Free Essay

Global Financial Crisis and the Eu

In:

Submitted By ssruttala
Words 5853
Pages 24
BUSI2034 Research Project 2015

Due Date: Monday, 4 May 2015, 4pm
Length of Essay: 4000 words excluding tables, figures, reference list, and appendices (if any).
Instructions:
You are required to develop an essay addressing the issues described in the following statement:
‘Geopolitical crises and epidemics haven’t stopped the global economy from expanding by some 3 percent in 2014. However, the Eurozone will remain the world economy’s main problem, with growth in the single-currency bloc expected to be negligible.
Problems in some of the Eurozone’s big economies are worrying analysts. The situation in Italy, for instance, is quite dramatic, with the economy stagnating. In France, high public deficits are a big worry; such a policy could not be continued for much longer. Underperforming fellow Eurozone nations could affect Germany’s own economic growth prospects, since they are the customers for most of Germany’s exports; it is expected that Germany’s gross domestic product will expand by just 1 percent in 2015.
Despite the evident problems in Eurozone, Germany and France are determined to restore a confidence to the Euro.’
Discuss the statement, and use examples to justify your opinion.

1.0 Introduction
The Global Financial Crisis or the ‘great recession’ as it is now known has been widely regarded as the worst global recession since the end of the Great Depression (Drezner, 2014). The events following the collapse of the US housing market and the subsequent financial meltdown has had consequences on a global scale, nowhere is this more evident than in the Eurozone (Allen & Ngai, 2012). The Eurozone, made up of 19 EU member states that have adopted a common currency and monetary policy, have faced increasing levels of public debt, economic stagnation and civil unrest (Ucler et al. 2015). Problems are further compounded by the fact that there is an increasing level of disagreements over the policies and structural reforms to be undertaken.

While it is easy to lay the blame for many of the problems entirely on the GFC, this can be a misleading proposition. Though the GFC and the recession that followed acted as the precursors to the Eurozone crisis, these problems were further exacerbated by the structural bottlenecks and often-contradictory fiscal policies that characterized the various Eurozone nations. This is evidenced by the fact that economic growth for the Eurozone in the year 2015 is estimated by the European commission to be around 1.3% (The Economist, 2015), which though better from previous years, is disappointing when compared to an estimated global growth forecast of 3.0% (World Bank, 2015). This seems especially lacklustre when taking the increasing levels of economic activity in both the UK and US into consideration, where markets have seemingly gained momentum spurred on by healing labour markets and accommodative monetary policy. The fact that the UK and US, both countries that have been significantly affected by the onset of the global recession, have seemingly restored their economic momentum raises the question off, why the Eurozone does not seem to be able to replicate their relative success?

It is within this context that this paper seeks to explore, first the nature of the Eurozone crisis and secondly, the potential solutions for the future. It is postulated that the reason behind the economic stagnation and the fact that the Eurozone seems to have an inability to shake of the lingering affects of the global recession is, at its basic level, a structural problem. The authors will seek to draw from prevalent economic theory and take a holistic perspective in examining the events that precipitated in the crisis, the Eurozone reactions, including the QE programmes and the long-term prospects of the Eurozone. Following which potential solutions shall be identified.

2.0 Context

3.1 Origins of the great recession: Global integration for better or worse
On September 15, 2008, Lehman Brothers, one of the largest investment banks in the world and the fourth largest in the United States filed for chapter 11 bankruptcy, resulting in what has now been called the perfect storm (Kensil & Margraf, 2012). Though the spectacular fall of Lehman Brothers and the subsequent asset relief program which culminated in the bailout of AIG are often cited as the starting of the financial crisis, it is perhaps important to look backwards to the previous decades in order to fully understand just why the financial crisis occurred and why its impact caused a contagion specifically in the Eurozone.
From the years 1971-1973, the Nixon administration effectively dismantled the Bretton Woods agreement that had kept much of the global currency supply in check, essentially changing the nature of currency from the previously accepted gold standard to a de facto regime of free-floating fiat currency (Schwartz, 2000). What followed were decades of competitive devaluations and an unprecedented increase in the supply of currency around the world (refer to Figure 1). This was also an era of significant deregulation and financial integration around the world, combined with increasing amounts of savings from oil-rich countries and developing nations such as China (Lanman, 2007). By the early 2000’s it became evidently clear that there was a massive savings glut in the worlds financial markets (Agudelo, 2007).
The combined factors of massive liquidity and low interest rates especially in the developed world such as the US and Eurozone culminated in increased speculation and artificially inflated prices, especially in the housing sector (Dugger, 2014). The problem was further exacerbated by generous government incentives and deregulation that increased the risk-taking propensities of Banks especially in the areas of sub-prime mortgages, essentially creating a housing bubble (Christiano et al. 2015). However, when the housing bubble started to collapse in late 2007 culminating in the eventual folding of Lehman Brothers in 2008, the markets faced an uncertain environment with investors increasingly looking for safer options such as Gold. The stock market value of Banks collapsed and capital dried up almost overnight, what started off as an insolvency crisis turned into a systemic one (Braude et al. 2012).
Similarly in Europe, banks such as BNP Paribas which had taken significant positions in the US markets suffered considerable losses with flow on effects throughout the EU economy. The increasingly untenable positions of Banks within the Eurozone combined with the fact that there were significant housing bubbles in Spain and France meant that capital flows and credit were drying up quickly (Ucler, 2015). The previous global trends of financial deregulation and integration also meant that EU financial institutions had direct exposure to toxic assets in the United States (Ahmad et al. 2014). This essentially meant that Banks were going to have to increasingly consolidate their balance sheets by de-leveraging, effectively cutting down credit access to the economy at large and constraining economic growth (refer to figure 2). This was further compounded by the limitations of various national governments in taking effective measures imposed by the nature of Eurozone.
Figure 1 (Billion Vault, 2015)

Figure 2 (Weisanthal, 2013)

3.2 Crisis in Europe: The unique case of the Eurozone
According to prevalent economic theory, specifically the Keynesian view, because of the cyclical nature of the economy, government intervention can be used as a way to stimulate the market in the short-run and to smooth out economic fluctuations (Snowden & Vane, 1995). This is precisely the premise of stimulus packages such as TARP in the USA and the Rudd-era stimulus packages in Australia. However, due to the nature and structure of the Eurozone, individual governments can be severely limited in their implementation of such strategies, some of these issues are explored in the following section.
2.2.1 The common currency
The economic rationale for the adoption of the single currency is based on the premise of a neo-liberal economic philosophy, that is, the best way to improve the economy is through the free movement of capital. At a microeconomic level, there is little doubt that the adoption of a common currency area should improve business and benefit member states through increased efficiency in the allocation of resources. However, from a macroeconomic perspective, it can also conversely limit states in their ability to respond to crises as well as significantly increase the risk of contagion (Ricci-Risquete et al. 2015).
In the broadest terms, states have two avenues with which to intervene in the markets, the first one being fiscal and the second being monetary. However the adoption of Euro by the 19 members of the EU that make up the Eurozone meant that monetary policy was now in the hands of a central bank and out of national jurisdiction. Whereas under the previous free-floating currency regime, the markets had the ability to correct such things as trade imbalances, and if they failed to do so, the national bank could intervene through interest rate cuts and increasing currency supply, the adoption of the single currency and the subsequent loss of policy initiative meant that nations were now faced with a scenario of having only two avenues with which to correct macroeconomic imbalances, namely 1) real wages and 2) Price adjustments (Blankenburg et al. 2013). However, in both of these aspects there were divergent trends with certain states incurring ever increasing macroeconomic imbalances (refer to Figure 3 & 4) whilst not inviting the requisite currency devaluations as a result of the single currency. Similarly, whilst labor productivity increased in some states, there tended to be divergence in per unit labor costs, namely between northern and southern states (Rusek, 2012).
This resulted in a scenario whereby a single monetary policy was adopted without taking into consideration the national differentials that existed. Furthermore, asymmetric shocks exogenous to the Eurozone such as the appreciation or devaluation of the Euro can be extremely harmful to certain vulnerable economies as opposed to resilient ones. This was illustrated by the fact that certain countries such as the PI(I)GS (Portugal, Italy, (Ireland) Greece and Spain) were hit harder then others such as Germany (Dellago et al. 2013) during the great recession. According to extant research, the first reason for this scenario is that macroeconomic and financial disequilibrium shakes the confidence of financial markets in the solvency of vulnerable countries. Secondly, microeconomic and systemic inefficiencies that are internal to the country lead to weak competitiveness. This results in a situation whereby countries are at the mercy of markets. This issue is further compounded by the often-contradictory fiscal policies of individual governments, often precipitating in inconsistencies to the monetary policy undertaken by the ECB whose policy impacts are Euro-wide. 2.2.2 Fiscal Policies
This leads us to the controversial topic of EU fiscal policies. In an ideal situation, fiscal and monetary policies are consistent. For example, in times of high inflation, governments tend to cut back on government expenditure and national banks raise interest rates. However, due to the fact that the Eurozone consists of a diverse range of countries at different stages of development and uniquely dissimilar situations on the domestic front, there have at times been inconsistencies. Whilst various components of the Maastricht treaty and subsequent agreements sought to find agreements to this problem by setting general criteria and frameworks within which to implement fiscal policies, the aim being to promote fiscal restraint. They have been for the most part unsuccessful (Papademos, 2003).
The Maastricht treaty was signed with the agreement amongst member nations that they would avoid excessive deficits, with successive EU governments working to curtail inflation as well as lower government spending. However, as the launch of the Euro neared it became clear that there would have to be formal guidelines for countries to follow once the common currency had been adopted, and to this end the stability and growth pact was signed in 1997. The two main outcomes of this pact included an agreement to curtail government debt to within 60% of GDP and the annual budget deficit to within 3% of GDP. Similarly current account surpluses were to be maintained in the long run, in order to ensure that the common monetary policy would not have any adverse effects (Allen & Ngai, 2012). Nevertheless, the nature of the enforcement mechanism ensured that within a short period of time countries were violating the conditions and there was a lack of political will to enforce the regulations. In fact Germany, which for many years had been seen as a proponent of fiscal discipline was one of the first countries to violate the conditions set, followed soon by France. By 2005, there had been enough ‘reform’ of the original regulations so as to let countries run up large deficits (refer to figures 5&6). This was especially true of countries such as Italy and Greece which had been running deficits even prior to the collapse of Lehman Brothers, the main reasons being profligate social spending combined with insufficient tax collection (Chinn et al. 2013). The latter being especially true in the case of Italy, where tax evasion accounts for 18% of GDP and governments are unable to take affective measures in addressing the problem (The economist, 2013; Hallett et al. 2008; Navarro et al. 2012).
This had three broad implications for affected countries in dealing with the Great Recession. They were namely: 1) The high levels of debt accumulated in the preceding decades gave less room for maneuverability in terms of fiscal stimulus. 2) The short-term debt undertaken immediately following the Financial Crisis had the effect of massively increasing debt levels, during a period in which tax revenue was declining. This had the flow on effect of shaking the confidence of financial markets in the solvency of especially vulnerable nations such as Spain, Greece, Italy and Ireland. As a consequence, the risk premiums and interest associated with government bonds increased (refer to figure 7), further constraining individual governments’ ability to service debt. 3) Whilst running budget deficits are common practices for governments looking to stimulate the economy. In the absence of monetary policy initiative, countries are faced with the conflicting ideas of 1) increasing expenditure and 2) servicing debt through taxation and austerity (which has the effect of decreasing demand and limiting economic growth). Conversely, countries such as the US can take monetary actions and limit the effects of excessive debt through the use of seigniorage (i.e. inflation tax). However, in the case of the Eurozone, such policy initiatives are made next to impossible because of the divergent nature and contrast between resilient nations as opposed to vulnerable nations. For example, the ECB cannot lower interest rates and increase currency supply excessively since this would have adverse effects on countries such as Germany which are not faced with the same problems as the rest of the Eurozone (Leen, 2012). This brings us to the question of regional disequilibria.

2.2.3 North vs. South: An asymmetric relationship
Further from the lack of fiscal integration, there was also growing disparity between the various states of the Eurozone, with the emergence of an asymmetric relationship between Northern and Southern Countries. The former having consistently built up current account surpluses in the past, whilst the latter have accumulated long-term current account deficits (De Grauwe et al. 2014). As a result, the Eurozone system was characterized by a bipolar relationship between debtors-creditors.
Since the early 2000s, trade imbalances emerged between Germany on the one hand running a trade surplus and Greece, Italy, Spain and Portugal on the other running up large trade deficits. This resulted in growing difficulties for the Mediterranean countries to find viable routes in order to sustain international competitiveness (Chen et al. 2013). Conversely, Germany was fostering its competitiveness through a strategy of wage less productivity growth, combining strong wage restraints policies and high investments in technological infrastructure, while at the same time curtailing social spending. This resulted in a scenario where domestic demand was supressed and private consumption as a percentage of GDP declined drastically, being substituted by intra-EU net exports (Tylford, 2015). In fact by 2014, Germany’s current account surplus hit a record of 7.5% of GDP, exceeding the limits prescribed by the European excessive imbalances procedure (Blankenburg et al. 2013).
Political Will
Though the Eurozone crisis is often seen as primarily an economic one, the political side of it cannot be underestimated, especially if a long-term solution is to be found. This is especially worrisome given the seeming failure of European Institutions in fostering accountability and gaining legitimacy amongst EU citizens. In May 2014 the elections for the EP saw a massive rejection by European electorates against the mainstream parties, a symptom that arose as a consequence of many of the economic crises and the policy actions taken by EU nations. The elections saw as well a rise in support for Euroskeptic parties such as the French National Front led by Marine Le Pen (The Economist, 2014) and the “Five Stars Movement” led by the Italian comedian Beppe Grillo (Faris, 2013). Both leaders aimed to weaken support for the European Union, riding on a wave of dissatisfaction and anger of increasingly impoverished segments of the population.
Moreover, EU institutions have failed in educating citizens towards an understanding of the role of the European Union. This is underlined by the results of a eurobarometer survey in 2004 where 55 per cent of respondents thought that the EU was created just after First World War and 50 per cent did not know that Members of the European Parliament were directly elected by voters. Furthermore, one in four Europeans thought that the biggest item on the EU budget was the cost of officials, meetings and buildings (McCormick, 2011). Finally, the process of decision-making is often criticized for being cumbersome and extremely slow given that the directives and regulations adopted must be accepted by the majority of the member states (Ray, 2007; Black, 2008).
These problems are further exacerbated by the discrepancy in terms of economic growth between northern and southern states, with France and Germany being perceived as ‘dictating policy’. This was especially true during the years following the great recession where Germany, a nation that was significantly less affected by the great recession, became a visible advocate of fiscal austerity measures that significantly affected struggling EU members considerably more than Germany. This essentially caused widespread political divisions between Germany on one side, and southern countries on the other (Blankenburg et al. 2013).
Figure 3 (Dellago et al. 2013, p. 204)

Figure 4 (Dellago et al, 2013, p.204)

Figure 5 (Allen & Ngai, 2012, p.9)

Figure 6 (Allen & Ngai, 2012, p.10)

Figure 7 (Allen & Ngai, 2012. P.12)

3.0 Eurozone Reactions
3.1 Bringing it all together
In the preceding section, the authors mentioned and expanded upon the reasons behind the ‘global recession’ and some of the structural as well as institutional constraints that inhibit governments within the Eurozone from taking the necessary steps to address the crisis. These constraints were broadly categorized as monetary, fiscal, structural and political. It is within this context that we propose two scenarios within which nations in the region can stimulate the economy and sustain long-term growth: 1) Fledgling nations exit the Eurozone and deal with economic problems individually with the added weight of an independent monetary policy. However, such a scenario would be costly and maybe detrimental in the long run. 2) Alternatively, the Eurozone could take an integrated approach to addressing the problems at hand and by doing so essentially find ways of circumventing the constraints previously elaborated on.
The second scenario was the preferred outcome by the Eurozone, notwithstanding the recent political divisions. However, much of the focus of recent efforts has been upon addressing the fiscal/budgetary problems of peripheral countries whilst often disregarding the problems associated with such things as trade imbalances. The economic thinking of Eurozone leaders so far has been that the only solutions to the Union’s problems are fiscal austerity and restoring the confidence of the financial sector. Such a view has had the downside of supressing demand and slowing growth within the short-run, whilst at the same time not addressing many of the structural constraints that could inhibit long-term growth.
3.2 Eurozone initiatives
In April 2010, when the euro crisis became increasingly visible, the Greek government negotiated its debt with the Troika in exchange for austerity measures. The Troika’s approach to the euro crisis up to that point had been dominated by its insistence of a market friendly solution aimed at increasing private sector participation in the renegotiation of the sovereign debt of EMU member states (Blankenburg et al. 2013). Such a policy limited the role played by the ECB to indirect interventions. The result being a series of ad hoc policy and institutional innovations, such as the European Financial Stability Facility (EFSF) that consisted of extending large loan packages to bankrupt states, issuing bonds as well as, other more complex debt instruments on the capital markets (Ucler et al. 2015).
The EFSF loan package had moreover stringent austerity conditions attached to it. It’s initial role was limited to that of a stability mechanism, intervening in primary and secondary bond markets as a rescue facility, before going on to become a permanent institution in the October of 2010 (i.e. European Stability Mechanism). Overall, since its creation the ESM failed to restore confidence in the markets, creating instead recurrent speculative attacks on sovereign debts in crisis-ridden EMU member states. The Accord of 27 October 2011 on Greek sovereign debt achieved only a brief stabilization of the European financial markets. However, market volatility that was attributed to an increasing reliance on uncertain cooperation by private creditors and member governments led in December 2011 to the adoption of LTRO’s (Blankenburg et al. 2013). The LTRO’s were essentially refinancing operations undertaken by the ECB as a way to lend to banks within the Eurozone region at generous rates (i.e. 1%), in order to boost liquidity and expand credit. However the results were disappointing since financial institutions were still wary of lending and economic uncertainty, this signalled the end of an emphasis on market friendly solutions (Schmieding, 2012). Further from this, as of 2010 there was still no evidence that these programmes had increased the capacity of the governments of debtor countries to service their debts, this was attributed to the relatively high risk premiums associated with the debt. It became increasingly clear, that the ECB would have to intervene directly in the market in order to restore financial confidence and put downward pressure on sovereign debt yields (Viterbo, 2015; Popescu, 2013).
On 6 September 2012, Mario Draghi, president for ECB finally announced the introduction of OMTs, recognising the ECB’s role as a lender of last resort to the EMU. The introduction of the OMTs implied the ECB assuming a role as the “banker of governments”, effectively buying up government debt. However, in order for OMTs to be effective in stabilising bond markets two features were necessary: first there was to be no quantitative limit on purchases of sovereign bonds of one to three year maturity. Secondly, to qualify for ECB bond purchases, countries have to adopt a full austerity program and/or a less stringent precautionary program for the recovery from short term temporary shocks (Blankenburg et al. 2013). In essence the OMTs appeared to be the only way with which to stabilize the bond market, assuring investors of the stability of the weaker countries and driving down servicing liabilities, providing much needed relief (Jessop, 2014; Buchheit, 2013).
3.2 Limitations
Though fiscal austerity does have its proponents who cite the fact that government expenditure needs to brought down in order to 1) consolidate and reduce debt pressures and 2) restore confidence. This author postulates that focusing on debt consolidation solely can be detrimental to the economy, since it has the side effects of creating unemployment and reducing demand based economic growth, further increasing government liabilities in the form of social security and decreasing revenue (e.g. less company tax). Furthermore, fiscal irresponsibility is not the sole reason for the crisis, such things as excessive deregulation, trade imbalances and the lack of enforcement mechanisms were also cited in the previous section (Rusek, 2012). Therefore, we propose that whilst financial austerity can put a stop to excessive deficits, it needs to be used moderately and in conjunction with structural reforms in order to promote growth. In the future, there also need to be strict criteria and the will to enforce them, if governments or institutions diverge. A point in case being the fact that the original stability and growth pact, which if it had been enforced, could have potentially avoided the debt crises all together. Although there has been recent momentum in addressing some of these issues, with the signing of the European Fiscal Compact in 2012 (i.e. essentially a newer version of the SGP), the current political dynamics have resulted in a situation where there are still no substantiative enforcement or disciplinary mechanisms created, for example, France within a two year period had already violated several of the criteria set (Alderman, 2014).
It is with the above conditions in mind that the authors propose the following solution:
In order to boost economic growth to similar levels such as the US and UK, it seems urgent that the structural imbalances that undermine the proper functioning of the Euro project be corrected. One possible way forward consists of a radical shift in the domestic economic policies of surplus countries toward measures aimed putting downward pressure on current account surpluses. Such policies could take the form of either direct transfers to southern countries or targeted increases in imports from southern countries. Alternatively, stimulus could also be implemented in order to boost domestic demand.
The most evident case is constituted by Germany, the economic heart of the Eurozone, whose rebalancing could result in major changes and relief for the European economy. In fact, under such a scenario, not only would debtor countries be able to service their debt more easily, there would also be improved investment prospects, hence reactivating the dynamics of demand and supply. Germany could also benefit from the increase in private consumption, in the form of positive effects for domestic business. Similarly, this kind of demand based economic interventions could kick-start inflation in northern countries, making it easier for the ECB to adjust the interest rates accordingly, which would further reduce pressure on debtor countries by increasing domestic investment, as well as reduce debt liabilities.
Similarly, the nature of the political dynamics and demand-side economics also mean that policy initiatives need to be undertaken in order to give greater breathing space for countries in terms of austerity. For example, the OMT’s not only helped give much needed relief to governments within the Eurozone but also restored confidence in the Euro (Lin et al. 2015). A related concept could be increased investments in infrastructure through public-private partnerships, increased investments in education and other strategic sectors; this could reduce unemployment in the long run, boost economic growth and increase competitiveness. However, this would require EU-wide coordination to ensure a equitable and efficient distribution, helped by strong fiscal integration and enforcement mechanisms, so as to ensure that the problems that caused the crisis in the first place do not arise again. 4.0 An epilogue of sorts & Conclusion
Notwithstanding the political divisions, leaders within the Eurozone, especially Germany and France seem determined to restore confidence in the Euro. It must be remembered, first and foremost that the economic and political basis behind the Eurozone project still remains upon solid foundations. Previously, this author mentioned the microeconomic rationale behind the adoption of a single currency and indeed trends in the Intra-EU trade indicate that the adoption of a single currency has been beneficial (figure 4).
Apart from this, it is perhaps pertinent to remember that the adoption of a single currency is part of an overall drive toward greater integration and as such, the failure of the Euro has the potential to undermine and even reverse some of the major political achievements within the broader EU context. Ironically, it is Germany’s export oriented economy and consistent current account surpluses (which this author alluded to previously as one of the structural problems) that provide its government with the most incentive to ensure a stable euro. A break-up of the Euro would see a significant appreciation of its own currency in comparison to the rest of the Eurozone economies, thus hurting its exports in the long run, not to mention its creditor status. Similarly, the repercussions for states such as France with their large public debts would also be drastic, albeit for a different reason. Were they to leave the Eurozone, they would be faced with devaluations in their currencies which, given their debtor status would exaggerate the problem.
It therefore follows that it is in the mutual interest of all parties to ensure a strong Euro into the future, not to mention the long-term costs associated with reverting to a single currency such as, decreased cross-border trade, labor mobility and the increased uncertainty involved with volatile national currencies. However, ensuring growth into the future does involve greater consensus amongst EU leaders in order to address some of the structural and underlying problems aforementioned. Nonetheless, in this authors’ opinion, the initiatives undertaken so far, notwithstanding their significant limitations do show an intrinsic desire and will to undertake policy initiatives.

References:
Alderman, L. “France Produces A ‘No Austerity’ Budget, Defying E.U. Rules'”, Nytimes.com. N.p., 2014. Web. 3 May 2015.

Agudelo, D.A. 2007, “Three essays on information and liquidity in international markets”, Indiana University.

Ahmad, W., Bhanumurthy, N.R. & Sehgal, S. 2014, "The Eurozone crisis and its contagion effects on the European stock markets", Studies in Economics and Finance, vol. 31, no. 3, pp. 325.

Allen, F. & Ngai, V. 2012, "In What Form Will the Eurozone Emerge from the Crisis?", Journal of Applied Finance, vol. 22, no. 2, pp. 6-19.

Banerjee, J. 2012, “In What form Will the Eurozone Emerge from the Crisis?”, Journal of Applied Finance, Vol. 6, no.22, pp. 6-19.
Blankenburg, S., King, L., Konzelmann, S. & Wilkinson, F. 2013, "Prospects for the eurozone", Cambridge journal of economics, vol. 37, no. 3, pp. 463-477.
Bullion Vault,. 'Gold Price Rally 'Does Not Necessarily Need Lower Dollar'', Bullionvault.com. N.p., 2015. Web. 2 May 2015.
Black, J. 2008, "Euroskepticism: Pathology or Reason?", Orbis, vol. 52, no. 3, pp. 480-493.
Braude, J., Eckstein, Z., Fischer, S. & Flug, K. 2012, Great Recession, MIT Press.
Buchheit, L.C. 2013, "The Eurozone debt crisis: the options now", Capital Markets Law Journal, vol. 8, no. 1, pp. 54-61.
Chen, R., Milesi‐Ferretti, G.M. & Tressel, T. 2013, "External imbalances in the eurozone", Economic Policy, vol. 28, no. 73, pp. 101-142.
Chinn, Menzie D. 2012, “The Eurozone in Crisis: Origins and Prospects”, La Follete School of Public Affairs, no. 001, pp. 2-11.
Christiano, L.J., Eichenbaum, M.S. & Trabandt, M. 2015, "Understanding the Great Recession", American Economic Journal.Macroeconomics, vol. 7, no. 1, pp. 110-167.

Dallago, B. 2013, "Financial and real crisis in the Eurozone and vulnerable economies", The European Journal of Comparative Economics, vol. 10, no. 3, pp. 195-215.
De Grauwe, P. & Ji, Y. 2014, "The Future of the Eurozone", The Manchester School, vol. 82, no. S1, pp. 15-34.
Drezner, D.W. 2014, "The System Worked: Global Economic Governance during the Great Recession", World Politics, vol. 66, no. 1, pp. 123-164.

Dugger, W.M. & Peach, J.T. 2013, "Abundance Denied: Consequences of the Great Recession", Journal of Economic Issues, vol. 47, no. 2, pp. 351-357.
Faris, S. 2013, Beppe Grillo, Bloomberg L.P.
Hallett, A.H., Neck, R. & Richter, C. 2008, "Policy issues in the Eurozone: cyclic convergence and fiscal sustainability", International Economics and Economic Policy, vol. 5, no. 1, pp. 1-4.
Jessop, B. 2014, "Repoliticising depoliticisation: theoretical preliminaries on some responses to the American fiscal and Eurozone debt crises", Policy & Politics, vol. 42, no. 2, pp. 207-223.
Kensil, S. & Margraf, K. 2012, "The Advantage of Failing First: Bear Stearns v. Lehman Brothers", Journal of Applied Finance,vol. 22, no. 2, pp. 60-76.
Leen, A.R. 2012, "Seigniorage: A True European Tax", EC Tax Review, vol. 21, no. 6, pp. 331.
Lin, C., Lin, S. & Wu, A. 2015, "Foreign exchange option pricing in the currency cycle with jump risks", Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting, vol. 44, no. 4, pp. 755-789.
Marine Le Pen's triumph: French politics 2014, The Economist Newspaper NA, Inc, London.
McCormick, J., Understanding the European Union (New York: Palgrave MacMillan, 2011), pp. 132-140
Navarro, V. 2012, "The Crisis and Fiscal Policies in the Peripheral Countries of the Eurozone", International Journal of Health Services, vol. 42, no. 1, pp. 1-7.
Papademos, L.D. 2003, "The stability and growth pact: an asset rather than a liability", CES info forum, vol. 4, no. 2, pp. 73-77.
Popescu, G.H. 2013, "Macroeconomic Policies in the European Union", Economics, Management and Financial Markets, vol. 8, no. 2, pp. 185.
Ray, L. 2007, "Mainstream Euroskepticism: Trend or Oxymoron?", Acta Politica, vol. 42, no. 2-3, pp. 153-172.
Ricci-Risquete, A. & Ramajo-Hernández, J. 2015, "Macroeconomic effects of fiscal policy in the European Union: a GVAR model", Empirical Economics, vol. 48, no. 4, pp. 1587-1617.
Rusek, A. 2012, "Eurozone Crisis and Its Solutions: Some Thoughts about Parallel Currency Regime", International Business Research, vol. 5, no. 10, pp. 11-18.

Lanman, B.N. 2007, 'Saving glut' keeping rates low, Bernanke says, Salt Lake City, Utah.
Schmieding, H. 2012, "Tough love: the true nature of the eurozone crisis", Business economics, vol. 47, no. 3, pp. 177-189.
Schwartz, A.J. 2000, "Do we need a new Bretton Woods?", Cato Journal, vol. 20, no. 1, pp. 21-25.

Snowdon, B. & Vane, H. 1995, "New-Keynesian economics today: The empire strikes back", American Economist, vol. 39, no. 1, pp. 48.

The Economist,. 'Taking Europe’S Pulse'. The Economist. N.p., 2015. Web. 2 May 2015.

The Economist. ‘Big Government meets big data’. The Economist, 8 January 2013.

Tylford, S. 2015, “German rebalancing: Waiting for Godot?”, Centre for European Reform, no.98, pp. 2-10

Ucler, G. & Kirmizioglu, H. 2015, "The Reasons of Eurozone Sovereign Debt Crisis and an Empirical Analysis over Permanency of the Crisis", International Journal of Economics and Financial Issues, vol. 5, no. 1, pp. 86-96.
Viterbo, A. 2015, "Supranational creditors: a threat to the equal status of bondholders?", Capital Markets Law Journal, vol. 10, no. 2, pp. 193-211.
Weisenthal, Joe. 'CHART: Here's The Massive Deleveraging Of European Banks'.Business Insider Australia. N.p., 2013. Web. 2 May 2015.

Wolf, H. 2012, "Eurozone entry criteria after the crisis", International economics and economic policy, vol. 9, no. 1, pp. 1-6.

World Bank,. 'Global Economic Prospects'. Worldbank.org. N.p., 2015. Web. 2 May 2015.

Similar Documents

Premium Essay

International Marketing

...in order to satisfy the needs of customers and the objectives of the organization. Different Terms:  Multidomestic marketing: adapting product and marketing programs to each foreign market independently.  Global marketing: marketing activities in multiple country markets are coordinated and integrated.  Foreign marketing: loosely refers to marketing a product in a market outside the home market. International Marketing Environments Global Economic Environment Cultural Environment International Marketing Global Competitive Environment Political/Regulatory Environment Systems Global Systems Global Financial Systems International Monetary Systems and Foreign Exchange Market Global/regional Trading Systems (WTO, EU, NAFTA, ASEAN,...) Importance of International Marketing • • • • World trade has risen from $2 trillion to $18 trillion in last three decades. International trade grows twice as fast as domestic trade. Global marketing is a “must” for firms to achieve sustained growth. Marketing success will be defined on a global scale. Domestic and International Trade Growth Percentage of Growth 12% 10% 8% 6% 4% 2% 0% Year International Trade Domestic Trade Financial Statistics Yearbook Source: International 2011, International Monetary Fund, Washington D. C. Uniqueness of International Marketing More markets  Complex and unfamiliar environments  Greater risk (political...

Words: 1762 - Pages: 8

Premium Essay

Debt Crisis

...SESRIC REPORTS ON GLOBAL FINANCIAL CRISIS – 9 SESRIC REPORTS   ON THE GLOBAL FINANCIAL  CRISIS                                         European Debt Crisis and Impacts on  Developing Countries    STATISTICAL ECONOMIC AND SOCIAL RESEARCH AND  TRAINING CENTRE FOR ISLAMIC COUNTRIES (SESRIC)  1  SESRIC REPORTS ON GLOBAL FINANCIAL CRISIS – 9     2011‐2 Issue    EUROPEAN DEBT CRISIS AND IMPACTS ON DEVELOPING  COUNTRIES    July – December 2011    SESRIC  Reports  on  Global  Financial  Crisis  :  The  financial  crisis  which  started  in  July  2007,  when  investors  lost  their  confidence  in  the  mortgage‐  and  asset‐based  securities  in  the  United  States,  has  deepened  during  2008‐2009  with  a  global  reach  and  affecting  a  wide  range  of  financial  and  economic  activities  and  institutions  in  both  developed  and  developing  countries  around  the  world.  As  the  crisis  deepened, the governments of major developed and developing countries as well as international financial  regulators attempted to take some mitigation actions and coordinate efforts to contain the crisis.  Given  this  state  of  affairs,  the  SESRIC  has  been  preparing  short  reports  since  May  2009  with  the  aim  of  monitoring  the  developments  related  to  the  current  global  financial  crisis  at  the  global,  regional  and national  levels.  In  particular,  these  reports  focus  on  the  impact  of  the  crisis  on  the  economies ...

Words: 3090 - Pages: 13

Premium Essay

Eurozone

...E SSAY COLLECT ION Crisis in the Eurozone Transatlantic Perspectives ESSAY COLLECTION Crisis in the Eurozone Transatlantic Perspectives This publication is a part of CFR’s International Institutions and Global Governance (IIGG) program and has been made possible by the generous support of the Robina Foundation. The Council on Foreign Relations (CFR) is an independent, nonpartisan membership organization, think tank, and publisher dedicated to being a resource for its members, government officials, business executives, journalists, educators and students, civic and religious leaders, and other interested citizens in order to help them better understand the world and the foreign policy choices facing the United States and other countries. Founded in 1921, CFR carries out its mission by maintaining a diverse membership, with special programs to promote interest and develop expertise in the next generation of foreign policy leaders; convening meetings at its headquarters in New York and in Washington, DC, and other cities where senior government officials, members of Congress, global leaders, and prominent thinkers come together with CFR members to discuss and debate major international issues; supporting a Studies Program that fosters independent research, enabling CFR scholars to produce articles, reports, and books and hold roundtables that analyze foreign policy issues and make concrete policy recommendations; publishing Foreign Affairs, the preeminent journal...

Words: 13337 - Pages: 54

Premium Essay

Report of Greece Crisis

...www.capitalvia.com Global Research Limited IMPACT of GREECE White Paper - Impact of Greece Crisis Global Research Limited Introduction Historically, financial crisis tend to lead to sharp economic downturns, low government revenues, widening government deficits, high levels of debt, pushing many governments into defaults. This is called SOVEREGIN DEBT CRISIS. GREECE is currently facing this, it accumulated high levels of debt during the decade before the crisis, when capital markets were highly liquid. As the crisis has unfolded and there was liquidity crunch in world economy, Greece may no longer be able to rol over its maturing debt obligations. Build – Up To The Current Crisis Between 2001-2008, Greece reported budget deficits averaged 5% per year, compared to Eurozone average of 2%. Also, its current account deficits averaged to 9% per year compared to Eurozone average of 1% Greece funded these twin deficits by borrowing in international capital markets, leaving it with chronically high external debt (115% of GDP in 2009) Some of the facts which can be depicted from following charts : www.capitalvia.com 2 White Paper - Impact of Greece Crisis Global Research Limited How Country Debts And Budget Deficits Compare? Projected budget deficit for 2009 Budget deficit figs as % of GDP Debt as % of GDP UK 13% Greece 12.5% Spain 11.25% Ireland 54.3% 68.6% 112.6% 65.8% 10.75% 114.6% 5.3% Italy Germany 3.5% 74.3% Source:...

Words: 2290 - Pages: 10

Premium Essay

Causes of the Sovereign Debt Crisis

...In the immediate aftermath of the financial meltdown in 2008, the global crisis has made an important shift. By then not the private banking sector, from where the financial crisis originally emerged from, but sovereign states face the risk of default. In order to analyse the multifaceted character of the European sovereign debt crisis, this essay focuses on its systemic causes. Contrary to the argument of popular Northern European politicians and journalists that blame the inability of Southern European states to manage deficit spending, the Eurozone crisis is firstly determined by imbalances in the European Monetary Union, and secondly by imbalances in the global political economy. This paper argues that the vast amount of sovereign debt is therefore not the result of weak Southern European nations, but of inherent structural illnesses that ultimately led to the current crisis. This essay is divided into two sections. The first section examines the problems of the design of the European Monetary Union. In regard to the theory of an ‘Optimum Currency Area’ by Robert Mundell, it analyses the extent to which the EMU has failed to meet the criteria of optimised efficiency. In the absence of an adjustment mechanism for unequal development in Euro member states, the dominance of Germany as leading export nation created severe inequalities. The second section then focuses on the role of the global political economy and imbalances that were created in the ‘era of financialisation’ following...

Words: 2451 - Pages: 10

Premium Essay

Euro Crisis

...www.capitalvia.com G lobal Research Limited I MPACT of G REECE White Paper - Impact of Greece Crisis Global Research Limited Introduction Historically, financial crisis tend to lead to sharp economic downturns, low government revenues, widening government deficits, high levels of debt, pushing many governments into defaults. This is called SOVEREGIN DEBT CRISIS. GREECE is currently facing this, it accumulated high levels of debt during the decade before the crisis, when capital markets were highly liquid. As the crisis has unfolded and there was liquidity crunch in world economy, Greece may no longer be able to rol over its maturing debt obligations. Build – Up To The Current Crisis Between 2001-2008, Greece reported budget deficits averaged 5% per year, compared to Eurozone average of 2%. Also, its current account deficits averaged to 9% per year compared to Eurozone average of 1% Greece funded these twin deficits by borrowing in international capital markets, leaving it with chronically high external debt (115% of GDP in 2009) Some of the facts which can be depicted from following charts : www.capitalvia.com 2 White Paper - Impact of Greece Crisis G lobal Research Limited How Country Debts And Budget Deficits Compare? Projected budget deficit for 2009 Budget deficit figs as % of GDP Debt as % of GDP 68.6% UK 13% 112.6% Greece 12.5% 54.3% Spain 11.25% 65.8% Ireland 10.75% 114.6% Italy ...

Words: 2286 - Pages: 10

Premium Essay

Piigs

...Topic: PIIGS (European debt crisis) 吳宇綸D0131292 劉昱顯D0131156 王謙 周雋彥D0125599 Contents 1. Introduction 2. Overview of the European sovereign debt problem 3. Relief measures of the European sovereign debt crisis 4. European debt crisis 5. Conclusion 6. References I. Introduction The PIIGS is a group that composed of five countries that have some commonality in location and economic environments. In this case, PIIGS includes Portugal, Italy, Ireland, Greece and Spain. The countries which be mentioned are all part of European Union members and have been noted for having weak economics and bad situation of financial problems. In 2008, economic crisis came to all over the world, during the worldwide economic crisis, Portugal, Italy, Ireland, Greece and Spain began to come out the grave and serious concern in the European Union refer to the enormous amount of sovereign debt that they were carrying. The problem with the PIIGS is that speculators dropped, compounding their debt issues and the situation might be much more worse. Many European Union members were also unwilling to rescue these struggling nations although when it became very clear that assistance would be needed. The sovereign debt crisis sparked a number of conversations about reforming financial policy in the European Union to prevent similar problems in the future. The members of PIIGS felt displeasure at the negative allusions and some have...

Words: 6354 - Pages: 26

Free Essay

Iceland Crisis

...DEEP FREEZE International Trade Assignment Case Study of Iceland FinancIal Collapse MBA in Marketing&Communication “The most spectacular bankruptcy of the 2008 financial crisis was the collapse of Iceland's financial system. This collapse is especially intriguing as Iceland is not an underdeveloped country!” ---EHMAN BROTHERS Introduction Iceland is an independent Nordic European island country situated at the confluence of the North Atlantic and Arctic Oceans, on the Mid-Atlantic Ridge. Its traditional industries are fishing, processing of fish, aluminum, and strong energy industry. During several years of economic boom, the Icelandic financial system expanded considerably. A nation with a slight population erected a banking system whose total assets were 10 times the size of the country's GDP. Greedy bankers, inexperienced upstairs, corrupt political elite, the deregulation of the financial system, make the banking sector grew faster than any other sector of the Icelandic economy. Following the global financial crisis in 2008, Iceland became the most dramatic economic meltdown. The key problem with the banks essentially owning all the bankrupt highly leveraged business (that were and are essentially good ocean harvesting fishing business) and the downgrade in sovereign debt rating led to capital flight. With the collapse of exchange rate of Krona, 3 main banks (Landsbanki, Kaupthing and Glitnir) are nationalized because of the serious liquidity problems of banks...

Words: 2998 - Pages: 12

Premium Essay

Bop of Greece

...Introduction Historically, financial crises have been followed by a wave of governments defaulting on their debt obligations. Financial crises tend to lead to, or exacerbate, sharp economic downturns, low government revenues, widening government deficits, and high levels of debt, pushing many governments into default. As recovery from the global financial crisis begins, but the global recession endures, some point to the threat of a second wave of the crisis: sovereign debt crises. Greece is currently facing a classic sovereign debt crisis. Greece accumulated high levels of debt during the decade before the crisis, when capital markets were highly liquid. As the crisis has unfolded, and capital markets have become more illiquid, Greece may no longer be able to roll over its maturing debt obligations. Some analysts have discussed the possibility of a Greek default. To avoid such a default, however, the Greek government has introduced a variety of austerity measures and, on April 23, 2010, formally requested financial assistance from the other 15 European Union (EU) member states that use the euro as their national currency (the Euro zone) and the International Monetary Fund (IMF).Greece’s debt crisis has raised a host of questions about the merits of the euro and the prospects for future European integration, with some calling for more integration and others less. Some have also pointed to possible problems associated with a common monetary policy but diverse national fiscal policies...

Words: 6617 - Pages: 27

Premium Essay

Greece in Crisis

...past decade. The country’s economic and political situation has reached crisis level thus propelling it into the global lime-light, dominating headlines in print and electronic media. This essay seeks to explain the crisis and explore the implications for Greece, the European Union and the international political economy, should continued assistance not forthcoming. The source of Creek’s debt crisis is both domestic and international. Domestically, analysts point to high government spending, weak revenue collection, and structural rigidities in the economy. This affected the state’s ability to fund government budget and current account deficits, resulting in profound borrowing. As the situation progressed for the worst, the Creek economy relied heavily on international capital markets, which only aided in making the country extremely vulnerable to any shifts in investor confidence. Access to capital at low interest rates after adopting the euro, and weak enforcement of European Union (EU) rules concerning debt and deficit ceilings facilitated Greece’s accumulating high levels of external debt. In October 2009 investors became jittery due to the actions of the newly elected government in revising the estimate of the government budget deficit for 2009 from 6.7% of gross domestic product (GDP) to 12.7% of GDP (Nelson et al., 2010). A few months later, however, in April 2010, Eurostat, the European Union (EU)’s statistical agency, estimated Greece’s deficit to be even higher, at...

Words: 2351 - Pages: 10

Free Essay

European Financial Crises

...Executive Summary Introduction Eurozone debt crisis, which is also known as European Sovereign debt crisis is an on-going financial crisis that the countries within the Eurozone such as Ireland, Italy, Portugal, Greece and Spain varying a certain degree that faces struggles to repay or refinance their government debt without the assistance of third parties. This has caused much worries faced by the European Unions and hence to the above crisis, thus causing a great impact beyond the borders to the world as a whole. We will look into various roles undertaken by the European Commission (EC), the European Central Bank (ECB) and the International Monetary Fund (IMF) in helping to solve the euro zone Debt Crisis. European Central Bank (ECB) The ECB is one of the seven institutions of the European Union which was listed in the Treaty on European Union where it administers the monetary policy of the 17 EU members’ states where euro zone is consider one of the largest currency areas in the world. Founded in 1998, the central bank is one of the most important in the world with more than 500 billion euros in its reserves. Currently, the bank is based in Frankfurt, Germany and led by Jean-Claude Trichet. The primary function of ECB is basically to implement monetary policy for Euro zone, responsible for the care of foreign reserves of the European System of Central Banks, and to promote and conduct smooth operating of the financial markets and foreign exchange functions. In addition...

Words: 2049 - Pages: 9

Premium Essay

European Crisis and Its Impact on India

...Living beyond our means = European crisis In early 2010 economic activities of the PIGS (a group of 4 nations in Europe namely Portugal, Italy, Greece and Spain) have come under increased scrutiny from the international investment community, with the threat of “Sovereign default” lurking around the corner. Sovereign default refers to a situation when government of particular country is unable to repay its debts. This situation of default payments by governments lead to European crisis. With onslaught of the recession and subsequent introduction of various financial stimulus packages, the government expenditure like public job creation, pensions, social benefits etc ..on various countries took on gargantuan proportions to support these packages. To support these packages government was forced to borrow heavily consequently generating high fiscal deficicts.Most countries had manageable fiscal deficit, the government of PIGS nations mopped up a huge debt bill. The state of affairs in Greece which was epicenter of the sovereign default malaise is shamboic as country was known to live beyond its means. Debt Skelton of PIGS [pic] Role over risk in EURO ZONE It is one element played a role in the crisis is “roll-over risk”. Countries involved are exposed to a fiscal crisis (the “bad equilibrium”) to the extent that they are forced to rely on the market to roll-over their debt. Thus, much depends on the amount...

Words: 1939 - Pages: 8

Premium Essay

Germany - Country Overview

...economic indicators in Germany since 2000 4 2. Germany’s economy in the lead up to the crisis 4 Table 2.1: Economic data since unification of Germany 5 3. Impact of the crisis in Germany 6 Graph 3.1: Exports in German compared to largest global exporters since 2000 7 Graph 3.2: Germany vs US employment data 8 4. Recovery of the German economy 8 5. Conclusion 9 6. References 10 Introduction: Germany at a glance Germany is a major economic and political force within Europe, and a founding member of the European Union (EU) since 1993. With a population of 82.1m and a Gross Domestic Product (GDP) of €2.5b, Germany is the most populous member state of the EU and has the largest national economy in Europe (EU website, 2014). As indicated in Graph 1.1 below, Germany also has the fourth largest economy by real GDP globally (behind the US, China and Japan) and is the third largest exporter in the world. Graph 1.1: World’s largest economies by GDP Source: International Monetary Fund, World Economic Outlook Database, April 2014 Exports make up approximately one third of Germany’s GDP and are driven by a strong industrial base. Germany is a major producer and exporter of automobiles, transport equipment, mining products, electronic and communications equipment, chemicals and pharmaceuticals (IMF, 2014). As a result of this concentration on exports, competitiveness in the global economy is an important factor impacting living standards in Germany. In addition, while...

Words: 3077 - Pages: 13

Premium Essay

Euro Crisis

...EUROPEAN DEBT CRISIS – ORIGIN, CONSEQUENCES AND POTENTIAL SOLUTIONS F RA N TI Š E K N E M E T H Abstract What is the European debt crisis? As the head of the Bank of England referred to it in October 2011, it is “the most serious financial crisis at least since the 1930s, if not ever.”1 In fact, the European debt crisis is the shorthand term for the region’s struggle to pay the debts it has built up in recent decades. Five of the region’s countries – Greece, Portugal, Ireland, Italy, and Spain – have, to varying degrees, failed to generate enough economic growth to make their ability to pay back bondholders the guarantee it’s intended to be. Although these five were seen as being the countries in immediate danger of a possible default, the crisis has far-reaching consequences that extend beyond their borders to the world as a whole. Introduction The global economy has experienced slow growth since the U.S. financial crisis of 2008-2009, which has exposed the unsustainable fiscal policies of countries in Europe and around the globe. Greece, which spent heartily for years and failed to undertake fiscal reforms, was one of the first to feel the pinch of weaker growth. When growth slows, so do tax revenues – making high budget deficits unsustainable. Greece's economy has struggled since the country joined the euro in 2001. In 2004, it admitted its budget deficit was higher than allowed under rules of entry. By 2008 the government had narrowly passed a belt-tightening budget...

Words: 2916 - Pages: 12

Premium Essay

Gbm 489 Greece Eye of the Storm

...country is experiencing during this economic crisis. Greece is the eye of the storm amidst the hurricane of the world. The following pages will provide insight into the storm of Greece’s debt, the assistance of the global organizations, structural reforms, policies, and suggestions in implementing a business plan. Greece s’ Debt Greece’s Debt problems consist of a variety of mistakes and issues including profligate spending, corruption, overpaid positions, tax evasion, and large pensions, etc. One rule when joining the European Union (EU) is an understanding each country is to keep the country’s budget deficit within 3% of GDP. Later, after Greece joined the EU its budget deficit was actually around 13% (Lemco, 2010). Greece tried to handle its debt issues until the EU decided further action needed to be taken. The Eye of the Storm According to the McGraw-Hill Dictionary of American Idioms and Phrasal Verbs, the eye of the storm has two definitions a literal and figurative. The literal definition states the eye of the storm is the area of calm in the center of a tornado, hurricane, or cyclone. The figurative definition states the eye of the storm is a temporary peaceful time amidst more trouble and strife yet to come (Spears, 2007). Either definition provides a great description of why Greece is called the Eye of the Storm. The figurative definition fits Greece better because Greece is temporarily in a peaceful time amidst the global crisis but there is definitely trouble and more...

Words: 1600 - Pages: 7