Free Essay

Financial Intermediation and Credit Policy in Business Cycles

In:

Submitted By DeGoks
Words 10599
Pages 43
Financial Intermediation and Credit Policy in Business Cycle Analysis∗

1 Introduction
To motivate interest in a paper on financial factors in business fluctuations it use to be necessary to appeal either to the Great Depression or to the experiences of many emerging market economies. This is no longer necessary.
Over the past few years the United States and much of the industrialized world have experienced the worst financial crisis of the post-war. The global recession that has followed also appears to have been the most severe of this era. At the time of this writing there is evidence that the financial sector has stabilized and the real economy has stopped contracting and output growth has resumed. The path to full recovery, however, remains highly uncertain.
The timing of recent events, though, poses a challenge for writing a Handbook chapter on credit market frictions and aggregate economic activity. It is true that over the last several decades there has been a robust literature in this area. Bernanke, Gertler and Gilchrist (BGG, 1999) surveyed much of the earlier work a decade ago in the Handbook of Macroeconomics. Since the time of that survey, the literature has continued to grow. While much of this work is relevant to the current situation, this literature obviously did not anticipate all the key empirical phenomena that have played out during the current crisis. A new literature that builds on the earlier work is rapidly cropping up to address these issues. Most of these papers, though, are in preliminary working paper form.
Our plan in this chapter is to look both forward and backward. We look forward in the sense that we offer a canonical framework to think about credit market frictions and aggregate economic activity in the context of the current crisis. The framework is not meant as comprehensive description of recent events but rather as a first pass at characterizing some of the key aspects and at laying out issues for future research. We look backward by making use of earlier literature to develop the particular framework we offer. In doing so, we address how this literature may be relevant to the new issues that have arisen. We also, as best we can, characterize how very recent literature is incorporating insights from the crisis.
From our vantage, there are two broad aspects of the crisis that have not been fully captured in work on financial factors in business cycles. First, by all accounts, the current crisis has featured a significant disruption of financial
2
intermediation.1 Much of the earlier macroeconomics literature with financial frictions emphasized credit market constraints on non-financial borrowers and treated intermediaries largely as a veil (see, e.g. BGG). Second, to combat the crisis, both the monetary and fiscal authorities in many countries including the US. have employed various unconventional policy measures that involve some form of direct lending in credit markets.
From the standpoint of the Federal Reserve, these "credit" policies represent a significant break from tradition. In the post war era, the Fed scrupulously avoided any exposure to private sector credit risk. However, in the current crisis the central bank has acted to offset the disruption of intermediation by making imperfectly secured loans to financial institutions and by lending directly to high grade non-financial borrowers. In addition, the fiscal authority acting in conjunction with the central bank injected equity into the major banks with the objective of improving credit flows. Though the issue is not without considerable controversy, many observers argue that these interventions helped stabilized financial markets and, as consequence, helped limit the decline of real activity. Since these policies are relatively new, much of the existing literature is silent about them.
With this background in mind, we begin in the next section by developing a baseline model that incorporates financial intermediation into an otherwise frictionless business cycle framework. Our goal is twofold: first to illustrate how disruptions in financial intermediation can induce a crisis that affects real activity; and second, to illustrate how various credit market interventions by the central bank and the Treasury of the type we have seen recently, might work to mitigate the crisis.
As in Bernanke and Gertler (1989), Kiyotaki and Moore (1997) and others, we endogenize financial market frictions by introducing an agency problem between borrowers and lenders.2 The agency problem works to introduce a wedge between the cost of external finance and the opportunity cost of in-
1For a description of the disruption of financial intermediation during the current recession, see Brunnermeier (2008), Gorton (2008) and Bernanke (2009). For a more general description of financial crisis over the last several hundred years, see Reinhart and Rogoff
(2009).
2A partial of other macro models with financial frictions in this vein includes,
Williamson (1987), Kehoe and Livene (1994), Holmstrom and Tirole (1997), Carlstrom and Fuerst (1997), Caballero and Kristhnamurthy (2001), Kristhnamurthy (2003), Christiano,
Motto and Rostagno (2005), Lorenzoni (2008), Fostel and Geanakoplos (2009), and
Brunnermeir and Sannikov (2009).
3
ternal finance, which adds to the overall cost of credit that a borrower faces.
The size of the external finance premium, further, depends on the condition of borrower balance sheets. Roughly speaking, as a borrower’s percentage stake in the outcome of an investment project increases, his or her incentive to deviate from the interests of lenders’ declines. The external finance premium then declines as a result.
In general equilibrium, a "financial accelerator" emerges. As balance sheets strengthen with improved economics conditions, the external finance problem declines, which works to enhance borrower spending, thus enhancing the boom. Along the way, there is mutual feedback between the financial and real sectors. In this framework, a crisis is a situation where balance sheets of borrowers deteriorate sharply, possibly associated with a sharp deterioration in asset prices, causing the external finance premium to jump. The impact of the financial distress on the cost of credit then depresses real activity.3
Bernanke and Gertler (1989), Kiyotaki andMoore (1997) and others focus on credit constraints faced by non-financial borrowers.4 As we noted earlier, however, the evidence suggests that disruption of financial intermediation is a key feature of both recent and historical crises. Thus we focus our attention here on financial intermediation.
We begin by supposing that financial intermediaries have skills in evaluating and monitoring borrowers, which makes it efficient for credit to flow from lenders to non-financial borrowers through the intermediaries. In particular, we assume that households deposit funds in financial intermediaries that in turn lend funds to non-financial firms. We then introduce an agency problem that potentially constrains the ability of intermediaries to obtain funds from depositors. When the constraint is binding (or there is some chance it may bind), the intermediary’s balance sheet limits its ability to obtain deposits.
In this instance, the constraint effectively introduces a wedge between the loan and deposit rates. During a crisis, this spread widens substantially, which in turn sharply raises the cost of credit that non-financial borrowers face. As recent events suggest, however, in a crisis, financial institutions face
3Most of the models focus on the impact of borrower constraints on producer durable spending. See Monacelli (2009) and Iacoviello (2005) for extensions to consumer durables and housing. Jermann and Quadrini (2009), amongst others, focus on borrowing constraints on employment.
4An exception is Holmstrom and Tirole (1997). More recent work includes see He and
Kristhnamurthy (2009), and Angeloni and Faia (2009).
4
difficulty not only in obtaining depositor funds in retail financial markets but also in obtaining funds from one another in wholesale ("inter-bank") markets. Indeed, the first signals of a crisis are often strains in the interbank market. We capture this phenomenon by subjecting financial institutions to idiosyncratic "liquidity" shocks, which have the effect of creating surplus and deficits of funds across financial institutions. If the interbank market works perfectly, then funds flow smoothly from institutions with surplus funds to those in need. In this case, loan rates are thus equalized across different financial institutions. Aggregate behavior in this instance resembles the case of homogeneous intermediaries.
However, to the extent that the agency problemthat limits an intermediary’s ability to obtain funds from depositors also limits its ability to obtain funds from other financial institutions and to the extent that nonfinancial firms can obtain funds only from a limited set of financial intermediaries, disruptions of inter-bank markets are possible that can affect real activity.
In this instance, intermediaries with deficit funds offer higher loan rates to nonfinancial firms than intermediaries with surplus funds. In a crisis this gap widens. Financial markets effectively become segmented and sclerotic. As we show, the inefficient allocation of funds across intermediaries can further depress aggregate activity.
In section 3 we incorporate credit policies within the formal framework.
In practice the central bank employed three broad types of policies. The first, which was introduced early in the crisis, was to permit discount window lending to banks secured by private credit. The second, introduced in the wake of the Lehmann default was to lend directly in relatively high grade credit markets, including markets in commercial paper, agency debt and mortgagebacked securities. The third (and most controversial) involved direct assistance to large financial institutions, including the equity injections and debt guarantees under the Troubled Assets Relief Program (TARP) as well as the emergency loans to JPMorgan Chase (who took over Bear Stearns) and AIG.
We stress that within our framework, the net benefits from these various credit market interventions are increasing in the severity of the crisis. This helps account for why it makes sense to employ them only in crisis situations.
In section 4, we use the model to simulate numerically a crisis that has some key features of the current crisis. Absent credit market frictions, the disturbance initiating the crisis induces only a mild recession. With credit frictions (especially those in interbank market), however, an endogenous disruption of financial intermediation works to magnify the downturn. We then
5
explore how various credit policies can help mitigate the situation.
Our baseline model is quite parsimonious and meant mainly to exposit the key issues. In section 5, we discuss a number of questions and possible extensions. In some cases, we discuss a relevant literature, stressing the implications of this literature for going forward.
2 A Canonical Model of Financial Intermediation and Business Fluctuations
Overall, the specific business cycle model is a hybrid of Gertler and Karadi’s
(2009) framework that allows for financial intermediation and Kiyotaki and
Moore’s (2008) framework that allows for liquidity risk. We keep the core macro model simple in order to see clearly the role of intermediation and liquidity. On the other hand, we also allow for some features prevalent in conventional quantitative macro models (such as Christiano, Eichenbaum and Evans (2005), Smets and Wouters (2007)) in order to get rough sense of the importance of the factors we introduce.5
For simplicity we restrict attention to a purely real model and only credit policies, as opposed to conventional monetary models. Extending the model to allow for nominal rigidities is straightforward (see., e.g., Gertler and
Karadi, 2009), and permits studying conventional monetary policy along with unconventional policies. However, because much of the insight into how credit market frictions may affect real activity and how various credit policies may work can be obtained from studying a purely real model, we abstract from nominal frictions.6
5Some recent monetary DSGE models that incorporate financial factors include Christiano,
Motto, and Rostagno (2009) and Gilchrist, Ortiz and Zakresjek (2009).
6There, however, several insights that monetary models add, however. First, if the zero lower bound on the nominal interest is binding, the financial market disruptions will have a larger effect than otherwise. This is because the central bank is not free to further reduce the nominal rate to offset the crisis. Second, to the extent there are nominal price and/or wage rigidities that induce countercyclical markups, the effect of the credit market disruption and aggregate activity is amplified. See, e.g., Gertler and Karadi (2009) and
Del Negro, Ferrero, Eggertsson and Kiyotaki (2010) for an illustration of both of these points. 6
2.1 Physical Setup
Before describing our economy with financial frictions, we present the physical environment. There are a continuum of firms of mass unity located on a continuum of islands. Each firm produces output using an identical constant returns to scale Cobb-Douglas production function with capital and labor as inputs.
Capital is not mobile, but labor is perfectly mobile across firms and islands.
Because labor is perfectly mobile, we can express aggregate output Yt as a function of aggregate capital Kt and aggregate labor hours Lt as:
Yt = AtKt αL1−α t , 0 < α < 1, (1) where At is aggregate productivity which follows a Markov process.
Each period investment opportunities arrive randomly to a fraction πi of islands. On a fraction πn = 1 − πi of islands, there are no investment opportunities.
Only firms on islands with investment opportunities can acquire new capital. The arrival of investment opportunities is i.i.d. across time and across islands. The structure of this idiosyncratic risk provides a simple way to introduce liquidity needs by firms, following Kiyotaki and Moore (2008).
Let It denote aggregate investment, δ the rate of physical deprecation and ψt+1 a shock to the quality of capital. Then the law of motion for capital is given by :
Kt+1 = ψt+1[It + πi(1 − δ)Kt] + ψt+1πn(1 − δ)Kt
= ψt+1[It + (1 − δ)Kt]. (2)
The first term of the right reflects capital accumulated by firms on investing islands and the second is capital that remains on non-investing islands, after depreciation. Summing across islands yields a conventional aggregate relation for the evolution of capital, except for the presence of the disturbance ψt+1, which we refer to as a capital quality shock. Following the finance literature
(e.g., Merton (1973)), we introduce the capital quality shock as a simple way to introduce an exogenous source of variation in the value of capital. As will become clear later, the market price of capital will be endogenous within our framework. In this regard, the capital quality shock will serve as an exogenous trigger of asset price dynamics. The random variable ψt+1 is best thought of as capturing some form of economic obsolescence, as opposed to
7
physical depreciation.7 We assume the capital quality shock ψt+1 also follows a Markov process.8
Firms on investing islands acquire capital from capital goods producers who operate in a national market. There are convex adjustment costs in the gross rate of change in investment for capital goods producers. Aggregate output is divided between household consumption Ct, investment expenditures, and government consumption Gt,
Yt = Ct + [1 + f (
It
It−1
)]It + Gt (3) where f ( It
It−1
)It reflects physical adjustment costs, with f(1) = f 0(1) = 0 and f 00(It/It−1) > 0. Thus the aggregate production function of capital goods producers is decreasing returns to scale in the short-run and is constant returns to scale in the long-run.
Next we turn to preferences:
Et
∞X i=0 βi

ln(Ct+i − γCt+i−1) − χ 1 + ε
L1+ε
t+i
¸
(4) where Et is the expectation operator conditional on date t information and γ ∈ (0, 1). We abstract from many frictions in the conventional DSGE framework
(e.g. nominal price and wage rigidities, variable capital utilization, etc.). However, we allow both habit formation of consumption and adjustment costs of investment because, as the DSGE literature has found, these features are helpful for reasonable quantitative performance and because they can be kept in the model at minimal cost of additional complexity.
If there were no financial frictions, the competitive equilibrium would correspond to a solution of the planner’s problem that involves choosing aggregate quantities (Yt, Lt, Ct, It, Kt+1) as a function of the aggregate state
7One way to motivate this disturbance is to assume that final output is a C.E.S. composite of a continuum of intermediate goods that are in turn produced by employing capital and labor in a Cobb-Douglas production technology. Suppose that, once capital is installed, capital is good-specific and that each period a random fraction of goods become obsolete and are replaced by new goods. The capital used to produced the obsolete goods is now worthless and the capital for the new goods is not fully on line. The aggregate capital stock will then evolve according to equation. (2).
8Other recent papers that make use of this kind of disturbance include, Gertler and
Karadi (2009), Brunnermeier and Sannikov (2009) and Gourio (2009).
8
(Ct−1, It−1, Kt, At, ψt) in order to maximize the expected discounted utility of the representative household subject to the resource constraints. This frictionless economy (a standard real business cycle model) will serve as a benchmark to which we may compare the implications of the financial frictions.
In what follows we will introduce banks that intermediate funds between households and non-financial firms in a retail financial market. In addition, we will allow for a wholesale inter-bank market, where banks with surplus funds on non-investment islands lend to banks in need of funds on investing islands. We will also introduce financial frictions that may impede credit flows in both the retail and wholesale financial markets and then study the consequences for real activity.
2.2 Households
In our economy with credit frictions, households lend to non-financial firms via financial intermediaries. Following Gertler and Karadi (2009), we formulate the household sector in way that permits maintaining the tractability of the representative agent approach.
In particular, there is a representative household with a continuum of members of measure unity. Within the household there are 1 − f "workers" and f "bankers". Workers supply labor and return their wages to the household. Each banker manages a financial intermediary (which we will call a "bank") and transfers nonnegative dividends back to household subject to its flow of fund constraint. Within the family there is perfect consumption insurance. Households do not hold capital directly. Rather, they deposit funds in banks. (It may be best to think of them as depositing funds in banks other than the ones they own). In our model, bank deposits are riskless one period securities. Households may also hold riskless one period government debt which is a perfect substitute for bank deposits.
Let Wt denote the wage rate, Tt lump sum taxes, Rt the gross return on riskless debt from t − 1 to t, Dht the quantity of riskless debt held, and
Πt net distributions from ownership of both banks and non-financial firms.
Then the household chooses consumption, labor supply and riskless debt
(Ct, Lt, Dht+1) to maximize expected discounted utility (4) subject to the flow of funds constraint,
9
Ct = WtLt + Πt − Tt + RtDht − Dht+1. (5)
Let uCt denote the marginal utility of consumption and Λt,t+1 the household’s stochastic discount factor. Then the household’s first order conditions for labor supply and consumption/saving are given by
EtuCtWt = χLϕ t , (6)
EtΛt,t+1Rt+1 = 1, (7) with uCt ≡ (Ct − γCt−1)−1 − βγ(Ct+1 − γCt)−1 and
Λt,t+1 ≡ β uCt+1 uCt
.
Because banks may be financially constrained, bankers will retain earnings to accumulate assets. Absent some motive for paying dividends, they may find it optimal to accumulate to the point where the financial constraint they face is no longer binding. In order to limit bankers’ ability to save to overcome financial constraints, we allow for turnover between bankers and workers. In particular, we assume that with i.i.d. probability 1 −σ, a banker exits next period, (which gives an average survival time = 1
1−σ ). Upon exiting, a banker transfers retained earnings to the household and becomes a worker. Note that the expected survival time may be quite long (in our baseline calibration it is ten years.) It is critical, however, that the expected horizon is finite, in order to motivate payouts while the financial constraints are still binding.
Each period, (1 − σ)f workers randomly become bankers, keeping the number in each occupation constant. Finally, because in equilibrium bankers will not be able to operate without any financial resources, each new banker receives a "start up" transfer from the family as a small constant fraction of the total assets of entrepreneurs. Accordingly, Πt is net funds transferred to the household:i.e., funds transferred from exiting bankers minus the funds transferred to new bankers (aside from small profits of capital producers).
An alternative to our approach of having a consolidated family of workers and bankers would be to have the two groups as distinct sets of agents, without any consumption insurance between the two groups. It is unlikely, however, that the key results of our paper would change qualitatively. By
10
sticking with complete consumption insurance, we are able to have lending and borrowing in equilibrium and still maintain tractability of the representative household approach.
2.3 Banks
To finance lending in each period, banks raise funds in a national financial market. Within the national financial market, there is a retail market, where banks obtain deposits from households; and a wholesale market, where banks borrows and lend amongst one and another.
At the beginning of the period each bank raises deposits dt from households in the retail financial market at the deposit rate Rt+1. After the retail financial market closes, investment opportunities for nonfinancial firms arrive randomly to different islands. Banks can only make loans to nonfinancial firms located on the same island. As we stated earlier, for a fraction πi of locations, new investment opportunities are available to finance as well as existing projects. Conversely, for a fraction πn = 1− πi, no new investments are available to finance, only existing ones. On the interbank market, banks on islands with new lending opportunities will borrow funds from those on islands with no new project arrivals.9
Financial frictions affect real activity in our framework via the impact on funds available to banks. For simplicity, however, there is no friction in transferring funds between a bank and non-financial firms in the same island. In particular, we suppose that the bank is efficient at evaluating and monitoring non-financial firms of the same island, and also at enforcing contractual obligations with these borrowers. We assume the costs to a bank of performing these activities are negligible. Accordingly, given its supply of available funds, a bank can lend frictionlessly to non-financial firms of the same island against their future profits. In this regard, firms are able to offer banks perfectly state-contingent debt. It is simplest to think of the bank’s claim on nonfinancial firms as equity.
9Our model is thus one where liquidity problems emerge in part due to limited market participation, in the spirit of Allen and Gale (1995, 2007) and others. This is because within our framework (i) only banks of the same island can make loans to nonfinancial firms and (ii) banks on investing islands cannot raise additional funds in the retail financial market after they learn their customers have investment opportunities.
11
After learning about its lending opportunities, a bank decides the volume of loans sht to make to non-financial firms and the volume of interbank borrowing bht where the superscript h = i, n denotes the island type (i for investing and n for non-investing) on which the bank is located during the period. Let Qht be price of a loan (or "asset") - i.e. the market price of the bank’s claim on the future returns from one unit of present capital of nonfinancial firm at the end of period. We index the asset price by h because, owing to temporal market segmentation, Qht may depend on the volume of opportunities that the bank faces.
For an individual bank, the flow-of-funds constraint implies the value of loans funded within a given period, Qht sht , must equal the sum of the bank net worth nht
, its borrowings on the interbank market bht and deposits dt :
Qht
sht
= nht
+ bht
+ dt. (8)
Note that dt does not depend upon the volume of the lending opportunities, which is not realized at the time of obtaining deposits.
Let Rbt be the interbank interest rate from periods t−1 to period t. Then net worth at t is the gross payoff from assets funded at t − 1, net borrowing costs, as follows: nht = [Zt + (1 − δ)Qht
]ψtst−1 − Rbtbt−1 − Rtdt−1, (9) where Zt is the dividend payment at t on the loans the bank funds at t − 1.
(Recall that ψt is an exogenous aggregate shock to the quality of capital).
Observe that the gross payoff from assets depends on the location specific asset price Qht
, which is the reason nht depends on the realization of the location specific shock at t.
Given that the bank pays dividends only when it exits (which occurs with a constant probability), the objective of the bank at the end of period t is the expected present value of future dividends, as follows
Vt = Et
∞X
i=1
(1 − σ)σi−1Λt,t+inh t+i, (10) where Λt,t+i is the stochastic discount factor, which is equal to the marginal rate of substitution between consumption of date t + i and date t of the representative household.
In order to maintain tractability, we make assumptions to ensure that we do not have to keep track of the distribution of net worth across islands.
12
In particular, we allow for arbitrage at the beginning of each period (before investment opportunities arrive) to ensure that ex ante expected rates of return to intermediation are equal across islands. In particular, we suppose that a fraction of banks on islands where expected returns are low can move to islands where they are high. Before they move, they sell their existing loans to nonfinancial firms to the other banks that remain on the island in exchange for inter-bank loans that the remaining banks have been holding in their portfolios. These transactions keep each existing loan to nonfinancial firms on the island it was initiated. At the same time, they permit arbitrage to equalize returns across markets ex ante.
As will become clear later, ex ante expected returns being equalized across islands requires that the ratio of total intermediary net worth to total capital on each island be the same at the beginning of each period10. Thus, given this arbitrage activity and given that the liquidity shock is i.i.d., we do not have to keep track of the beginning of period distribution of net worth across islands. To motivate an endogenous constraint on the bank’s ability to obtain funds in either the retail or wholesale financial markets, we introduce the following simple agency problem: We assume that after an bank obtains funds, the banker managing the bank may transfer a fraction θ of "divertable" assets to his or her family. Divertable assets consists of total gross assets Qht sht net a fraction ω of interbank borrowing bht
. If a bank diverts assets for its personal gain, it defaults on its debt and is shut down. The creditors may re-claim the remaining fraction 1−θ of funds. Because its creditors recognize the bank’s incentive to divert funds, they will restrict the amount they lend.
In this way a borrowing constraint may arise.
We allow for the possibility that bank may be constrained not only in obtaining funds from depositors but also in obtaining funds from other banks.
Though we permit the tightness of the constraint faced in each market to differ. In particular, the parameter ω indexes (inversely) the relative degree of friction in the interbank market:
With ω = 1, banks cannot divert assets financed by borrowing from other banks: Lending banks are able to perfectly recover the assets that underlie the loans they make. In this case, the interbank market operates frictionlessly,
10In turn, this requires a movement of net worth from low return to high return islands that is equal in total to the quantity of interbank loans issued in the previous period. The asset exchange between moving and staying banks described in the text accomplishes this arbitrage. 13 and banks are not constrained in borrowing from one another. They may only be constrained in obtaining funds from depositors.
In contrast, with ω = 0, lending banks are no more efficient than depositors in recovering assets from borrowing banks. In this case, the friction that constrains a banks ability to obtaining funds on the interbank market is the same as for the retail financial market. In general, we can allow parameter ω to differ for borrowing versus lending banks. However, maintaining symmetry simplifies the analysis without affecting the main results.
We assume that the banker’s decision over whether to divert funds must be made at the end of the period after the realization of the idiosyncratic uncertainty that determines its type, but before the realization of aggregate uncertainty in the following period. Here the idea is that if the banker is going to divert funds, it takes time to position assets and this must be done between the periods (e.g., during the night). Let Vt(sht
, bht
, dt) be the maximized value of Vt, given an asset and liability configuration
¡
sht, bht
, dt
¢
at the end of period t. Then in order to ensure the bank does not divert funds, the following incentive constraint must hold for each bank type:
Vt(sht
, bht
, dt) ≥ θ(Qht sht − ωbht
). (11)
In general the value of the bank at the end of period t − 1 satisfies the
Bellman equation
Vt−1(st−1, bt−1, dt−1)
= Et−1Λt−1,t
X
h=i,n πh{(1 − σ)nht
+ σM ax dt [Max sht ,bht
Vt(sht
, bht
, dt)]}. (12)
Note that the loans and interbank borrowing are chosen after a shock to the loan opportunity is realized while deposits are chosen before.
To solve the decision problem, we first guess that the value function is linear: Vt(sht
, bht
, dt) = νstsht
− νbtbht
− νtdt (13) where νst, νbt and νt are time varying parameters, and verify this guess later.
Note that νst is the marginal value of assets at the end of period t; νbt is the marginal cost of interbank debt; and νt is the marginal cost of deposits.11
11The parameters in the conjectured value function are independent of the individual bank’s type because the value function is measured after the bank finishes its transaction for the current this period and because the shock to the loan opportunity is i.i.d. across periods. 14
Let λh t be the Lagrangian multiplier for the incentive constraint (11) faced by bank of type h and λt ≡
P
h=i,n πhλh t be the average of this multiplier across states. Then given the conjectured form of the value function, we may express the first order conditions for dt, sht
, and λh t , as:
(νbt − νt) (1+λt) = θωλt, (14) μ νst
Qht
− νbt

(1 + λh
t) = λh t θ(1 − ω), (15)
[θ − ( νst Qht
− νt)]Qht sht − [θω − (νbt − νt)]bht
≤ νtnht
. (16)
According to equation (14), the marginal cost of interbank borrowing exceeds the marginal cost of deposit if and only if the incentive constraint is expected to bind for some state (λt > 0) and the inter-bank market operates more efficiently than the retail deposit market (i.e., ω > 0, meaning that assets financed by interbank borrowing are harder to divert than those financed by deposits). Equation (15) states that the marginal value of assets in terms of goods νst
Qht
exceeds the marginal cost of interbank borrowing by banks on type h island to the extent that the incentive constraint is binding (λh t > 0) and there is a friction in interbank market (ω < 1). Finally, equation (16) is the incentive constraint. It requires that the values of the bank’s net worth
(or equity capital), νtnht
, must be at least as large as weighted measure of assets Qht sht net of interbank borrowing bht that a bank holds. In this way, the agency problem introduces an endogenous balance sheet constraint on banks. The model for the general case with 0 ≤ ω ≤ 1 is somewhat cumbersome to solve. There are, however, two interesting special cases that provide insight into the models workings. In case 1, there is a perfect interbank market, which arises when ω = 1. In case 2, the frictions in the interbank market are of the same magnitude as in the retail financial market, which arises when ω = 0. We next proceed to characterize each of the cases. The Appendix then provides a solution for the general case of an interbank friction with ω < 1.
15
2.3.1 Case 1: Frictionless wholesale financial market (ω = 1)
If banks cannot divert assets financed by inter-bank borrowing (ω = 1), interbank lending is frictionless. As equation (15) suggests, perfect arbitrage in the interbank market equalizes the shadow values of assets in each market, implying νst
Qbt
= νst
Ql
t
, which in turn implies Qbt
= Ql t = Qt. The perfect interbank market, further, implies that the marginal value of assets in terms of goods νst
Qt
must equal the marginal cost of borrowing on the interbank market νbt, νst
Qt
= νbt. (17)
Because asset prices are equal across island types, we can drop the h superscript in this case. Accordingly, let μt denote the excess value of a unit of assets relative to deposits, i.e., the marginal value of holding assets νst
Qt
net the marginal cost of deposits νt. Then, given that banks are constrained in the retail deposit market, equations (14) and (15) imply that the μt ≡ νst Qt − νt > 0. (18)
It follows that the incentive constraint (16) in this case may expressed as
Qtst − bt = φtnt (19) with φt = νt θ − μt
. (20)
Note that since interbank borrowing is frictionless, the constraint applies to assets intermediated minus interbank borrowing. How tightly the constraint binds depends positively on the fraction of net assets the bank can divert and negatively on the excess value of bank assets, given by μt. The higher the excess value is, the greater is the franchise value of the bank and the less likely it is to divert funds.
Let Ωt+1be the marginal value of net worth at date t+1 and let Rkt+1 is the gross rate of return on bank assets. Then after combining the conjectured value function with the Bellman equation, we can verify the value function is linear in
¡
sht
, bht
, dt
¢
if μt and νt satisfy: νt = EtΛt,t+1Ωt+1Rt+1 (21)
16
μt = EtΛt,t+1Ωt+1(Rkt+1 − Rt+1) (22) with Ωt+1 = 1− σ + σ(νt+1 + φt+1μt+1), and
Rkt+1 = ψt+1
Zt+1 + (1 − δ)Qt+1
Qt
.
Let us define the "augmented stochastic discount factor" as the stochastic discount factor Λt,t+1 weighted by the (stochastic) marginal value of net worth
Ωt+1. (The marginal value of net worth is a weighted average of marginal values for exiting and for continuing banks. If a continuing bank has an additional net worth, it can save the cost of deposits and can increase assets by the leverage ratio φt+1, where assets have an excess value equal to μt+1 per unit). According to (21), the cost of deposits per unit to the bank νt is the expected product of the augmented stochastic discount factor and the deposit rate Rt+1. Similarly from (22), the excess value of assets per unit, μt, is the expected product of the augmented stochastic discount factor and the excess return Rkt+1 − Rt+1.
Since the leverage ratio net of interbank borrowing, φt, is independent of both bank-specific factors and island-specific factors, we can sum across individual banks to obtain the relation for the demand for total bank assets
QtSt as a function of total net worth Nt as:
QtSt = φtNt (23) where φt is given by equation (20). Overall, a setting with a perfect interbank is isomorphic to one where banks do not face idiosyncratic liquidity risks.
Aggregate bank lending is simply constrained by aggregate bank capital.
If the banks’ balance sheet constraints are binding in the retail financial market, there will be excess returns on assets over deposits. However, a perfect interbank market leads to arbitrage in returns to assets across market as follows:
EtΛt,t+1Ωt+1Rkt+1 = EtΛt,t+1Ωt+1Rbt+1 > EtΛt,t+1Ωt+1Rt+1. (24)
As will become clear, a crisis in such economy is associated with an increase in the excess return on assets for banks of all types.
17
2.3.2 Case 2: Symmetric frictions in wholesale and retail financial markets (ω = 0)
In this instance the bank’s ability to divert funds is independent of whether the funds are obtained in either the retail or wholesale financial markets. This effectively makes the borrowing constraint the bank faces symmetric in the two credit markets. As a consequence, interbank loans and deposits become perfect substitutes as sources of finance. Accordingly, equation (14) implies that the marginal cost of interbank borrowing is equal to the marginal cost of deposits νbt = νt. (25)
Here, even if banks on investing islands are financially constrained, banks on non-investing islands may or may not be. Roughly speaking, if the constraint on inter-bank borrowing binds tightly, banks in non-investing islands will be more inclined to use their funds to re-finance existing investments rather than lend them to banks on investing islands. This raises the likelihood that banks on non-investing islands will earn zero excess returns on their assets.
Because asset supply per unit of bank net worth is larger on investing islands than on non-investing islands, the asset price is lower, i.e., Qi t < Qnt
.
Intuitively, given that the leverage ratio constraint limits banks’ ability to acquire assets, prices will clear at lower values on investing islands where supplies per unit of bank net worth are greater. In the previous case of a perfect interbank market, funds flow from non-investing to investing islands to equalize asset prices. Here, frictions in the inter-bank market limit the degree of arbitrage, keeping Qi t below Qnt.
A lower asset price on the investing island, of course, means a higher expected return. Let μht
≡ νst
Qht
− νt be the excess value of assets on a type h island. Then we have: μi t > μnt
≥ 0. (26)
The positive excess return implies that banks in the investing islands are finance constrained. Thus the leverage ratios for banks on each island type are given by:
Qi
tsi t ni t = φi t = νt θ − μi t (27)
Qnt
snt nnt ≤ φn t = νt θ − μnt
, and μ Qnt snt nnt
− φn t ¶ μnt = 0. (28)
18
In this case the method of undetermined coefficients yields νt = EtΛt,t+1
X
h0=i,n πh0Ωh0 t+1Rt+1 = Et h0 Λt,t+1Ωh0 t+1Rt+1 (29) μht = Et h0 Λt,t+1Ωh0 t+1(Rhh0 kt+1 − Rt+1) (30) with Ωh0 t+1 = 1− σ + σ(νt+1 + φh0 t+1μh0 t+1), and
Rhh0
kt+1 = ψt+1
Zt+1 + (1 − δ)Qh0 t+1 Qht
.
With an imperfect interbank market, both the marginal value of net worth
Ωh0
t+1 and the return on assets Rhh0 kt+1 depend on which island type a bank enters in the subsequent period. Accordingly, we index each by h0 and take expectations over h0 conditional on date t information denoted as Et h0 .
Because leverage ratios differ across islands, we aggregate separately across bank-types to obtain the aggregate relations:
Qi
tSi t = φi tNi t (31)
Qnt
Sn t ≤ φn t Nn t , and (Qnt
Sn
t − φn t Nn t ) μnt
= 0, (32) where φi t and φn t are given by equations (27) and (28). As we will see, in the general equilibrium, investment will depend on the price of capital on "investing" islands, Qi
t. Accordingly, it is the aggregate balance sheet constraint on asset demand for banks on investing islands, given by equation
(31) that becomes critical for interactions between financial conditions and production. Next, from (25, 26, 29, 30), we learn that the returns obey
Et
h0
Λt,t+1Ωh0
t+1Rih0 kt+1 > Et h0 Λt,t+1Ωh0 t+1Rnh0 kt+1 (33)
≥ Et h0 Λt,t+1Ωh0 t+1Rbt+1 = Et h0 Λt,t+1Ωh0 t+1Rt+1. with ≥ holds with strict inequality iff μnt
> 0 and holds with equality iff μnt = 0. With an imperfect inter-bank market, a crisis is associated with both a rise in the excess return for banks on investing islands and increase in the dispersion of returns between island types.
19
As we show in Appendix, for the case where the interbank market is imperfect but operates with less friction than the retail deposit market (i.e.,
0 < ω < 1), the interbank rate will lie between the return on loans and the deposit rates. Intuitively, because a dollar interbank credit will tighten the incentive constraint by less than a dollar of deposits (since lending banks are able to recover a greater fraction of creditor assets than are depositors), the interbank rate exceeds the deposit rate. However, because lending banks are not able to perfectly recover assets ω < 1, there is still imperfect arbitrage which keeps the expected discounted interbank rate below the expected discounted return to loans.
2.4 Evolution of Bank Net Worth
Let total net worth for type h banks, Nh t , equal the sum of the net worth of existing entrepreneurs Nh ot (o for old) and of entering entrepreneurs Nh yt (y for young):
Nh
t = Nh ot + Nh yt. (34)
Net worth of existing entrepreneurs equals earnings on assets net debt payments made in the previous period, multiplied by the fraction that survive until the current period, σ:
Nh
ot = σπh{[Zt + (1 − δ)Qht
]ψtSt−1 − RtDt−1}. (35)
Because the arrival of investment opportunity is independent across time, the interbank loans are net out in the aggregate here. We assume that the family transfers to each new banker is the fraction ξ/(1−σ) of the total value assets of exiting entrepreneurs, implying:
Nh
yt = ξ[Zt + (1 − δ)Qht
]ψtSt−1. (36)
Finally, by the balance-sheet of the entire banking sector, deposits equal the difference between total assets and bank net worth as follows,
Dt =
X
h=i,n
(Qht
Sh t − Nh t ). (37)
Observe that the evolution of net worth depends fluctuations in the return to assets.. Further, the higher the leverage of the bank is, the larger will be
20
the percentage impact of return fluctuations on net worth. Note also that a deterioration of capital quality (a decline in ψt) directly reduces net worth.
As we will show, there will also be a second round effect, as the decline in net worth induces a fire sale of assets, depressing asset prices and thus further depressing bank net worth.
2.5 Nonfinancial Firms
There are two types of non-financial firms: goods producers and capital producers.
2.5.1 Goods Producer
Competitive goods producers on different islands operate a constant returns to scale technology with capital and labor inputs, given by equation (1).
Since labor is perfectly mobile across islands, firms choose labor to satisfy
Wt = (1 − α)
Yt
Lt
(38)
It follows that we may express gross profits per unit of capital Zt as follows:
Zt =
Yt − WtLt
Kt
= αAt μ Lt
Kt
¶1−α
. (39)
As we noted earlier, conditional on obtaining funds from a bank, a goods producer does not face any further financial frictions and can commit to pay all the future gross profits to the creditor bank. A goods producer with an opportunity to invest obtains funds from an intermediary by issuing new state-contingent securities (equity) at the price Qi t . The producer then uses the funds to buy new capital goods from capital goods producers. Each unit of equity is a state-contingent claim to the future returns from one unit of investment: ψt+1Zt+1, (1 − δ)ψt+1ψt+2Zt+2, (1 − δ)2ψt+1ψt+2ψt+3Zt+3, ... .
Through perfect competition, the price of new capital goods is equal to Qi t, and goods producers earn zero profits state-by-state.
Note that given constant returns and perfect labor mobility, we do not have keep track of the distribution of capital across islands. As in the standard competitive model with constant returns, the size distribution of firms is indeterminate.
21
2.6 Capital Goods Producers
Capital producers operate in a national market. They make new capital using input of final output and subject to adjustment costs, as described in section 2.2. They sell new capital to firms on investing islands at the price
Qi
t. Given that households own capital producers, the objective of a capital producer is to choose It to solve: max Et
∞X
τ=t
Λt,τ
½
Qi
τ Iτ −

1 + f μ Iτ
Iτ −1
¶¸

¾
From profit maximization, the price of capital goods is equal to the marginal cost of investment goods production as follows,
Qi
t = 1+f μ It
It−1

+
It
It−1
f 0(
It
It−1
) − EtΛt,t+1(
It+1
It
)2f 0(
It+1
It
) (40)
Profits (which arise only outside of steady state), are redistributed lump sum to households.
2.7 Equilibrium
To close the model (in the case without government policy), we require market clearing in both the market for securities and the labor market. Total securities issued on investing and non-investing islands correspond to aggregate capital acquired by each type, as follows:
Si
t = It + (1 − δ) πiKt (41)
Sn
t = (1− δ) πnKt.
Note that demand for securities by banks is given by equation (23) in the case of a frictionless interbank market and by equations (31) and (32) in the case of an imperfect interbank market. Observe first that the market price of capital on each island type will in general depend on the financial condition of the associated banks. Second, with an imperfect interbank market, the asset price will be generally lower (or, equivalently,state-contingent loans rates offered by banks will be generally greater) on investing islands than elsewhere.12 12This verifies the earlier conjecture in Section 2.3.2. For the more general case of imperfect interbank market, see Appendix 1.
22
Finally, the condition that labor demand equals labor supply requires that (1 − α)
Yt
Lt · EtuCt = χLϕ t (42)
Because of Walras’ Law, once the market for goods, labor, securities, and interbank loans is cleared, the market for riskless debt will be cleared automatically:
Dht = Dt + Dgt, where Dgt is supply of government debt. This completes the description of the model.
Absent credit market frictions, the model reduces to a real business cycle framework modified with habit formation and flow investment adjustment costs. With the credit market frictions, however, balance sheet constraints on banks ability to obtain funds in retail and wholesale market may limit real investment spending, affecting aggregate real activity. As we will show, a crisis is possible where weakening of bank balance sheets significantly disrupts credit flows, depressing real activity.
As we have discussed, one example of a factor that could weaken bank balance sheets is a deterioration of the underlying quality of capital. A negative quality shock directly reduces the value of bank net worth, forcing banks to reduce asset holdings. A second round effect on bank net worth arises as the fire sale of assets reduces the market price of capital. Further, the overall impact on bank equity of the decline in asset values is proportionate to the amount of bank leverage. With highly leveraged banks, a substantial percentage drop in bank equity may arise, leading to a significant disruption of credit flows. We illustrate this point clearly in section 4.
3 Credit Policies
During the crisis the various central banks, including the US. Federal Reserve, made use of their powers as a lender of last resort to facilitate credit flows. To justify such actions, the Fed appealed to Section 13.3 of the Federal Reserve
Act, which permits it in "unusual end exigent circumstances" to make loans to the private sector, so long as the loans are judged to be of sufficiently high grade. The statute makes clear that in normal times the Fed is not permitted to take on private credit risk. In a crisis, however, the Fed has
23
freedom to fulfill its responsibility as lender of last resort, provided that it does not absorb undue risk.
In practice, the Fed employed three general types of credit policies. First, early on it expanded discount window operations by permitting discount window loans to be collateralized by high grade private securities and also by extending the availability of the window to non-bank financial institutions.
Second, the Fed lent directly in high grade credit markets, funding assets that included commercial paper, agency debt and mortgage backed securities.
Third, the Treasury, acting in concert with the Fed, injected equity in the banking system along with supplying bank debt guarantees (together with the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation).
There is some evidence that these types of policies were effective in stabilizing the financial system. The expanded liquidity helped smoothed the flow of funds between financial institutions, effectively by dampening the turmoilinduced increases in the spread between the interbank lending rate (LIBOR) and the Treasury Bill rate. The enhanced financial distress following the
Lehmann failure, however, proved to be too much for the liquidity facilities alone to handle. At this point, the Fed set up facilities to lend directly to the commercial paper market and a number of weeks later phased in programs to purchase agency debt and mortgage backed securities. Credit spreads in each these markets fell.
The equity injections also came soon after Lehmann. Though not without controversy, the equity injections appeared to reduce stress in banking markets. Upon the initial injection of equity in mid-October 2008, credit default swap rates of the major banks fell dramatically. At the time of this writing, the receiving banks have paid back a considerable portion of the funds. Further, though risks remain, the government appears to have made money on many of these programs.
In the sub-sections below, we take a first pass at analyzing how these policies work, using our baseline model.13 As we showed in the previous section, within the context of our model, the financial market frictions open the possibility of periods of distress where excess returns on assets are abnormally high. Because they are balance sheet constrained, private financial intermediaries cannot immediately arbitrage these returns. One can view the point of the Fed’s various credit programs as facilitating this arbitrage in
13For related attempts to model credit policy, see Curdia and Woodford (2009a, 2009b),
Reis (2009), and Sargent and Wallace (1983).
24
times of crisis. In this regard, each of the various policies works somewhat differently, as we discuss below.
Before proceeding, we emphasize that, consistent with the Federal Reserve
Act, we have in mind that these interventions be used only during crises and not during normal times. Indeed, within the logic of the model, the net benefits from credit policy are increasing in the distortion of credit markets that the crisis induces, as measured by the excess return on capital.
3.1 Lending Facilities (Direct Lending)
What we mean by direct lending is meant to broadly characterize the facilities the Fed set up for direct acquisition of high quality private securities.
Lending facilities work as follows: We suppose that the central bank has both an advantage and a disadvantage relative to private lenders. The advantage is that unlike private intermediaries, the central bank is not balance sheet constrained (at least in the same way). Private citizens do not have to worry about the central bank defaulting. The liabilities it issues are government debt and it can credibly commit to honoring this debt (aside from inflation). Thus, in periods of distress where private intermediaries are unable to obtain additional funds, the central bank can obtain funds and then channel them to markets with abnormal excess returns.14
In the current crisis, the Fed funded the initial expansion of its lending programs by issuing government debt (that it borrowed from the Treasury) and then later made use of interest bearing reserves. The latter are effectively government debt. It is true that the interest rate on reserves fell to zero as the Federal Funds rate reached its lower bound, giving these reserves the appearance of money. However, once the Fed moves the Funds rate above zero it will also raise the interest rate on reserves. In this regard, the Fed’s unconventional policies should be thought of as expanded central intermediation as opposed to expanding the money supply. In the case of lending facilities, a key advantage of the central bank is that it is not constrained in its ability to funds the same way as private intermediaries may be in time
14Others have also emphasized how that special nature of government liabilities can give rise to a productive role for government financial intermediations. See, example, Sargent and Wallace (1983), Kiyotaki and Moore (2008), Gertler and Karadi (2009), and Shleifer and Vishny (2010). As originally noted by Wallace (1980), unless there is something special about government liabilities, the Miller-Modigliani theorem applies to government finance. 25 of financial distress. Another equally important advantage is that the Fed can lend in many markets. By contrast, private banks face a limited market participation constraint, i.e., they can only lend to nonfinancial firms of the same island.
At the same time, we suppose that the central bank is less efficient at intermediating funds. It faces an efficiency cost τ per unit, which may be thought of as a cost of evaluating and monitoring borrowers that is above and beyond what a private intermediary (who has specific knowledge of a particular market) would pay.15
To obtain funds, the central bank issues government debt to the private that is a perfect substitute for bank deposits, and pays the riskless real rate
Rt+1. It lends the funds in market h at the private loan rate Rhh0 kt+1 which depends upon the state of the next period h0. Observe that the central banks is not offering the funds at a subsidized rate. However, by expanding the supply of funds available in the market, it will reduce equilibrium lending rates. Let Sh t be total securities of type h intermediated, Sh pt total securities of type h intermediated by private banks, and Sh gt total type h securities intermediated by the central bank. Then total intermediation of type h assets is given by:
Qht
Sh t = Qht
(Sh
pt + Sh gt) (43)
We suppose the central bank chooses to intermediate the fraction ϕht of total credit in market h:
Sh
gt = ϕht
Sh
t (44) where ϕht may be thought of as an instrument of central bank credit policy.
Assuming that banks investing regions are constrained under a symmetric frictions in wholesale and retail financial markets (ω = 0), lending facilities expand the total amount of assets intermediated in the market. Combining equations (31), (43) and (44), yields
Qi
tSi t =
1
1 − ϕi t φi tNi t (45)
15Other potential costs include the potential for politicization of credit flows. We abstract from this consideration, though we think it provides another important reason for why credit policies are more appropriate in crises than normal times.
26
The effect on asset demand for non-investing regions depends on whether or not banks in these regions are balance sheet constrained (i.e., on whether the excess return μnt
> 0 is positive). If they are, then lending facilities affect asset demands similarly to the way they do in investing regions, only the superscript i is replaced by n in (45). One other hand, if banks in non-investing regions are not constrained (i.e., μnt
= 0), then central bank credit merely displaces private credit, leaving total asset demand in the sector unaffected. Let Sn∗ t be total asset demand consistent with a zero excess return on assets on non-investing islands in equilibrium. Then
Qnt
Sn∗ t = Qnt
Sn
pt + ϕnt
Qnt
Sn∗ t , iff μnt
= 0. (46)
Here an increase in central credit provision crowds out private intermediation one for one. Only when private intermediaries are financially constrained does central bank intermediation expand the overall supply of credit.
3.2 Liquidity Facilities (Discount Window Lending)
With liquidity facilities, the central bank uses the discount window to lend funds to banks that in turn lend them out to nonfinancial borrowers. Typically, liquidity facilitates are used to offset disruption of inter-bank markets.
Such was the case in the current crisis.
Another distinguishing feature of liquidity facilities is that central bank lending is typically done at a penalty rate. This prescription dates back to
Bagehot (1873). The idea is that during a liquidity crises, it is the breakdown of markets for short term funds that is responsible for many borrowers having limited credit access, as opposed to lack of credit worthiness of individual borrowers. Because excess returns for these borrowers are abnormally high during the crisis, they are more than willing to borrow at penalty rates.
Offering the funds at a penalty rate, further, discourages inefficient use of central bank credit by the private sector.
In this section we use our model to illustrate how discount window lending may facilitate the flow of inter-bank lending during a crisis. To do so, we restrict attention to the case (ω = 0), where borrowers in the inter-bank market face symmetric constraints on obtaining funds in both the wholesale and retail markets. In this instance, banks with surplus funds face the same risk as depositors that borrowing banks may divert a fraction of gross assets for their own purposes.
27
We suppose the central bank offers discount window credit at the noncontingent interest rate Rmt+1 to banks who borrow on the inter-bankmarket.
It funds this activity by issuing government debt that is a perfect substitute for household deposits. For discount window lending to expand the supply of funds in the inter-bank market, however, the central bank must have an advantage over private lenders in supplying funds to borrowing banks.
Otherwise discount window lending will simply supplant private inter-bank lending. Here we suppose that the central bank is better able to enforce repayment than private lenders. In particular for any unit of discount window credit supplied, a borrowing bank can divert only the fraction θ(1 − ωg) of assets, with 0 < ωg ≤ 1. Recall that for credit supplied by a private lender, the borrowing bank can divert the fraction θ > θ(1 − ωg). Here the idea is that the government may have additional means at its disposal (IRS records, access to credit records, legal punishments, etc.) to retrieve assets. We suppose, however, that after a certain level of discount window lending, the central bank’s ability to retrieve assets more efficiently than the private sector disappears. Think of this as reflecting some capacity constraint on the central bank’s ability to efficiently process discounted window loans secured by private credit.16
Let mht be discount window borrowing for a bank of type h. The flow of funds constraint is now,
Qht
sht
= nht
+ bht
+ mht
+ dt. (47) with mht
≥ 0. Let Vt(sht
, bht
, mht
, dt) be the value of a bank who holds assets and liabilities (sht
, bht
, mht
, dt) at the end of period t. For the bank to continue operating this value must not fall below the gain from diverting assets, taking into account the central bank’s advantage in retrieving assets. Accordingly, in this case the incentive constraint is given by:
Vt(sht
, bht
, mht
, dt) ≥ θ
¡
Qht sht − ωgmht
¢
. (48)
16Alternatively, if we had asset heterogeneity this constraint might reflect a limitation on the kind of bank assets that might be suitable collateral for discount window lending.
For example, information-intensive commercial and industrial loans are not good collateral for discount window loans since they require expertise for monitoring and evaluation. On the other hand, agency debt or high grade securitized mortgage might be suitable, but banks might only have a limited fraction in their portfolios.
28
We defer the details of the bank’s decision problem for this case to the
Appendix. Accordingly, let μmt be the excess cost to a bank of discount window credit relative to deposits μmt = Et h0 Λt,t+1Ωh0 t+1(Rmt+1 − Rt+1). (49)
Next note that, because we are restricting attention to the case of symmetric frictions in private interbank and retail financial markets (ω = 0), the interbank rate equals the deposit rate: Rbt+1 = Rt+1. Then from the first order conditions we learn that in order for both private interbank borrowing and discount window to be actively used, we need: μmt = ωgμi t (50) where μi t is the excess value of assets on investing islands, given by equation
(30).
According to equation (50), to make borrowers indifferent between discount window and private credit at the margin, the central bank should set
Rmt+1 tomake the excess cost of discount window credit equal to the fraction ωg of the excess value of assets. Intuitively, because a unit of discount window credit permits a borrowing bank to expand assets by a greater amount than a unit private interbank credit, it is willing to pay a higher cost for this form of credit. In this way, the model generates an endogenously determined penalty rate for discount window lending.
Let Mt be the total supply of discount window credit offered to the market.
Then one can show that the market demand for assets by investing banks is given by
Qi
tSi pt = φi tNi t + ωgMt. (51)
Thus, so long as ωg > 0, discount window lending can expand the total level of assets intermediated by banks on investing regions.
Because the excess value of bank assets on non-investing islands is less than that on investing islands, i.e., μnt
< μi
t., banks on non-investing islands will not borrow from the discount window. Given that the discount rate is set to satisfy equation (50) discount window lending will be too expensive for banks who do not have new investment to finance.
The question then arises as to why the central bank does not simply expand discount lending to drive excess values of assets to zero. As we noted earlier, it reasonable to suppose that there are capacity constraints on
29
the central bank’s ability to adequately monitor bank’s asset management activities, (even though we do not formally incorporate it into our model here). With a capacity constraint on discount window lending (secured by private credit) the central bank may need to use other tools such as direct lending or equity injections during crisis periods of high excess returns. While liquidity facilities may be useful for improving the flow of funds in inter-bank markets, in a major crisis other kinds of interventions may be necessary to stabilize financial markets.

Similar Documents

Premium Essay

Wwww

...Financial intermediation 陈鸣杰 F1003 201048950504 CONTENTS The process of financial intermediation………………………………..2 The deposit-taking financial intermediaries…………………………..4 The non-deposit-taking financial intermediaries………………………6 The Impact of non-depository financial institutions…………………..9 How to facilitate the transfer of liquidity from surplus to deficit units in the economy………………….. ………………….. …………………..10 The process of financial intermediation In a market economy, the savings - investment into the process is carried out around the financial intermediaries to financial intermediation of savings into investment in the basic process of institutional arrangements. The basis of the existence of financial intermediaries such as the field has been the concern of financial. Financial intermediaries to discuss the issue, we must first make the meaning of the definition of financial intermediaries. Financial intermediation by the banking financial intermediaries and the general non-bank financial intermediaries form, specifically including commercial banks, securities firms, insurance companies, and information consulting services and other intermediary institutions, finance is the core of modern economy. Books related to financial intermediation. In the modern market economy, the financial activities closely with the economy, the scope of financial activities, quality directly affects the performance of economic activity...

Words: 2554 - Pages: 11

Premium Essay

Term Paper

...List of Research Papers Related to Financial System Date | Title | Jun. 19, 2014 | Portfolio Rebalancing Following the Bank of Japan's Government Bond Purchases: A Fact Finding Analysis Using the Flow of Funds Accounts Statistics  | Jun. 19, 2014 | Portfolio Rebalancing Following the Bank of Japan's Government Bond Purchases: Empirical Analysis Using Data on Bank Loans and Investment Flows  | Apr. 23, 2014 | Financial System Report (April 2014)  | Apr. 23, 2014 | New Financial Activity Indexes: Early Warning System for Financial Imbalances in Japan  | Mar. 31, 2014 | Survey on Core Deposit Modeling in Japan: Toward Enhancing Asset Liability Management  | Feb.  7, 2014 | Estimation of Firms' Default Rates in terms of Intangible Assets  | Jan. 17, 2014 | Benchmarking of Unconditional VaR and ES Calculation Methods: A Comparative Simulation Analysis with Truncated Stable Distribution  | Oct. 23, 2013 | Financial System Report (October 2013)  | Sep. 24, 2013 | Risk Aggregation by a Copula with a Stressed Condition  | Jul. 26, 2013 | Financial Results of Japan's Banks for Fiscal 2012  | May   2, 2013 | Identifying Conventional and Unconventional Monetary Policy Shocks: A Latent Threshold Approach  | Apr. 17, 2013 | Financial System Report (April 2013)  | Mar. 25, 2013 | Banks' Stockholdings and the Correlation between Bonds and Stocks: A Portfolio Theoretic Approach  | Mar. 19, 2013 | What is the Major Determinant of Credit Flows through Cross-Border Banking...

Words: 713 - Pages: 3

Premium Essay

Islamic Financial System

...CHAPTER ONE INTRODUCTION 1.1. Background: Financial stability and economic growth is the concern of any country that looks for the welfare of its people. Therefore, the banking sector and its role of intermediation between savers and borrowers is the target of regulators in every country to enhance stability, soundness and economic growth. The banking sector is one component of the financial system and its importance stems from the importance of the financial system as a whole. 1.2. 1.2 Financial Systems The financial system is defined by Gurusamy (2008) as a system that aims at establishing and providing a regular, smooth, efficient and cost effective linkage between depositors and investors (ISBN 0-07-015335-3). Researchers such as Levine...

Words: 1539 - Pages: 7

Premium Essay

Economics

...trilemma How can emerging economies protect themselves from the rich world’s monetary policy? Source: The Economist Aug 31st 2013 SINCE the beginning of May the Indian rupee has plunged by 23% against the dollar. The Turkish lira fell by 15% in that time, and the Indonesian rupiah by 16%. Headlines warn of a replay of the Asian crisis of the late 1990s. Complaints from emerging-market officials that rich-world monetary experiments are to blame for the trouble look like sour grapes. But new research presented to the world’s top central bankers at their recent gathering in Jackson Hole suggests they may have a point. At issue is how the flood (and ebb) of foreign capital affects economies. The traditional rule has been that countries face a “trilemma”: they must choose between free capital flows, a fixed exchange rate and an autonomous (independent) monetary policy. “The impossible trinity” sounds like new-age theology (religious truth) but simply posits (presents) that an economy can choose at most two of these three. An economy open to free movement of capital can keep a fixed exchange rate, for example, only by subjugating monetary-policy goals to its defence—by raising interest rates sharply, say, when capital outflows put downward pressure on the currency. Yet the trilemma also implies that an economy can enjoy both free capital flows and an independent monetary policy, so long as it gives up worrying about its exchange rate. Emerging-market leaders have...

Words: 1498 - Pages: 6

Premium Essay

Corp Finance

...general role of the financial system in a modern economy • The major functions of financial markets and financial intermediaries • What saving is and its uses • How the financial system channels funds from lenders to borrowers • The role of the Federal Reserve and its regulatory and monetary policy responsibilities Lectures Notes I. Economic and financial analysis of an ever-changing system A. Economics is about how society decides what gets produced, how it gets produced and who gets what. B. Microeconomics studies about individual decision making units. Macroeconomics deals with aggregate or total behavior of all households and firms. C. Finance is about how the financial system coordinates the flow of funds from lenders to borrowers and how new funds are created by financial intermediaries in the borrowing process. D. Historically, the financial system has been highly regulated since a smooth functioning, efficient financial system is vital to a healthy economy. C. In recent years, the financial system has been changing due to new ways to raise and use money through financial intermediation, increased globalization, and deregulation. II. Finance in our daily lives A. Money is something generally acceptable and generally used to make payments. Saving is income not spent on consumption. Both households and firms save. Since businesses do not spend on consumption, all of business income except that...

Words: 831 - Pages: 4

Premium Essay

Financial Crisis

...Financial Crises: Theory and Evidence Franklin Allen University of Pennsylvania Ana Babus Cambridge University Elena Carletti European University Institute June 8, 2009 1. Introduction Financial crises have been pervasive phenomena throughout history. Bordo et al. (2001) find that their frequency in recent decades has been double that of the Bretton Woods Period (1945-1971) and the Gold Standard Era (1880-1993), comparable only to the Great Depression. Nevertheless, the financial crisis that started in the summer of 2007 came as a great surprise to most people. What initially was seen as difficulties in the US subprime mortgage market, rapidly escalated and spilled over to financial markets all over the world. The crisis has changed the financial landscape worldwide and its costs are yet to be evaluated. The purpose of this paper is to concisely survey the literature on financial crises. Despite its severity and its ample effects, the current crisis is similar to past crises in many dimensions. In a recent series of papers, Reinhart and Rogoff (2008a, 2008b, 2009) document the effects of banking crises using an extensive data set of high and middle-to-low income countries. They find that systemic banking crises are typically preceded by credit booms and asset price bubbles. This is consistent with Herring and Wachter (2003) who show that many financial crises are the result of bubbles in real estate markets. In addition, Reinhart and Rogoff find...

Words: 11555 - Pages: 47

Free Essay

The Poor and Their Money

...i The Poor and Their Money An essay about financial services for poor people Stuart Rutherford Institute for Development Policy and Management University of Manchester January 1999 The Department for International Development will be publishing this work in New Delhi during 1999. For further information contact Sukhwinder Arora at the Department for International Development, New Delhi, India. ii PREFACE Over the last 15 years initiatives to provide financial services to poor people (the ‘microfinance industry’) have come on by leaps and bounds in terms of size and reputation. Despite this, the industry is still only in its adolescence and our understanding of why and how poor and very poor people use microfinancial services ( and why many choose not to use the services that are available) remains partial at best. This essay takes the reader on a ‘voyage of discovery’ that seeks to both deepen her/his understanding and encourage her/him to apply that knowledge to the practice of microfinance. The voyage that Stuart Rutherford offers is a unique one based upon years of careful and detailed personal research. It does not take a deductive approach that develops a theoretical model of the financial behaviour of poor people. Nor does it follow the ‘case study plus best practice’ approach that has been favoured by many practitioners when they write of microfinance. Instead, it adopts an inductive approach - based on thousands of conversations and meetings with...

Words: 42654 - Pages: 171

Premium Essay

Research Proposal

...UNIVERSITY OF NAIROBI INSTITUTE OF DIPLOMACY AND INTERNATIONAL STUDIES Implications of Global International Monetary Policy Decision on Economic Systems in East Africa: A Case Study of Kenya NAME: LILLIAN WACHIRA REG NO: R50/63875/2010 Supervisor: Dr. Gerrishon Ikiara A Research Proposal submitted in partial fulfillment of the Degree of Masters of Arts in International Studies (MA IS) DECLARATION I declare that this research proposal is my original work and has not been presented for a degree in any other university. NAME: LILLIAN WACHIRA REG. NO: R50/63875/2010 Sign: ………………………………… Date: ……………………… This research proposal has been submitted for examination with my approval as university supervisor SUPERVISOR: Sign: ……………………………… Date: …………………………. DEDICATION I dedicate my project to my lovely mother Beatrice, my brothers Edwin and Eric whose prayers words of encouragement and push for tenacity ring in my ears. ACKNOWLEDGEMENT I would like to express my sincere gratitude to my supervisor Dr. Gerrsihon Ikiara for the continuous support and guidance while carrying out my project, for his patience, motivation and immense knowledge. I would also like to thank the participants in my survey, who have willingly shared their precious time during the process of interviewing. I...

Words: 24867 - Pages: 100

Free Essay

Good to Know

...Journal of Banking & Finance 22 (1998) 613±673 The economics of small business ®nance: The roles of private equity and debt markets in the ®nancial growth cycle Allen N. Berger a a,b,* , Gregory F. Udell c Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Washington, DC 20551, USA b Wharton Financial Institutions Center, Philadelphia, PA 19104, USA c Kelley School of Business, Indiana University, Bloomington, IN 47405, USA Abstract This article examines the economics of ®nancing small business in private equity and debt markets. Firms are viewed through a ®nancial growth cycle paradigm in which different capital structures are optimal at di€erent points in the cycle. We show the sources of small business ®nance, and how capital structure varies with ®rm size and age. The interconnectedness of small ®rm ®nance is discussed along with the impact of the macroeconomic environment. We also analyze a number of research and policy issues, review the literature, and suggest topics for future research. Ó 1998 Published by Elsevier Science B.V. All rights reserved. JEL classi®cation: G21; G28; G34; E58; L89 Keywords: Venture capital; Small business lending; Bank; Mergers 1. Introduction The role of the entrepreneurial enterprise as an engine of economic growth has garnered considerable public attention in the 1990s. Much of this focus * Corresponding author. Tel.: 1 202 452 2903; fax: 1 202 452 5295; e-mail: aberger@frb.gov. 0378-4266/98/$19.00 Ó 1998 Published...

Words: 30009 - Pages: 121

Free Essay

The Growth of Finance

...The Growth of Modern Finance* Robin Greenwood Harvard Business School and NBER David Scharfstein Harvard Business School and NBER July 2012 Abstract The U.S. financial services industry grew from 4.9% of GDP in 1980 to 7.9% of GDP in 2007. A sizeable portion of the growth can be explained by rising asset management fees, which in turn were driven by increases in the valuation of tradable assets, particularly equity. Another important factor was growth in fees associated with an expansion in household credit, particularly fees associated with residential mortgages. This expansion was itself fueled by the development of non-bank credit intermediation (or “shadow banking”). We offer a preliminary assessment of whether the growth of active asset management, household credit, and shadow banking – the main areas of growth in the financial sector – has been socially beneficial. * We thank Toomas Laarits for excellent research assistance. We are grateful to Lewis Alexander, John Campbell, Darrell Duffie, Sam Hanson, Anil Kashyap, Morgan Ricks, Andrei Shleifer, Jeremy Stein, Adi Sunderam, Paul Tucker, Bob Turley, Luigi Zingales, and especially David Autor and Tim Taylor for very helpful suggestions. We also thank Erin Ludlow, James Green, Rodger Smith, Karen Lanzetta, Justyna Podziemka, Covie Edwards-Pitt for their help and advice on financial services data, and the Securities Industry and Financial Markets Association (SIFMA) and Greenwich Associates for providing...

Words: 15797 - Pages: 64

Premium Essay

Avimnvygvhvbjkbvkjb

...Commercial Bank Management (CBM) Credits: 3 ------------------------------------------------- ------------------------------------------------- Course Instructor: Prof. D N Panigrahi Objectives of the course: The course inputs are designed to accomplish the following objectives. * To help students to understand the role and functions of Commercial Banks, main strategic issues in retail and corporate banking and the risks faced by the Banking Industry in India. * To familiarise the students with the new Banking Practices and Processes including new banking technologies. * To familiarise the students with the legal and regulatory framework for banks in India. * To equip the students with the tools and techniques used in interpreting and evaluating the performance, profitability, productivity, and efficiency of the Commercial Banks. * To equip the students with the in-depth knowledge of Bank Financial Management Process including Treasury, Investment, Asset Liability Management & Risk Management. * To equip the students with the in-depth knowledge and skills in Credit Analysis & Appraisal Processes relating to the banks’ lending decisions like Working Capital Financing, Term Loan & Project Financing, Domestic & International Trade Finance including Export-Import Finance, BG (LG) & LC, Retail Asset Financing like Home Loans, Car Loans, Educational Loans, Gold Loans, Loans ag. Securities, Personal and Credit Card Loans. * To understand...

Words: 2603 - Pages: 11

Premium Essay

Capitalization and Consolidation

...The sector was characterized by small sized banks with high overheads; low capital base averaging less than $10million; heavy reliance on government patronage and loss making. Nigeria’s banking sector was still characterized by a high degree of fragmentation and low levels of financial intermediation up until 2004. In the light of the foregoing, banks are compelled by the Central Bank of Nigeria to raise their capital base from N2 billion to 25 billion on or before 31st December, 2005. Most banks resorted to mergers and acquisition as a survival strategy, which saw a reduction in the number of banks from 89 to 25. This study contributes to the concept of bank recapitalization by critically examining the impact of bank consolidation on the performance of banks using a sample of randomly selected Nigerian banks. It is the intention of the researcher to give more validity to empirical evidence that have been obtained by previous researchers on the subject matter. Relevance of the study The earliest set of studies evaluates the effects of bank consolidation through mergers and acquisitions comparing pre- and post- merger performance by measuring performance using either accounting or productive efficiency indicators.The results from both indicators have varied and at sometimes been contradictory. This can be explained by performance-influencing variables like size, brand name, diversification and cost reduction, there is still no reconciliation between these indicators. I intend...

Words: 6693 - Pages: 27

Premium Essay

Pdf, Doc Docx

...Lecture 4: Credit risk The nature of banking is strongly related to the management and control of risks. This lecture gives an overview of the main risks to which banks are subject, namely interest rate risk/market risk, liquidity risk and credit risk, as well as broader systemic risks. We then examine economic issues relating to the core of banks’ traditional business, namely onbalance-sheet lending. We focus in particular on the various ways in which banks seek to control the risks arising from their loan books. This discussion includes a brief assessment of issue of credit rationing which is an issue of both microeconomic and macroeconomic significance. Bank risks – an overview What is risk? – danger that a certain unpredictable contingency can occur, which generates randomness in cashflow Risk and uncertainty – risks may be described using probability analysis (business cycle, company failures), while events subject to uncertainty cannot (financial crises, wars etc.) Risk and variability – variability alone may not entail risk as long as known for sure ex ante The nature of qualitative asset transformation- gives rise to risks because of mismatched balance sheet. Main forms of risk Credit risk – risk that party to contract fails to fully discharge terms of contract Interest rate risk – risk deriving from variation of market prices owing to interest rate change Market risk – more general term for risk of market price shifts Liquidity risk – risk asset owner unable to...

Words: 1173 - Pages: 5

Premium Essay

Risk Management Still at Rudimentary Stage in Nigeria’

...Risk Management Still at Rudimentary Stage in Nigeria’ Deputy Governor, Financial System Stability, Central Bank of Nigeria (CBN), Dr. Chiedu K. Moghalu, recently spoke on “Risk-Ability: Risk Management Knowledge and Infrastructure for Nigeria’s Financial Services Industry,” at a Chief Risk Officers’ retreat. Obinna Chima, who was there presents the excerpts: Financial Crisis From the tulip mania in Holland in the mid-1630s to the ultimately disastrous speculative rush for the shares of the Mississipi Company promoted by John Law and his Banque Royale in Paris in the early 1700s, from the South Sea Bubble in London in the same period (to which Sir Isaac Newton lost a princely £20,000) to the great Wall Street Stock Market boom of the 1920s that preceded the Great Crash of 1929 and the Great Depression and on to the global financial crisis of 2008 – 2009, the history of finance over the past 500 years has been marked by frequent booms and busts. Historical evidence suggests, as the famous American economist John Kenneth Galbraith put it, “that the financial memory should be assumed to last, at a maximum, no more than 20 years. This is normally the time it takes for the recollection of one disaster to be erased and for some variant on previous dementia to come forward to capture the financial mind.” If this is so, and we are condemned to cycles of financial implosions that wipe out economic value, is the modern science of risk management doomed? It isn’t. The future...

Words: 1973 - Pages: 8

Free Essay

Bangladesh Economy

...How Capital Markets Enhance Economic Performance and Facilitate Job Creation BY WILLIAM C. DUDLEY US CHIEF ECONOMIST GOLDMAN, SACHS & CO. BY R. GLENN HUBBARD DEAN COLUMBIA BUSINESS SCHOOL NOVEMBER 2004 How Capital Markets Enhance Economic Performance and Facilitate Job Creation BY WILLIAM C. DUDLEY US CHIEF ECONOMIST GOLDMAN, SACHS & CO. BY R. GLENN HUBBARD DEAN COLUMBIA BUSINESS SCHOOL Introduction Our main thesis is that well-developed capital markets generate many economic benefits, including higher productivity growth, greater employment opportunities, and improved macroeconomic stability. To focus on these significant benefits, we examine three issues: (1) the importance of capital markets in facilitating superior economic performance, (2) how the capital markets foster job creation, and (3) the necessary preconditions for the development of well-functioning capital markets. Our analysis focuses on two particular sets of comparisons. First, within the United States, how has macroeconomic performance improved over time as the capital markets have become more dominant? Second, across countries, can one explain the superior macroeconomic performance evident in recent years in countries that have well-developed capital markets such as the UK and the US relative to countries such as Germany and Japan, in which the capital markets are much less developed? We highlight the impact of capital market development on the economic performance of the United States...

Words: 13084 - Pages: 53