least partly, by a desire to make it harder for investors to uncover information that the managers do not want to affect their firms’ stock prices: • • • • Managers choose and lobby for accounting methods that improve highly visible statistics, such as earnings-per-share and debt-equity ratios, and conceal expenses and liabilities in less-visible footnote disclosures. Managers classify arguably ongoing expenses as nonrecurring or extraordinary items, while reporting arguably unusual gains as part of operating income. Managers develop “cookie jar” reserves to maintain the capacity for positive accruals to boost earnings in the future (Nelson et al. 2002). Managers announce pro forma earnings numbers that emphasize improvements relative to their own strategically chosen benchmarks, while making it more difficult for investors to observe other measures of performance (Schrand and Walther 2000; Krische 2001).
This paradox is a major motivation of Grossman and Stiglitz (1980). Lee (2001) discusses the importance of the paradox to those teaching future investment professionals.

5

The “Incomplete Revelation Hypothesis” and Financial Reporting

239

Proponents of the EMH argue these actions affect stock prices only because they alter the information provided to the market or alter the terms of stated contracts, such as debt covenants or earnings-based compensation contracts. However, evidence for these alternative explanations is not always apparent. The IRH predicts that such behavior has the greatest effects on market prices when information is most costly to extract, or when trading interest is relatively low, for example, because a stock is not particularly liquid. The IRH also implies that decisions to conceal information can signal information about management. Because making bad news hard to extract inflates market prices only temporarily, investors can infer that managers who do so have a greater need for an immediate stock price boost. If less competent managers tend to be more impatient, perhaps because they believe poor stock price performance will trigger investigations into their competence, then investors can use reporting choices to infer managerial competence (Bloomfield and Kadiyali 2000). Financial Reporting Regulation Many accounting regulations can be viewed as governing the cost of extracting key statistics from financial data. For example, SFAS No. 130 permits firms to report the components of “Other Comprehensive Income,” such as unrealized gains and losses on certain investments, in a Comprehensive Income Statement, instead of reporting these components only in the Statement of Changes in Stockholders Equity. In efficient markets, such a change is important only if it conveys different information about the content of items. For example, investors might infer that a gain reported on the income statement has greater economic meaning than one simply passed through the owners’ equity accounts. However, such changes also alter the ease with which investors can extract that statistic (Hirst and Hopkins 1998), thereby affecting market prices. Regulations affecting extraction costs also affect investor welfare, because not all traders choose to extract costly statistics. Traders who face relatively low extraction costs, perhaps because they have access to investment professionals or information services, tend to benefit from regulations that increase the difficulty of extraction. In the models underlying the IRH, informed traders recoup extraction costs in transactions with noise traders who seek liquidity, need to rebalance their portfolios, or trade for any reason other than a rational response to information. Regulators can protect noise traders with regulations that place relevant information in the hands of more investors, as argued by Lev (1988). The more completely prices reflect information, the smaller the losses of the noise traders. However, regulators who wish to protect noise traders must recognize that doing so reduces the potential gains of extracting information, which in turn may limit the development of novel forms of financial analysis. The social benefits of improved financial analysis may outweigh the social benefits of alleviating noise trader losses. RATIONALITY, IRRATIONALITY, AND THE IRH Many discussions of inefficiency pit rationalists, who assume that investors behave rationally, against behavioralists, who assume that investors behave in systematically irrational ways. The IRH accommodates both perspectives. From a rationalist perspective, the noise trading that drives inefficiency reflects the random activities of rational investors who trade for noninformational purposes, such as needs to balance their portfolios. Traders rationally choose not to extract all statistics from public data because

240

Accounting Horizons/September 2002

the costs of doing so exceed the benefits. The internal consistency of this perspective, drawn from the rational expectation models underlying the IRH, clarifies that informational inefficiency need not indicate investor irrationality. From a behavioralist perspective, noise trade is driven by investors’ irrational and unpredictable changes in sentiment.6 Collection costs are simply convenient ways to represent the bounded abilities of investors to interpret information. Managers’ incentives to exploit incomplete revelation do not depend on its cause. Thus, whether the IRH is given a rational or behavioral interpretation does not affect the nature or importance of its predictions about price or reporting behavior. The IRH does not permit every form of irrationality that behavioralists can imagine. It permits only forms of irrationality that capture information-processing costs. A behavioral model consistent with the noisy rational expectations models must assume that traders rationally interpret the statistics they collect, although they might ignore important data, even when placed before them. It must also assume that traders trade rationally given their interpretations. These restrictions prohibit the IRH from explaining overreactions to public data. The IRH can accommodate some phenomena commonly referred to as overreactions, because they are more appropriately viewed as underreactions. For example, extreme ratios of price-to-earnings or price-to-book value tend to revert over time to more moderate levels. Extreme long-term returns revert to long-term averages in a similar way. These predictable price movements imply that high prices are too high and low prices are too low. However, such an interpretation does not specify the information to which the market is supposedly overreacting. As a result, these errors are better viewed as underreactions to the statistics used to identify the price errors—prices fail to reveal the news indicated by extreme prices relative to earnings or book value, or by extreme returns relative to average returns. In general, researchers should view deviations of price from the values indicated by fundamentals as underreactions to the fundamentals, whenever they are unable to identify the statistics driving those deviations. In this case, the IRH accommodates the deviations as the effects of noise trading, which may be rational or irrational. Under- and overreactions can also be difficult to distinguish when a widely disseminated statistic is contradicted or qualified by a statistic that is less widely disseminated. For example, one could use the evidence in Sloan (1996) to argue that markets overreact to the transitory accrual component of earnings. However, another interpretation is that only some investors decompose earnings into accruals and cash flows, causing the market to underreact to this information. Hand (1990) also provides evidence open to multiple interpretations. Hand (1990) finds that market prices react to the component of earnings reflecting a previously announced debt-equity swap. Because the gain from the swap was public data when the swap was first announced, the EMH predicts no price reaction to this component of income when total earnings are announced. This reaction to old information can therefore be interpreted as an overreaction. However, another interpretation is that not all investors are aware of the initial swap announcement, causing the market to underreact to the information that a component of earnings is old news.7
6 7

Black (1989) discusses how to interpret the role and nature of noise traders in financial markets. Another possibility is that prices react incompletely to the fact that the swap occurred at all, even though the swap is an event that may convey information. Then the re-announcement in earnings makes the reaction more complete by allowing more investors to react to the information. However, Hand (1989) finds that an initial announcement of a larger gain leads to a more negative price response, suggesting that investors view swap gains as bad news. Thus, the positive reaction to the re-announcement does not seem like a completion of the initial negative reaction to the swap’s occurrence.

The “Incomplete Revelation Hypothesis” and Financial Reporting

241

It may be possible to interpret all evidence of overreaction to one statistic as an underreaction to another contradictory statistic, rendering the overreaction consistent with the IRH. Such interpretations seem appropriate when one can identify the specific information to which investors are underreacting, as in the case of Sloan (1996) and Hand (1990). However, it is more difficult to reinterpret the evidence of DeBondt and Thaler (1987), who find that prices overreact to persistent trends in earnings. In this case, there is no obvious statistic that investors are ignoring. Rather, they appear to be overestimating the persistence of earnings trends. As an alternative to reinterpreting overreactions as underreactions to unidentified statistics, researchers should consider extending the IRH to incorporate pervasive forms of irrationality that would allow the IRH to predict overreactions, as well as underreactions. Experimental research suggests that three forms of irrationality seem particularly useful as a basis for understanding overreactions: • Overreliance on unreliable data. Many experiments find that people tend to react too strongly to statistics that have little information content, because their reactions are determined by how salient the information is and how strongly it is emphasized, rather than by its statistical validity.8 Markets might overreact to persistent earnings trends because the older earnings numbers have very little power to predict future earnings, but are very salient to investors. Similarly, markets might overreact to repeated publication of interesting but relatively uninformative evidence, such as income from debt-equity swaps, pro forma earnings announcements, or analysts’ projections. A special case of this error arises when investors fail to completely account for the incentives of the reporters to distort their information. For example, Forsythe et al. (1999) find that buyers in a laboratory market take sellers’ reports at face value, even though the sellers systematically inflate their reports. Recent investigations into the influence of misleading and self-interested analyst reports suggest that such a lack of skepticism may have played a part in the overpricing of Internet stocks. • Aggressive Trading by Less-Informed Investors. Markets might overreact because investors who collect little information fail to recognize their informational disadvantage in the market. This error, found in countless experiments, causes relatively uninformed traders to trade too aggressively and influence prices too much. This behavior, in turn, causes market prices to overreact to statistics that are collected by relatively uninformed investors who collect little other information.9 • Inappropriate Information Collection. The models underlying the IRH assume that each trader balances the costs and benefits of the statistics they extract information, given what other traders collect. However, the benefits depend on how many other traders collect the statistics, and traders choose what statistics to collect without knowing other traders’ decisions. Economic models assume that traders can predict others’ decisions accurately, but experimental tests of similar settings find that they often have trouble doing so (Bloomfield 1997). If traders underestimate how many others collect highly publicized statistics, then they will trade too aggressively on those statistics, causing market overreactions. Future experiments could test this possibility.
8 9

Griffin and Tversky (1992) and Bloomfield et al. ( 2002) discuss this evidence. Kagel (1995) provides a broad review of this trading error, which is known as the “winner’s curse.” Bloomfield et al. (1999) provide evidence that such errors can influence market prices, and cause less-well-informed traders to transfer wealth to more-informed investors.

242

Accounting Horizons/September 2002

CONCLUSIONS Those who believe markets are inefficient rarely provide a coherent and refutable alternative to the Efficiency Markets Hypothesis. This paper presents the Incomplete Revelation Hypothesis (IRH) as such an alternative, and describes its implications for financial reporting research, practice, and regulation. The IRH assumes that the costs of extracting useful statistics from public data keep markets from fully revealing the meaning of those statistics. This assumption runs counter to the common assertion that accounting data are so widely analyzed that analysis costs could not possibly account for observed inefficiencies. However, no statistic is relied upon by all traders, not even an earnings announcement. As long as some traders ignore a statistic, perhaps in favor of other statistics, traditional models of financial markets predict that prices will reveal the statistic incompletely. In addition, this concern focuses on the realism of the assumptions underlying the IRH, rather than focusing on the validity of its predictions. As Friedman (1953) argues, all useful theories rely on unrealistic assumptions because they seek simplicity. The EMH has been successful largely because its simple assumptions account so well for financial market behavior. Research will establish the usefulness of the IRH by testing its predictions, not by questioning its assumptions. The IRH extends the EMH by explicitly recognizing the costs of extracting statistics from public data. This extension does not alter the key qualitative predictions of the EMH that most accounting researchers rely on in event studies and price-association studies. However, it converts many phenomena that are “anomalies” from the perspective of the EMH into natural predictions of the IRH. Unlike the EMH, the IRH predicts that investors devote resources to predicting price changes from public data and are able to do so successfully, that managers attempt to manipulate market prices by emphasizing good news and tucking bad news in footnotes, and that regulators attempt to thwart such behavior. Its ability to account for such behavior, while also providing a number of novel testable predictions, gives the IRH great potential as a foundation for financial reporting research, practice, and regulation.

REFERENCES Ball, R. and P. Brown. 1968. An empirical evaluation of accounting income numbers. Journal of Accounting Research (Autumn): 663–681. ———. 1992. The earnings-price anomaly. Journal of Accounting and Economics 15 (2-3): 319–345. Bernard, V. L., and J. Thomas. 1990. Evidence that stock prices do not fully reflect the implications of current earnings for future earnings, Journal of Accounting and Economics 13 (4): 305–340. Bhushan, R. 1994. An informational efficiency perspective on the post-earnings-announcement drift. Journal of Accounting and Economics 18 (1): 45–65. Black, F. 1989. Noise. Journal of Finance 43: 540–555. Bloomfield, R. 1996. The interdependence of reporting discretion and informational efficiency in laboratory markets. The Accounting Review 71 (4): 493–511. ———. 1997. Strategic dependence and the assessment of fraud risk: A laboratory study. The Accounting Review 72 (4): 517–539. ———, R. Libby, and M. W. Nelson. 1999. Confidence and the welfare of less-informed investors. Accounting, Organizations and Society 24 (8): 623–647. ———, and V. Kadiyali. 2000. How verifiable cheap-talk can communicate unverifiable information. Working paper, Cornell University.

The “Incomplete Revelation Hypothesis” and Financial Reporting

243

———, R. Libby, and M. W. Nelson. 2002. Over-reliance on previous years’ earnings. Contemporary Accounting Research (forthcoming). DeBondt, W., and R. Thaler. 1987. Further evidence of investor overreaction and stock market seasonality. Journal of Finance 42 (3): 557–581. Fama, E. F. 1970. Efficient capital markets: A review of theory and empirical work. Journal of Finance 25 (2): 383–417. ———. 1998. Market efficiency, long-term returns, and behavioral finance. Journal of Financial Economics 49 (3): 283–306. Forsythe, R., R. Lundholm, and T. Reitz. 1999. Cheap talk, fraud and adverse selection in financial markets: Some experimental evidence. Review of Financial Studies 12: 581–618. Francis, J., K. Schipper, and L. Vincent. 2001. The relative and incremental information in alternative (to earnings) performance measures. Working paper, Duke University. Friedman, M. 1953. Essays in Positive Economics. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press. Griffin, D., and A. Tversky. 1992. The weighing of evidence and the determinants of confidence. Cognitive Psychology 24 (3): 411–435. Grossman, S., and J. Stiglitz. 1980. On the impossibility of informationally efficient markets. American Economic Review 70: 393–408. Hand, J. 1989. Did firms undertake debt-equity swaps for an accounting paper profit or for true financial gain? The Accounting Review 64 (October): 587–623. ———. 1990. A test of the extended functional fixation hypothesis. The Accounting Review 65 (4): 740–763. Hirshleifer, D., and S. H. Teoh. 2002. Limited attention, information disclosure and financial reporting. Working paper, Fisher College of Business, The Ohio State University. Hirst, D. E., and P. E. Hopkins. 1998. Comprehensive income reporting and analysts’ valuation judgments. Journal of Accounting Research 36 (Supplement): 47–75. Kagel, J. H. 1995. Auctions: A survey of experimental research. In The Handbook of Experimental Economics, edited by J. H. Hagel, and A. E. Roth. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Kothari, S. P. 2001. Capital markets research in accounting. Journal of Accounting and Economics 31: 105–231. Krische, S. 2001. Investors’ evaluations of strategic prior-period benchmark disclosures in earnings announcements. Working paper, University of Illinois at Urbana–Champaign. Lee, C. M. C. 2001. Market efficiency and accounting research: A discussion of “Capital market research in accounting,” by S. P. Kothari. Journal of Accounting and Economics 31: 233–253. Lev, B. 1988. Toward a theory of equitable and efficient accounting policy. The Accounting Review 63: 1–23. Libby, R., R. J. Bloomfield, and M. Nelson. 2002. Experimental research in financial accounting. Accounting, Organizations and Society (forthcoming). Lundholm, R. J. 1991. Public signals and the equilibrium allocation of private information. Journal of Accounting Research 29 (2): 322–350. Maines, L., and L. McDaniel. 2000. Effects of comprehensive-income characteristics on nonprofessional investors’ judgments: The role of financial-statement presentation format. The Accounting Review 77 (2): 179–207. Nelson, M. W., J. A. Elliott, and R. L. Tarpley. 2002. Where do companies attempt earnings management, and when do auditors prevent it? Working paper, Cornell University. Schrand, C., and B. Walther. 2000. Strategic benchmarks in earnings announcements: The selective disclosure or prior-period earnings components. The Accounting Review 75 (2): 151– 177. Sloan, R. 1996. Do stock prices fully reflect information in accruals and cash flows about future earnings? The Accounting Review 71 (3): 289–315. Sunder, S. 1992. Market for information: Experimental evidence. Econometrica 60 (3): 667–695. Watts, R., and J. Zimmerman. 1986. Positive Accounting Theory. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall.

Similar Documents

Free Essay

Efficient Market Hypothesis

...Efficient Market Hypothesis Efficient Market - Introduction  An efficient capital market is a market that is efficient in processing information Assumptions for Market to be Efficient 1. 2.  In other words, the market quickly and correctly adjusts to new information In an efficient market, the prices of securities observed at any time are based on “correct” evaluation of all information available at that time In an efficient market, prices immediately and fully reflect all available information Large no. of investors analyze and value securities for profit New information comes to the market in a random fashion  3. 4. Stock Prices adjust quickly to the new information Stock Prices should available information reflect all  Definition "In an efficient market, competition among the many intelligent participants leads to a situation where, at any point in time, actual prices of individual securities already reflect the effects of information based both on events that have already occurred and on events which, as of now, the market expects to take place in the future. In other words, in an efficient market at any point in time the actual price of a security will be a good estimate of its intrinsic value.“ - Professor Eugene Fama Efficient Market Hypothesis - Forms Efficient Market Hypothesis Weak Form Semi-Strong Form Strong Form The EMH Graphically All information, public & private • In this diagram, the circles represent the amount of information that each...

Words: 846 - Pages: 4

Free Essay

Efficient Market Hypothesis

...of history, magical thinking, quasimagical thinking, attention anomalies, the availability heuristic, culture and social contagion, and global culture. Theories of human behavior from psychology, sociology, and anthropology have helped motivate much recent empirical research on the behavior of financial markets. In this paper I will survey both some of the most significant theories (for empirical finance) in these other social sciences and the empirical finance literature itself. Particular attention will be paid to the implications of these theories for the efficient markets hypothesis in finance. This is the hypothesis that financial prices efficiently incorporate all public information and that prices can be regarded as optimal estimates of true investment value at all times. The efficient markets hypothesis in turn is based on more primitive notions that people behave rationally, or accurately maximize expected utility, and are able to process all available information. The idea behind the term “efficient markets hypothesis,” a term coined by Harry Roberts (1967),1 has a long history in financial research, a far longer history than the term itself has. The hypothesis (without the words This paper was prepared for John B. Taylor and Michael Woodford, Editors, Handbook of Macroeconomics. An earlier version was presented...

Words: 18103 - Pages: 73

Free Essay

Efficient Market Hypothesis

...Introduction Efficient market hypothesis is widely accepted by academic community as a cornerstone of modern financial theory. Fama (1970) gives detailed definition of this theory and states that efficient market is a market that stock prices quickly and fully reflect all available and newly released information, where majority of participants are rational in their decision making process and where an investor is not able to outperform the market through any analyses, because of actual price of stock shows its intrinsic value. Naturally such revolutionary hypothesis did not occur suddenly. In 1990 Louis Bachelier in his "Theory of Speculation" paragraph gave definition of informational efficiency of the market. This study was not being developed until 1953 when Maurice Kendall who postulated that stock prices movement follow the random walk theory. Further enhancement of these studies associated with the name of Eugene Fama who gave comprehensive resume of efficient market hypothesis, as well as empirical evidences to support it and defined three form of efficient market: weak, semi-strong and strong in 1970 (Dimson and Mussavian, 1998). Later several different researches have been carried out by financial academics which continuously underpinned efficient market hypothesis. Consequently this theory began widely use by investors for investment decision making process. However only after two decades this hypothesis began less dominance in the market. Several crashes, changing...

Words: 3508 - Pages: 15

Premium Essay

Efficient Market Hypothesis

...1. Explain what efficient market hypothesis is. ` In a simple statement, the Efficient Market Hypothesis (EMH) means that security prices fully reflect all available information (Fama, 1991). There are three forms of EMH. Weak Form EMH Semi-Strong Form EMH Strong Form EMH • All past prices of a stock are reflected in today's stock price. • Technical analysis cannot be used to predict and beat a market. • All public information is calculated into a stock's current share price. • Neither fundamental nor technical analysis can be used to achieve superior gains. • All information in a market, whether public or private, is accounted for in a stock price. • Not even insider information could give an investor the advantage. Adapted from http://www.investopedia.com/exam-guide/cfa-level-1/securities-markets/weak-semistrong-strong-emh-efficient-market-hypothesis.asp#axzz27eAhlXfl The assumptions behind this hypothesis are; 1. A large number of profit-maximising participants analyse and value securities independently. 2. News regarding securities comes to the market randomly and independently. 3. Trading decisions of all the investors adjust security prices rapidly to reflect the effect of new information. . 2. Link it to the idea of the fully revealing rational expectations equilibria. The EMH is the application of Rational Expectations Theory by Muth (1961). Assuming there is only one equilibrium price, it states that outcomes do not differ systematically from what...

Words: 905 - Pages: 4

Free Essay

Efficient Market Hypothesis

...02-19-2014 FINMAN 5B 1:30-2:30 MWF D522 “TESTS AND RESULTS IN EFFICIENT MARKET HYPOTHESIS” a.) Weak Form EMH -Tests of “Statistical memory” in security prices and returns Statistical tests of independence between rates of return: * Autocorrelation tests- it is mostly support the weak-form EMH and indicates that price changes are random and some studies using more securities and more complicated tests cast some doubt. *Runs tests – it indicates randomness in prices -Tests of Trading rules Comparison of trading rules to a buy-and-hold policy * Some filter rules seem yield above-average profits with small filters, but only before taking into account the substantial transactions costs involved * Trading rule results have been mixed, and most have not been able to beat a buy-and-hold policy Problems with tests: *Cannot be definitive since trading rules can be complex and there are too many to test them all *Testing constraints- it use only publicly available data, it should include all transactions costs and it should adjust the results for risk (an apparently successful strategy may just be a very risky strategy). Results generally support the weak-form EMH, but results are not unanimous- it shows that some strategies too subjective to test and not all trading rules are disclosed. b.) Semi Strong Form EMH -Tests often involve “market-adjusted returns” It is created by subtracting the market return from the security’s return, thereby defining a security’s...

Words: 843 - Pages: 4

Premium Essay

Efficient Market Hypothesis

...Efficient Market Hypothesis * EMH emerged in the 1950s due to early application of computers in analysis of time series behaviour of economic variables. * The general idea of EMH is that markets incorporate all available information into all prices and the assumptions are that there is elimination of riskless profit opportunities and all prices of stocks are equal to their fundamental value and we have Rational expectations: agents use optimal forecasts based on all information available so as to minimise the forecast error. * In 1970 Eugine Fama defined EMH and divided it into 3 main forms. There are three main forms of EMH that are usually tested by researchers. * Weak form states that past prices have no influence on current prices or in other words it is impossible to use past information to predict future prices since all this info is already priced into stocks * Semi strong form states that market efficiency takes into account all publicly available information, past and present, such as financial reports, public announcements * Strong form states that all information, including that of insiders is reflected in prices and therefore cannot be useful in price forecasting * Early tests which focus on the performance of investment analysts and mutual funds tend to support the EMH in that past good performance does not indicate that an advisor or mutual fund will perform well in the future. For example – Jensen (1967) measures the predictive...

Words: 814 - Pages: 4

Premium Essay

Emh (the Efficient Market Hypothesis.)

...ASSIGNMENT OF INVESTMENT AND PORTFOLIO ANALYSIS Efficient Market Hypothesis (EMH) SUBMITTED TO DR. NIAMAT KHAN SUBMITTED BY SSH SHAYKH ROLL NO: 04 INSTITUTE OF MANAGEMENT STUDY UNIVERSITY OF PESHAWAR Efficient Market Hypothesis (EMH) Has been consented as one of the cornerstones of modern financial economics. Fama first defined the term "efficient market" in financial literature in 1965 as one in which security prices fully reflect all available information. The market is efficient if the reaction of market prices to new information should be immediate and impartial. Efficient market hypothesis is the initiative that information is quickly, and efficiently integrated into asset prices at any position in time, so that old information cannot be used to foretell future price movements. Therefore, three versions of EMH are being notable depends on the level of available information. TYPES OF Efficient Market Hypothesis (EMH) Weak form EMH The current asset prices already imitate past price and volume information. The information enclosed in the past succession of prices of a security is completely reflected in the current market price of that security. It is named weak form because the security prices are the most publicly and easily available pieces of information. It implies that no one should be able to smash the market using something that "everybody else knows". Yet, there are still numbers of financial researchers who are studying the past stock price cycle...

Words: 1232 - Pages: 5

Free Essay

Weak Form Efficiency and Calendar Anomalies: Comparison Between Developed and Developing Equity Markets

...Developed and Developing Equity Markets Syed Zulfiqar Ali Shah Assistant Professor-Finance, Department of Business Administration Faculty of Management Sciences, International Islamic University Islamabad E-mail: zulfiqar.shah@gmail.com Muhammad Husnain Ph.D Scholar (Finance) Mohammad Ali Jinnah University Islamabad Email: Husnain_ctn@yahoo.com Abstract Financial economists have continuously questioned the efficient market hypothesis especially in last decade. Major part of discussion is whether the equity markets are efficient and if not then up to what extent one can forecast the meaningful future movement of equity prices. On one side there are believers of random walk and contrary there are followers of chartist theories. Those who negate the random walk suggested that there exist anomalies in the equity markets and hence are not perfectly efficient. The major objective of this study is to check the weak form of efficiency and presence of calendar anomalies in equity markets of developing and developed countries. On the basis of most recent and relatively longer horizon (14 Year) data on daily basis and a range of powerful econometrics this study suggested that in broader sense both of developed and developing equity markets are weak form inefficient. Hence there is no remarkable difference in term of market efficiency in equity markets of developed and developing countries. Hence one can reject the random walk hypothesis and therefore presence of markets efficiency is again a matter...

Words: 8230 - Pages: 33

Free Essay

“When the Price of a Stock Can Be Influenced by a “Herd” on Wall Street with Prices Set at the Margin by the Most Emotional Person, or the Greediest Person, or the Most Depressed Person, It Is Hard to Argue That the

...that the market always prices rationally. In fact, market prices are frequently nonsensical.” ------------------------------------------------- This report will analysis the statement by Warren Buffett, and it considers the contrasting evidence on the validity of the observation on the Efficient Markets Hypothesis. The report briefly outlines the forms of the Efficient Market Hypothesis, the report also analysis’s the evidence both seminal and recent on the theory relating to the three forms of the hypothesis. It also examines the theoretical role and motivation of analysts in creating market efficiency; lastly it looks at alternative perspectives on the pricing of securities. Introduction In 1984 Warren Buffett penned an article titled “The Superinvestors of Graham-and-Doddsville”, based on a speech he had given on the occasion of the 50th anniversary of his mentor Ben Graham’s legendary textbook, Security Analysis. In it, Buffett rejected the then growing (and now entrenched) view in academia that markets are ''efficient'' because ''stock prices reflect everything that is known about a company’s prospects and about the state of the economy.'' Warren Buffett argued against EMH, saying the preponderance of value investors among the world's best money managers rebuts the claim of EMH proponents that luck is the reason some investors appear more successful than others. (Hoffman, 2010) This report will either agree with Buffet or somewhat sit on the fence. A market is said...

Words: 2524 - Pages: 11

Premium Essay

The Evolution of Stock Market Efficiency over Time: a Survey of the Empirical Literature

...THE EVOLUTION OF STOCK MARKET EFFICIENCY OVER TIME: A SURVEY OF THE EMPIRICAL LITERATURE Kian-Ping Lim Universiti Malaysia Sabah and Monash University and Robert Brooks Monash University Background This paper provides an insight into the empirical literature as pertains the evolution of stock market efficiency over time, with a keen focus on the weak form Efficient Market Hypothesis (EMH). The authors provide a systematic review of the correlation between several financial factors namely: Adaptive Markets Hypothesis (AMH), Efficient Markets Hypothesis (EMH), Evolving Return Predictability, Stock markets and Weak-form EMH. The authors pay keen attention on how return predictability from past price changes is affected by key players and determinants on the stock markets. From the survey they conduct, the posit that the bulk of the empirical studies examine whether the stock market under study is or is not weak-form efficient in the absolute sense, assuming that the level of market efficiency remains unchanged throughout the estimation period. The authors acknowledge that one field that has drawn extensive investigation by scholars and other players alike is the predictability of stock returns on the basis of past price changes. This is partly due to its direct implication on weak-form market efficiency. They find that a vast majority of the literature implicitly assumes the level of market efficiency remains unchanged throughout the estimation period. However, the possibility...

Words: 1925 - Pages: 8

Premium Essay

Positive Accounting Theory

...Chapter 7 - Positive Theory Positive Accounting Theory Philosophy of PAT Million Friedman championed positive theories in economics. He stated that: (part 3 Empirical Research in Accounts of Accounting theory from Jayne Godfrey) The ultimate goal of positive science (i.e. INDUCTIVE) is • The development of a ‘theory ‘ or ‘hypothesis’; • that yields valid and meaningful “Predictions’ • about phenomena not yet “observed”. Consistent with Friedman’s view, Watts and Zimmerman asserts that: The objective of “positive accounting theory” is to “explain” and “predict” accounting practice. • “Explanation” means providing reasons for observed practice. For example, positive accounting theory seeks to explain why firms continue to use historical cost accounting and why certain firms switch between a numbers of accounting techniques. • “Prediction” of accounting practice means that the theory predicts “unobserved phenomena”. Watts and Zimmerman start their book with a fundamental statement of The Role of Theory (Chapter 1).They asserts that the objective of positive accounting theory is to explain and predict accounting practice,(p.2) “Unobserved phenomena” are not necessarily future phenomena; they include phenomena that have occurred, but on which systematic evidence has not been collected. For example – Predicting the reaction of firms to a proposed accounting standard and an explanation of why firms would lobby for and against...

Words: 2421 - Pages: 10

Free Essay

Case Study

...create passively managed mutual funds that are based on market indices, known as index funds. Advocates claim that index funds routinely beat a large majority of actively managed mutual funds (this is proved by the graph provided); one study claimed that over time, the average actively managed fund has returned 1.8% less than the S&P 500 index - a result nearly equal to the average expense ratio of mutual funds (fund expenses are a drag on the funds' return by exactly that ratio). Since index funds attempt to replicate the holdings of an index, they obviate the need for active management, and have a lower churn rate. 2. Is the graph consistent or inconsistent with market efficiency? Explain carefully. The graph is consistent with market efficiency. The efficient market hypothesis (EMH) states that it is not possible to consistently outperform the market by using any information that the market already knows, except through luck. Information or news in the EMH is defined as anything that may affect prices that is unknowable in the present and thus appears randomly in the future. Market efficiency hypothesis is the simple statement that security prices fully reflect all available information. A precondition for this strong version of the hypothesis is that information and trading costs, the costs of getting prices to reflect information, are always 0. A weaker and economically more sensible version of the efficiency hypothesis says that prices reflect information to the point where...

Words: 513 - Pages: 3

Premium Essay

Financial Crisis

...October 28, 2011 The Efficient-Market Hypothesis and the Financial Crisis Burton G. Malkiel* Abstract The world-wide financial crisis of 2008-2009 has left in its wake severely damaged economies in the United States and Europe. The crisis has also shaken the foundations of modern-day financial theory, which rested on the proposition that our financial markets were basically efficient. Critics have even suggested that the efficient--market–hypotheses (EMH) was in large part, responsible for the crises. This paper argues that the critics of EMH are using a far too restrictive interpretation of what EMH means. EMH does not imply that asset prices are always “correct.” Prices are always wrong, but no one knows for sure if they are too high or too low. EMH does not imply that bubbles in asset prices are impossible nor does it deny that environmental and behavioral factors cannot have profound influences on required rates of return and risk premiums. At its core, EMH implies that arbitrage opportunities for riskless gains do not exist in an *Princeton University. I am indebted to Alan Blinder and to the participants in the Russell Sage Conference on Economic Lessons From the Financial Crisis for extremely helpful comments. 2 efficiently functioning market and if they do appear from time to time that they do not persist. The evidence is clear that this version of EMH is strongly supported by the data. EMH can comfortably coexist with behavior finance, and the insights of Hyman...

Words: 11209 - Pages: 45

Premium Essay

Simulation

...QUESTION 8. 10 points Use the data in nyse.dta to answer these questions. Our goal here is to test the efficient markets hypothesis (EMH). The strict form of the efficient markets hypothesis states that information observable to the market prior to week t should not help predict the return in week t. The EMH presumes that any such investment opportunities will be noticed and will disappear almost instantaneously. One simple way to test this is to specify the AR(1) model returnt = ß0 + ß1return t-1 + ut as the alternative. Then, the null hypothesis is easily stated as H: ß0 = 0 Compute weekly returns in nyse.dta are computed using data from January 1976 through March 1989. The close at the next trading day was used. Consider a special form of heteroskedasticity common in financial data, that of auto-regressive conditional heteroskedasticity (ARCH) a way of describing volatility in market returns. QUESTION 9: 5 points Estimate the following equation, where us is the residuals from the AR(1) model given above: U2 = ß0 + ß1return t-1 + ut Let there be the fitted values from this equation (the estimates of the conditional variance). How many of are negative? QUESTION 10 5 points Add to the model return2t-1 and again compute the fitted values h1. Are any h1 negative? Why is the sign important? QUESTION 11 5 points. Use the from the model relating the variance in the error to the return in the last week and the return in the last week squared and estimate by weighted least...

Words: 349 - Pages: 2

Premium Essay

Finance

...CHAPTER 11 Efficient Markets and Behavioral Finance Answers to Problem Sets 1. c   2. Weak, semistrong, strong, strong, weak.   3. a. False b. False c. True d. False e. False f. True   4. a. False - In what kind of markets do financing decisions occur? Investment Decisions occur where? b. False - c. True – what information do stocks not reflect? d. False- returns are the same for what kind of stocks?   5. 6 - (-.2 + 1.45 X 5) = -1.05%.   6. a. True b. False c. True d. True – can managers increase EPS?   7. Decrease. The stock price already reflects an expected 25% increase. The 20% increase conveys bad news relative to expectations.   8. a. Executives should not plan on issuing shares based on apparent trends or cycles in their company’s stock price. b. Executives can observe their company’s stock price change and use the change as a reliable source of market-based information about the future prospects of the company. Stock price changes are the best forecast of a company’s future earnings as well as the best forecast future industry earnings. c. A financial manager evaluating the creditworthiness of a large customer could check the customer’s stock price and the yield on its debt. A falling stock price or a high yield could indicate trouble ahead. d. Don’t...

Words: 2339 - Pages: 10