Free Essay

Icesave

In:

Submitted By gauvin
Words 4719
Pages 19
MCG Consulting Group | Icesave Dispute: Settlement Proposal to Oddný G. Harðardóttir | International Business MGCR 382- 001 Fall 2012 |

|

Contents Executive Summary 3 Description of the Icesave Case 4 Overview of the unsustainable growth and collapse of the Icelandic financial sector in 2008 4 The Collapse of Icesave (Iceland’s Landsbanki) 5 Attempts of agreements and Icelandic referendums 6 Ruling: European Free Trade Association v. Iceland – EFTA Court Case E-16/11 References 8 The proposal from MCG Group (MCG) 9 Economic benefits and arguments 12 Legal aspect of the Icesave dispute 14 Appendix A 17 Bibliography 18

Executive Summary Objective MCG Consulting Group is a consulting firm specialized in banking. MCG’s goal is to provide effective solutions for multifaceted issues by researching all avenues of a problem and ensuring to always have supporting evidence for given proposals. The following paper is an examination of the current Icesave loan conflict followed by a proposal which MCG believes takes all stake holders into consideration. Important Acronyms EEA (European Economic Area), EU (European Union), EFTA (European Free Trade Association), ECJ (European Court of Justice), Research Methods * Review of the history of the crisis including previous agreement attempts and referendums. * Review of financial influences including: * The conservation of Iceland’s natural resources which are its major exports. * Consideration towards Iceland’s credit score and therefore its ability to raise capital in the long run and the short run. * The possibility of economic sanctions from England and The Netherlands which represent a huge part of Icelandic exports. * Consideration towards the current state of the European economy as a whole and the potential impact of having yet another country in dire straits. * Review of the legal aspect of the dispute including: * EEA agreements which Iceland has committed to including deposit guarantee schemes. * The complications due to the cross-border aspect of the banking failure. * Weighing the importance of goodwill and therefore more diplomatic actions as opposed to legal actions. Conclusion Completely avoiding payment of loans would be unacceptable and have too many long term consequences. Iceland should make a compromise by taking a course of action which takes all stake holders into consideration without crippling its own economy. Solution Commit to paying half of the approximately €4 Billion debt. Repay this portion by converting it to non-participative preferred shares in Nyi Landsbanki. These shares will pay dividends based on a predetermined formula and not by earnings of the issuer. After 8 years these shares could be redeemed by the Icelandic government for a maximum of 85% of the remains of the loan. This allows for the creditors to potentially earn more returns should Nyi Landsbanki have performed beyond expectations. In addition both creditor countries will be granted a non-voting seat on the board of directors in a show of good faith and transparency while allowing Iceland to maintain sovereign control. Description of the Icesave Case Overview of the unsustainable growth and collapse of the Icelandic financial sector in 2008 Historically, Iceland’s economy was driven by a collection of small, publicly regulated financial institutions. The three main banks (Landsbanki, Glitnir and Kaupthing) were publicly owned, which yielded the government a strong control over the fixation of interest rates and the risk management of those institutions (Sigurjonsson, 2009). To meet the requirements of the European Economic Area, which Iceland joined in 1994, the Icelandic government launched a broad liberalization of the markets that led to massive privatization and deregulation of the banking system (see Appendix A). Foreign ownership was discouraged, which led to a strong cross-ownership of the banks; this ceded strong control of the banks to a small group of individuals that had no real experience in large scale banking (Sigurjonsson, 2009). When Iceland finally joined the EEA common market, allowing free flow of capital, banks expanded their activities abroad and they expanded exponentially. Risk taking by the inexperienced Icelandic international bankers was neglected by the government and was made very easy by the banks solid credit ratings from the large agencies (Gunnarsson, 2011). From 2001, the business model of the Icelandic banks, because of the relatively small size of the local economy (approx. 320,000 in population), relied on “attracting funding from international markets” (Goddard & Molyneux, 2009). The banks, therefore, leveraged their balance sheet with foreign loans for the next 7 years and their growth became highly unsustainable. When the financial crisis hit, banks’ deficit accounted for roughly 15% of Iceland’s GDP in 2006 and 25% in 2007. Iceland’s inflation reached double digits and the overvalued krona (Iceland’s currency) declined by 35% in 2008 (Sigurjosson, 2011). With inadequate liquid reserves to guarantee their loans, and with the turmoil caused by the credit crisis following the collapse of Lehman Brothers, the Icelandic banks access to credit to generate cash inflows was virtually shut down. The Icelandic government had no choice but to declare an Emergency Act to put the three banks into receivership and acquired 75% of their stakes. The Financial Supervision Authority took charge of liquidating the banks’ assets and three new legal entities were put into place to guarantee normal operations within Iceland. The collapse of the three main banks of Iceland represented 85% of their banking system. According to the IMF, this was the largest banking collapse in history relative to the size of a national economy (Méndez-Pinedo, 2011) with the banks’ foreign loans and assets representing about 10 times the Icelandic GDP (Central Intelligence Agency, 2012). The Collapse of Icesave (Iceland’s Landsbanki) In October 2006, Landsbanki started commercializing an online savings account known as Icesave. Offering high yield savings accounts, which yielded interest rates from 5-6%, it was able to attract around 300,000 customers in the UK with deposits of over £4.8 bn and 125,000 depositors in the Netherlands with €1.7 bn. On 6 October 2008, when the Icelandic bank collapsed and the Emergency Act was declared by the Reykjavik government, “All Icelandic deposits were transferred to the new banks, irrespective of whether they were held by domestic or foreign depositors” (Gunnarsson, 2011). The Icelandic government guaranteed that the deposits that were held in commercial and saving accounts on the domestic land would be covered, but didn’t guarantee the same treatment to depositors in foreign branches (Gunnarson, 2011). As the Icesave accounts in the UK and the Netherlands were not incorporated as subsidiaries but as branches, depositors did not have protection from their respective national governments’ deposit insurance (Goddard & Molyneux, 2009). In response to this measure, Her Majesty’s Treasury froze the assets of those accounts under the Anti-Terrorist Crime and Security Act; the Netherlands took similar but less draconian measures (Méndez-Pinedo, 2011). Little liquidity was recovered, as most of it had already been transferred to Iceland or offshore accounts. Both the UK and the Netherlands reimbursed depositors in their countries and defined it as a loan to Iceland (Gunnarsson, 2011). UK and Dutch claims accounted for a total of EUR 3.91 bn with an interest rate of 5.5%. Considering that the Icelandic population is approximately 320,000, this represents an obligation of EUR 48,000 with interest rates of EUR 2,000 per year per Icelandic family; this is equivalent to 50% of the Icelandic GDP (Méndez-Pinedo, 2011). Attempts of agreements and Icelandic referendums Before resorting to the current attempts at resolution through the courts, the Icelandic, Dutch, and British governments went through several rounds of negotiation. However, in every case, these negotiations amounted to nothing. Either talks broke down or the Icelandic people rejected the agreement through a referendum. Almost immediately after Landsbanki collapsed, the governments entered into negotiations to refund Dutch and British depositors. Early in the process these negotiations appeared to be going well. In fact, four days after Landsbanki was placed into receivership, the Icelandic government issued a press release (PMO, 2008a) stating that, “After constructive deliberations, the Dutch and Icelandic governments have agreed on a solution regarding the Dutch depositors of Landsbanki Icesave savings accounts”, and a joint declaration with the UK (PMO, 2008b) saying that “Significant progress was made on retail depositors of Icesave”. Unfortunately, after such an optimistic start, this round of negotiations broke down rather quickly. The end of these talks marked a significant souring in the Icelandic and Dutch relationship; the Netherlands began to threaten to block the IMF’s loan to Iceland if there was not a resolution over Icesave.
Later on the governments began to negotiate in Brussels, with France mediating, which actually went quite well. In June 2009 the governments came to an agreement, with the UK loaning Iceland £2.2 billion and the Netherlands making a loan of €1.3 billion (Waibel, 2010). In December 2009 the Icelandic Parliament, also known as the Althing, passed a bill which was in line with this deal and which the Dutch and British governments accepted. However, after it went through the Althing, the Icelandic President, Ólafur Ragnar Grímsson, refused to sign the bill without putting it to a referendum. This resoundingly rejected the bill; more than 90% of Icelanders voted against the bill. Later, the three governments came to another agreement over how Iceland could repay the debt. This amended the deal, calling for Iceland to repay the debt over an extended period, starting in 2016. In early 2011, this deal once again passed through the Althing, and Grímsson once again called for a referendum on the deal. Once again, the Icelandic people rejected the deal, this time by a margin of roughly 60-40. With a second consecutive vote against paying back the Dutch and British governments, Icelanders made it clear that they did not support repaying the debt unless there was a clear legal obligation to do so (Sigurdardóttir, 2011). This referendum was the last attempt at negotiations, and resulted in the dispute being taken to the EFTA court.

Ruling: European Free Trade Association v. Iceland – EFTA Court Case E-16/11 References Iceland is part of EEA, meaning that it is a member of an internal market that allows it to trade goods, capital, services, and labor with the EU’s members. Even though Iceland is not an official member of the EU, this agreement obligates them to comply with the EU’s economic laws and regulations (The Norway Mission to the EU, 2009). The EFTA Surveillance Authority makes sure that countries within the EFTA (non-EU members of the EEA) comply with these obligations. In December 2011, this organization opened a case against Iceland in the EFTA court. The Surveillance Authority seeks to prove that Iceland did not hold its obligations by not guaranteeing Dutch and British deposits and it also seeks to force Iceland to pay back the UK and the Netherlands. The first pillar of the EFTA’s case is based around articles 3(1), 4(1), 7(1), and 10(1) of Directive 94/19/EC. These articles deal with a state’s responsibility to guarantee deposits in the case of a bank’s collapse (EFTA Surveillance Authority vs. Iceland, 2011). A Joint Legal Opinion concluded that a state has an obligation to make sure that a deposit-guarantee scheme has adequate means and can pay back creditors. Iceland’s argument is that this does not oblige them to pay back creditors, but rather to simply have a deposit-guarantee scheme in line with the norms in other countries. Furthermore, they argue that even if the obligation to pay back everything did exist, they were precluded from doing so by uncontrollable circumstances, specifically a systemic collapse of the Icelandic economy (Waibel, 2010). The EFTA’s response to this is that it would be illogical if “the greater the shock the less coverage for deposit holders” (EFTA Surveillance Authority, 2012; Davíðsdóttir, 2012). The second pillar of the EFTA’s case is that, even if Iceland did not violate Directive 94/19/EC, it did violate Article 4 EEA (EFTA Surveillance Authority vs. Iceland, 2011). This prohibits discrimination on the basis of nationality by a government. The EFTA suggests that Iceland discriminated by guaranteeing Icelandic deposits, but not those in the UK or the Netherlands. Iceland argues that they didn’t actually discriminate based on nationality. Rather, they made their decision on which deposits to guarantee based on which branch the deposits were held at, which is distinct from nationality (Ministry for Foreign Affairs, 2012).
It is important to note that the decision on this case is not necessarily binding on Iceland; even if the court finds for the EFTA, the decision is not wholly enforceable. However, the outcome of this case will have important ramifications on the dispute regardless. Whichever side wins will have a lot more power in negotiations after the decision. Furthermore, if the court finds for the EFTA, it may provide the “clear and unequivocal” legal obligation that Sigurdardóttir (2011) claims the Icelandic public needs to approve a deal which repays the loan.

The Proposal from MCG Group (MCG) Because of Iceland’s fragile financial position and its unfavorable diplomatic situation vis-à-vis the UK and the Netherlands, it is MCG’s opinion that its government should seek for a settlement outside of court that would satisfy all parties. It is in the best interest of the Icelandic government to make a deal that would have future economic and political benefits for all the stakeholders involved in the dispute. The liquidation 90% of the newly nationalized Nýi Landsbanki bank’s assets as an approach to repay the national loan was proposed during the third round of negotiations of the dispute. MCG does not believe that this is the optimal approach, as it would handicap Iceland’s economic recovery (Méndez-Pinedo, 2011). In addition, the proposition of an annual repayment with interest paid by the Icelandic Government would be a measure that would harm the economic growth of the country. Furthermore, this would require austerity measures of the Icelandic government. In order to avoid future economic drawbacks, the Icelandic Finance minister, should propose to her premier counterparts a feasible, firm and final settlement. For this agreement to be feasible it should include a reduction of Iceland’s debts to a level that is manageable from Iceland’s stand of point, while being acceptable to the UK and the Netherlands. MCG Group’s suggestion is to cut the debt by 50% of the total amount owed, which would reduce Iceland’s liability to approximately EUR 1.95 billion. The new Icelandic debt, would take form of a financial instrument issued to the English and Dutch government. MCG Group recommends that this instrument take the form of non-participative preferred shares in Nyi Landsbanki. The dividends paid on these preferred shares would be “calculated according to a predetermined formula and not be determined by the earnings of the issuer” (OECD, 2012). As for capital repayment of the preferred shares dividends, it would only be allowed if the bank met minimum capital adequacy ratios based on Basel iii Accord requirements (BIS, 2012). The investors (UK and Netherlands) would not participate directly in the distribution of earnings and would not be affected by the dilution of shares. This solution allows the UK and Dutch governments to be in a position to receive residual money while giving them an incentive to help Iceland to recover. Moreover, this would represent a chance for Iceland’s economy to improve and this would be an incentive for Nýi Landsbanki to perform. In addition to show good faith and transparency, an observer of both creditor countries would be granted a spot on the board of directors of the bank for the duration of the deal. This would allow the UK and the Netherlands to keep an eye on the bank’s actions while defending their interest, but they would not be able to vote on the decisions of the board, given the Icelandic bank’s total sovereign control. In case of exceptional returns and assuming that the bank exceeded predetermined capital ratios, the Icelandic government could decide to repay more than what was agreed by the predetermined formula. This would show their goodwill towards creditors. MCG Group firmly thinks this measure should be implemented at the sole discretion of the Icelandic government. At that point, the decision should be based on if they consider that the goodwill of this action would overrule the tradeoff of the returns that could be produced by keeping this capital in their bank. After eight years, these non-participative preferred shares could be redeemed by the Icelandic government for a maximum of 85% of what is left to pay on the loan or would be given back to the Icelandic government, if the total repayment has been achieved or surpassed. This would allow the creditors to hope for more returns from the predefined dividends if Nýi Landsbanki performs beyond expectations. Economic benefits and arguments The right proposal for Iceland is one that takes into consideration the will of the people, the need of the creditors and the interests of the European economy as a whole. Iceland is seeing many unprecedented changes in policy which hint towards a true desire to maintain its image in the European Community and truly show that the country has a desire to make drastic changes to reform its economy. One of the most striking examples of this is a complete rewrite of the Icelandic constitution (Robertsson, 2012). More importantly this new constitution is unique in that it directly includes amendments on economic regulation. This suggests that Iceland is invested in making a real effort to maintain its image on the world stage. By showing that it is willing to make such drastic reforms, investors can be more certain about the country’s future which further solidifies MCG Consulting Group’s proposal to repay debts through preferred shares in Landsbanki. With these changes there are true growth prospects for Iceland and a real possibility that the new lowered debt will be paid in full by the repurchase of shares in time. Furthermore this proposal, in MCG’s opinion, would be acceptable to the population of Iceland and would be seen as a compromise that would not impair Iceland’s sovereignty and economic prospects. One of the more obvious proposals, which were considered for the Icelandic government by MCG Group, was to sell off some of Iceland’s national resources and property to settle its debts as the Greek government has done. Looking at the new constitution it is immediately clear that this would not be possible. A staggering 80% of voters voted to declare “all non-privately owned natural resources as national property” (Robertsson, 2012). Although Iceland was recently upgraded by Fitch from a BB+ rating to BBB- ("Reuters", 2012), essentially bringing it out of the “junk” category, the country still has a long way to go. By repaying at least half of its Icesave debt Iceland makes a compromise, which ensures it does not slip back into a junk bond rating among creditors. This allows for more access to capital in the long run while not crippling its economy in the short term by committing to paying a debt in full, which it cannot afford. By choosing to not pay its debt at all, Iceland also runs the risk of economic sanctions by some of its major trading partners. For example 33.9% of Iceland’s exports are to the Netherlands and another 10.1% are to the United Kingdom (“Exports by countries September”, 2012). By refusing to pay its debts Iceland puts 44% of its exports at risk. Avoiding the other extreme solution of full repayment also affects the country in that it can avoid austerity measures, which could result in major civil unrest. This compromise is not only beneficial for Iceland and its people but also for the two other major stakeholders (UK and Netherlands), and for the EEA as a whole. Considering the devastating ripple effect that Greece and Spain have recently had on the European economy, it is not in EEA’s interest to have any more countries in dire straits economically. For obvious reasons, the UK and the Netherlands would not be in favor of Iceland not taking any responsibility for its debt but at the same time the two countries should be wary of pressing for full repayment, since it would cripple the small Nordic country. By accepting shared responsibility of around 50%, as seen in the proposal, the UK and the Netherlands prove to international investors the strength of the solidarity between member countries of the EEA. Although Iceland by itself does not represent a significant portion of these two major stakeholder’s exports, avoiding more bad headlines in Europe would be a wise political move considering the existing forecasts by investors. For example, Morgan Stanley has already made very grim economic forecasts for Europe including GDP growth of -0.5, -0.6 and -0.5 % for the EEA, the Netherlands and the U.K. respectively in 2012, and a meager 0.0, 0.2, and 1% growth in 2013 (Boesler, 2012). Another major European melt down could make investor forecasts even worse and constrict foreign investments and credits even further. Finally, the proposal also encourages the Icelandic bank to perform and allows for the U.K. and the Netherlands to each assign an observer to the board of directors without voting rights in order to keep a watchful eye on their investments and to avoid that the bank once again takes on irrational risks. Legal aspect of the Icesave dispute When Iceland joined the EEA, it had to comply with the agreement and adopt a law for banks to contribute to the deposit guarantee schemes. However, in the case of Icesave, the directions for state liability in the EU and the EEA law were unclear and ambiguous because of the context of the general failure of the banking system. Since the EEA agreement had never anticipated the possibility of a complete banking failure in one country leaving cross-border depositors unprotected, there is no specific guideline for the role of the state if its deposit guarantee scheme fails to have sufficient funds due to a systematic banking crisis (Méndez-Pinedo, 2011b). The Icesave incident is a cross-border banking failure that has generated for the first time in the internal market a number of victims of this magnitude in other European states. Moreover, no comparative data is available concerning the application of the EU laws in other non-EU countries (Méndez-Pinedo, 2011b) and therefore there is no defined milestone on which the legal judgment can be based on. The European integrated international market’s legal system is currently composed of two legal entities: EFTA and ECJ. While the communication concerning the interpretation of laws and their applications between the two courts is strong, no direct legal procedure was implemented to cope with cross-border judicial disputes occurring between countries in EEA and EU (Méndez-Pinedo, 2011b). The ECJ has no real legal power over the Icelandic state, given that Iceland is not a part of the EU and therefore only responds to the EFTA. Furthermore, there is no explicit law stating that after a systematic banking collapse, a country will have to assure sovereign liability for the financial compensation of depositors in other European countries (Méndez-Pinedo, 2011b). However, Iceland should demonstrate its goodwill to the UK and the Netherlands for diplomatic reasons. Since Iceland is presently recovering from the 2008 crisis and its credit rating is BBB-, its refusal to cooperate would translate into harsher economic repercussions for its people and a longer period of recovery. For these reasons, the Icesave dispute has primarily been approached diplomatically rather than legally. MCG Group’s proposition would be in the best interest for the UK and the Netherlands when taking into consideration the three past bilateral propositions. On three occasions the Icelandic government sought to come to an agreement with the UK and Netherlands regarding the compensation payments made by the later governments to the depositors in their respective countries (Méndez-Pinedo, 2011b). Yet, none of the referendums came to a legal agreement mainly due to the many gray areas in the law and a lack of a precedent similar case on which to base a solution. This lack of legal interpretation certainty has played a major role in the outcome of the referendums, “the Icelandic people will not accept a requirement to cover costs related to deposit insurance guarantees, unless the legal obligation for doing so is clear and unequivocal” (Sigurdardóttir, 2011). Therefore, MCG’s proposition of reducing the debt by 50% and converting it to non-participative preferred shares would be ideal. Furthermore, the proposition is clear and leaves no room for misinterpretation. Finally, the UK and the Netherlands should accept this proposition and their legal actions in the EFTA and the ECJ should be dropped because it might be their only way of recovering a part of what they have lost, and as the EU commissioner, Neelie Kroes, said in one of her speeches, “exceptional circumstances would justify exceptional measures” (Kroes, 2008).

Appendix A

Represents the fusion of the several financial institutions from 1990 to 2007 and the growth of the Icelandic's Bank Assets The Icelandic Bank collapse: challenges to governance and risk management

Author: Throstur Olaf Sigurjonsson
Edition/Format: Article

Bibliography Bank for International Settlment, International regulatory framework for banksbanks (Basel III), http://www.bis.org/bcbs/basel3.htm, 2012 Boesler, . "Morgan Stanley: Here's Our Grim Outlook For Europe's Key Economies." Business Insider 30 Jul 2012, n. pag. Web. 17 Nov. 2012. <http://www.businessinsider.com/morgan-stanley-economic-outlook-europe-2012-7?op=1>. Davíðsdóttir, S. (2012, September 19). Iceland: Icesave (yet again) and the EU deposit guarantee schemes. Retrieved from http://uti.is/index.php?s=icesave "Dutch and Icelandic Understanding on Icesave." Prime Minister's Office. Iceland, 11 Oct. 2008. Web. 17 Nov. 2012. EFTA, EEA. 2012. Free movement of services. Retrieved from website: http://www.efta.int/eea/policy-areas/services.aspx EFTA Surveillance Authority v. Iceland. No. E-16/11. EFTA Court. EFTA Court: Cases. N.p., 15 Dec. 2011. Web. 17 Nov. 2012. Eyvindur G. Gunnarsson, The Icelandic regulatory response to the financial crisis, University of Iceland, 2011 "Fitch raises Iceland to 'BBB-', investment grade." Reuters[Reykjavik] 17 Feb 2012, n. pag. Web. 17 Nov. 2012. <http://www.reuters.com/article/2012/02/17/idUSL2E8DH5XA20120217>. Iceland. Statistics Iceland. Exports by countries September 2012. Reykjavik: , 2012. Web.<http://www.statice.is/?PageID=1261&src=/temp_en/Dialog/varval.asp?ma=UTA02205&ti=Exports by countries September 2012&path=../Database/utanrikisverslun/Utflutningur/&lang=1&units=Fob million ISK>. "Icesave Questions and Answers." Ministry for Foreign Affairs. Iceland, n.d. Web. 17 Nov. 2012. Jóhanna Siguroardóttir.The Icesave Referendum has been Oversimplified 13 Apr. 2010. Web. 17 Nov. 2012. <http://www.guardian.co.uk/commentisfree/2011/apr/13/icesave-referendum-uk-payments/print>. John Goddard, Phil Molyneux and John O.S. Wilson, The financial crises in Europe: evolution, policy responses and lessons for the future, Bangor University/University of St Andrews, 2009 "Joint Declaration." Prime Minister's Office. Iceland, 11 Oct. 2008. Web. 17 Nov. 2012 Kroes, Neelie. 2008. Dealing with the Current Financial Crisis. Talk presented to the Economic and Monetary Affairs Committee, European Parliament, Brussels, 6 October. Méndez-Pinedo, M. E. 2011a. Iceland and the EU: Bitter lessons after the bank collapse and the Icesave dispute. Contemporary Legal and Economics Issues, 3, 9-42. Retrieved from http://search.proquest.com/docview/1032551346?accountid=12339 Méndez-Pinedo, Maria E. 2011b.The Icesave Distpute in the Aftermath of the Icelandic Financial Crisis: Revisiting the Principles of State Liability, Prohibition of State Aid and Non-Discrimination in European Law, European Journal of Risk Regulation, 3, 356-372. Norway Mission to the EU, The EEA Agreement. (2009). European economic area. Retrieved from website: http://www.eu-norway.org/about/eeaforside/ OECD Glossary of statistical terms – Non-participative Preferred shares, http://stats.oecd.org/glossary/detail.asp?ID=6076 (Accessed on 12/11/2012) Robertsson, . "Voters in Iceland back new constitution, more resource control." Reuters [Reykjavik] 21 Oct 2012, Web. <http://www.reuters.com/article/2012/10/21/us-iceland-referendum-idUSBRE89K09C20121021>. Throstur Olaf Sigurjonsson, The Icelandic Bank collapse: challenges to governance and risk management, School of Business of Reykjavik University in Iceland, 2009 Waibel, Michael. “Iceland’s Financial Crisis – Quo Vadis International Law.”ASIL Insight 14.5 (2010).

Similar Documents

Premium Essay

Why Did Icesave Fall?

...writing skills Introduction In October 2008 Iceland was one of the first countries to be seriously hit by the international financial crisis and the consequences were enormous. In Iceland, around 85% of its banking system collapsed in just a few days. One of these banks, a privately owned commercial bank named Landsbanki Íslands had been operating an online savings brand, Icesave, in the UK since 2006 and the Netherlands since 2008. After the bank was taken into receivership in October 2008, more than 400,000 Icesave deposit holders in both countries were unable to access their online accounts. The UK and Dutch authorities announced that all deposits would be guaranteed. According to Directive 94/19/EC deposits were guaranteed up to 20,887 Euros per account.[1] The UK authorities decided to pay out to depositors in full, while the Dutch authorities paid up to 100,000 Euros. It became clear that the Icelandic Deposit Guarantee Fund, established under EU legislation to cover losses in the event of a bank failure, was not in a position to cover the losses incurred by Icesave depositors. Talks therefore started on the aspects of the payout by the UK and the Dutch authorities of the deposit guarantees and whether the Icelandic government was liable to cover the minimum deposit guarantees. On this basis, formal negotiations between Iceland, the UK and the Netherlands started in February and were concluded in June 2009. Under the Agreements reached on 5 June...

Words: 1424 - Pages: 6

Premium Essay

Titel

...constraints on the country, particularly in the fisheries and agrarian sectors, rather than provide benefits * Iceland is already a member of the European Free Trade Association(EFTA) * Iceland must resolve its debt disputes before becoming a member of the EU, according to rules of the EFTA. Meaning, they must pay back GB and the Netherlands IceSave * Icesave, an online subsidiary of Landsbanki bank, collapsed along with its parent and Iceland's other major banks in October 2008, leaving 340,000 British and Dutch citizens out of pocket. * Both Britain and The Netherlands reimbursed their citizens' deposits and have since been seeking repayment from Iceland. The U.K. is owed about 2.3 billion pounds ($3.6 billion) in compensation and The Netherlands euro1.3 billion ($1.7 billion). * Should the taxpayers of Iceland have to pay for the Hubris of a few bankers? * Iceland's failure to settle the dispute has delayed payments from a $4.6 billion loan from the International Monetary Fund. Some legislators believe Britain and the Netherlands could also block Iceland's application to join the European Union until an Icesave deal is signed into law. The Financial Crisis * Under-estimation of the risk of a foreign currency shortage, and a subsequent lack of access to foreign currency, contributed significantly to the financial crisis * In the first week of October 2008, almost the entire Icelandic banking system collapsed, bringing the whole economy down with...

Words: 1890 - Pages: 8

Premium Essay

Stakeholder

...of stakeholders depends on the political, economic and social environment. Internal stakeholders are those from within the business, e.g. managers, employees and shareholders. In the Icelandic banks, the internal stakeholders are managers, staff and employees of the Icelandic bank, and there is no doubt that the owners are the most important stakeholders among all of them. The staff and employees get the paid from company directly and do service for them, that is why they are the internal stakeholders. The external stakeholders are such as suppliers, government, financiers which influence and are influenced by organization but are not its ‘internal part’ (business dictionary). The primary stakeholders are 300,000 British citizens and Icesave housing customers like David Pedrick and his wife, even though they just has a little interest in it,domestic creditors are also a part of external stakeholders. The secondary stakeholders are governments, the media, the pressure groups Liberty and the communities where organizations are nearby or located like Kaupthing Singer& Friendlander which is the subsidiary company. Moreover, the strongest stakeholder is the National Council for Voluntary Organizations. Because it controls many important things and makes more decisions. Part two The purpose of a power/interest matrix is that helps people analyse the relative power and interest of the stakeholders,and divide them into different groups on the base of the level of interest and power...

Words: 893 - Pages: 4

Free Essay

Islandia

...liquidez hacia los bancos Islandeses en el extranjero, cabe señalar que las operaciones de los bancos Islandeses llegaron a 10 veces el PBI de Islandia, al producirse la crisis financiera el gobierno británico intervino los tres bancos operantes en Gran Bretaña ante lo cual el Gobierno Islandés de entonces de conservadores y social demócrata, no tuvieron más remedio de intervenir a los tres grandes bancos y podríamos decir que lo dividió en dos secciones interior y exterior, garantizando los depósitos de los Islandeses en Islandia (interior) pero se negó a cancelar activos de negocios realizados fuera del país, Gran Bretaña y Holanda (exterior) dejando a los ahorradores Británicos y Holandeses que fueron captados por la subsidiaria IceSave que tenía aproximadamente 300.000 clientes británicos y 910 millones de euros invertidos por administraciones locales y entidades públicas del Reino Unido. A Landsbanki le seguieron los otros dos bancos principales, el Kaupthing el Glitnir. Sus principales clientes también estaban en Gran Bretaña y Holanda. Al final los gobiernos de Bretaña y Holanda tuvieron que pagar a sus ahorradores sus depósitos pero exigiendo a Islandia la...

Words: 894 - Pages: 4

Premium Essay

Financial Crisis

...From being one of the poorest nations in Europe to becoming one of the most successful economies in the West, the geographically isolated country of Iceland suffered a lot when its three major banks collapsed in the same week in October 2008. As a consequence of the banking crisis, Iceland entered a deep recession and deep cuts in employment were made and the exchange rate dropped sharply which caused the inflation to soar. The Central Bank of Iceland has been criticized for its monetary policy in the past and how it handled the collapse. The banks had pursued risky expansion strategies – notably borrowing in foreign capital markets to finance the aggressive international expansion of Icelandic investment companies – that made them vulnerable to the deterioration in global financial markets. They had also grown to be too big for the government to rescue. When access to foreign capital eventually closed, the banks failed. Non-financial firms and households were also vulnerable to the deterioration in global financial conditions, having taken on a lot of debt in recent years based on inflated collateral values. In some cases, the debt was foreign-currency denominated, without matching foreign-currency assets or revenues. This essay examines the Iceland Financial Crisis and analyzes the cause, effect, and recovery. Effects The current situation of the economy has severely affected many Icelandic business and citizens in the country. The replacement of Nyi Laandsbanki for the old...

Words: 1402 - Pages: 6

Premium Essay

Iceland Economic Environment Analysis

...ICELAND: EXCHANGE RATES, BoP & the FINANCIAL CRISIS From Riches to Rags and Back Again Since Iceland's financial crash in 2008, the country has been floundering to get back on its feet. The fall this charming and chilly land experienced was nothing short of spectacular – with GDP contracting 12.5% from 2007 to 2010 i and unemployment peaking at 9.4% in 2007 and culminating in a total government collapse on January 27, 2009.ii Altogether, the banks – who owed more than six times the country's GDP in debtiii - defaulted on 85 billion,iv leaving the previously affluent residents angry and afraid. Since that time, the country has taken drastic measures to right the economic situation, and while Iceland is not yet out of danger, the economic future is certainly looking hopeful. How was this tiny country, against all odds, able to crawl back from the brink of disaster? Looking Back First, let's back up and take a look at Iceland's recent economic history. The 1990s, Iceland's golden days, combined free-market and capitalist principles with a robust welfare system. At the time, this produced strong economic growth plus low unemployment and a relatively even distribution of income. As a result, Iceland was rated as "having one of the world's highest levels of economic freedom as well as civil freedoms."v In the second quarter of 1998, the GDP growth rate reached 10.20%.vi (For comparison purposes, the current GDP growth rate in the US is 2.4%.vii) Iceland's ability to sustain...

Words: 1558 - Pages: 7

Premium Essay

Interest Exchange Rate

...Executive Summary It is important for companies and investors to have a firm understanding on the forces driving exchange rate changes as these would affect investment and financing opportunities. This report analyzes the movements of three currencies, Australian Dollar (AUD), Icelandic Krona (ISK), and Indian Rupee (INR) against US dollar, and suggests events that may cause the violations of three chosen currencies. Analysis shows that factors including but not limited to inflation rates, interest rate differences, foreign investment as well as demand and supply of domestic currency are highly correlated with exchange rate changes in chosen currencies. Based on the analysis, Purchasing Power Parity is used to forecast spot exchange rates of those chosen currencies in one-year and three-year time. Rationales and limitations of PPP are also given to analyze the forecasts of three currencies. Table of Content 1.0 Introduction 1 2.0 Question 1 1 2.1 AUD/USD 1 3.0 Question 2 4 3.1 ISK/USD 4 3.2 INR/USD 6 3.3 Common Events that May Have Influenced the Exchange Rate Changes 8 4.0 Question 3 9 4.1 Forecast of Currencies 9 4.2 Forecast of AUD 10 4.3 Forecast of ISK 11 4.3 Forecast of INR 11 4.3 Comments on the Forecasts 12 References 13   Figures & Tables Figure 1 Exchange Rate of AUD/USD Over Five Years 1 Figure 2 Percentage Change of AUD/USD Exchange Rate 2 Figure 3 Trends of AUD/USD and Gold Price 2 Figure 4 AUD/USD Exchange Rate and Interest...

Words: 3687 - Pages: 15

Premium Essay

Investigating International Business

...UNIT 40 INVESTIGATING INTERNATIONAL BUSINESS BTEC NATIONAL INTRODUCTION. The international nature of business is evident to anyone who, for example, buys an iPod from Apple or insurance from Aviva. Many brand names are recognised throughout the world as organisations increase demand for their products by expanding from a national to an international market. Initially, the nature of the international business environment will be considered by looking at the size and importance of international markets. Governments encourage businesses to trade internationally but protectionism is also common. International business is regulated not just by national governments but also by transnational trading arrangements promoted by trading blocs such as the European Union and global agencies such as the World Trade Organization (WTO). Both large and small businesses trade internationally but doing business internationally is often more complex than doing business in the home market. Consideration will be given to the issues facing a domestic (UK) business when it expands its operations into the international sphere. However, some insights can be made by considering issues faced by overseas businesses as they have expanded their operations by moving into the UK market. Tesco has had very limited success in extending operations into France and Carrefour has had similar problems in establishing operations in the UK. However, they both have had more success in Malaysia and...

Words: 10545 - Pages: 43

Premium Essay

Iceland V Ireland

...------------------------------------------------- Ireland & Iceland: ------------------------------------------------- Who made the better choice? ------------------------------------------------- Contents 1. Introduction to the financial crisis 2 2. Conditions leading up to the Irish and Icelandic economic crisis 3 2.1 The business cycle 3 2.2 The era of the Irish ‘Celtic Tiger’ 4 2.3 The ‘Financial Vikings’ of Iceland 5 3. Financial crisis response 6 3.1 Government response to the financial crisis 6 3.2 The default decision 10 4. Economic outlook and long-term repercussions 14 5. Conclusion 18 1. Introduction to the financial crisis The Great Recession began in 2007 as the United States housing market fell into a sharp decline. Many economists consider the resulting financial crisis to be the worst financial crisis since the Great Depression. While the crisis can be traced back to a variety of economic origins, the volatility that existed in the world economy from the 1990’s undoubtedly played a large role (Roubini, 2010). The Asian Crisis that arose after the fall of car manufacturer Kia in 1997 and the burst of the Dotcom Bubble in the early 2000’s resulted in many wealthy countries decreasing interest rates to all-time lows to encourage growth in their economies (Roubini, 2010). These low interest rates led consumers, particularly those in the US, to borrow more money than they could afford to repay (Roubini, 2010). During...

Words: 5823 - Pages: 24

Premium Essay

Wikileak

...     About us Advertise Contact Us Send Comments/Tips Home My FDL Firedoglake News TBogg La Figa Book Salon FDL Action The Dissenter Pam's House Blend Elections FDL TV Just Say Now Password Remember Me Login              Username: « Is the UK Torture Inquiry an Attempt to Limit Further Disclosure? Another Obama Recess Appointment For Someone Not Named Johnsen » Wikileaks Leaker Bradley Manning Finally Charged By: emptywheel Tuesday July 6, 2010 12:14 pm submit Tweet 93 The government has finally charged Bradley Manning, the Wikileaks leaker. He is charged with two counts of violating the UCMJ, one related to loading onto his own unsecure computer a set of information and adding unauthorized software to a military network computer, and the other related to accessing and passing information onto someone not entitled to have it. I find the charge sheet particularly interesting for two reasons. What the government says that Manning did with the material he accessed, and an apparent discrepancy between the government’s depiction of the timing and Wired’s depiction of it. What the government knows about what Manning did with the information First, it describes the information he accessed differently as follows:   The video of the July 12, 2007 Apache killing of Reuters journalists (obtained via unauthorized access, loaded onto his unsecured computer, transmitted to someone unauthorized to receive it) The Rejkjavik State Department...

Words: 8363 - Pages: 34

Free Essay

Mr Edgy

...WikiLeaks This article is about the website and organisation. For the Australian political party, see The Wikileaks Party. Note that WikiLeaks has no connection whatsoever to Wikipedia or its parent, the Wikimedia Foundation, which operates the encyclopedia. WikiLeaks The logo of WikiLeaks, an hourglass with one globe leaking to the second | | Web address | WikiLeaks.org [1] a | Slogan | We open governments. | Commercial? | No | Type of site | Document archive and disclosure | Registration | None | Available in | English, but the documents are written in various languages | Owner | Sunshine Press | Created by | Julian Assange | Launched | 4 October 2006 | Alexa rank | 14,957 (April 2014[2]) | Current status | Online | WikiLeaks is an international, online, non-profit, journalistic organisation which publishes secret information, news leaks, and classified media from anonymous sources. Its website, initiated in 2006 in Iceland by the organization Sunshine Press, claimed a database of more than 1.2 million documents within a year of its launch. Julian Assange, an Australian Internet activist, is generally described as its founder, editor-in-chief, and director. Kristinn Hrafnsson, Joseph Farrell, and Sarah Harrison are the only other publicly known and acknowledged associates of Julian Assange. Hrafnsson is also a member of Sunshine Press Productions along with Assange, Ingi Ragnar Ingason, and Gavin MacFadyen.[3][4] The group has released...

Words: 12383 - Pages: 50

Premium Essay

Tobin Tax

...The Tobin Tax And Its Effects On The Foreign Exchange Market International Business Thesis By Mark Hansen 290587-1563 & Nina Johansen 140988-1838 Advisor Niels Blomgren-Hansen 17.05.2010 Executive summary In this thesis a financial transaction tax in the form of the Tobin Tax is examined as a means to reduce volatility on the foreign exchange market. James Tobin original proposal is presented followed by his 1995 paper and Frankel’s contribution to the discussion. Frankel gives merit to Tobin’s line of reasoning on reducing stability by dividing investors into short-term speculators and long-term fundamentalists and defines the former’s activities as destabilizing and the latter as stabilizing. However, we find this segmentation problematic since it is not possible to divide the market participants into these categories in the foreign exchange market. Many of the short-term investors do not necessarily speculate or disregard fundamentals, but rather try to avoid risk. Accordingly, many of the short term market movements are instead stabilizing. Therefore, the Tobin Tax would not only deter the destabilizing transactions, but also the stabilizing ones. If the foreign exchange market is in fact excessively volatile as Tobin argues then the tax could possibly have a positive effect by throwing sand in the wheels and thereby slowing short-term reactions. Our findings suggest that the foreign exchange market is in fact highly volatile, but we find no convincing...

Words: 24467 - Pages: 98

Premium Essay

Financial Crisis in the European Union: the Cases of Greece and Ireland

...Financial Crisis in the European Union: The Cases of Greece and Ireland Sara F. Taylor Thesis submitted to the faculty of the Virginia Polytechnic Institute and State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Master of Arts in Political Science Scott G. Nelson, Chair Karen M. Hult Deborah J. Milly September 7, 2011 Blacksburg, Virginia Keywords: EUROPEAN UNION, EUROZONE, GREECE FINANCIAL CRISIS, IRELAND BANKING CRISIS, EUROPEAN CENTRAL BANK Copyright 2011 Sara F. Taylor Financial Crisis in the European Union: The Cases of Greece and Ireland Sara Frances Taylor ABSTRACT The 2008 eurozone financial crisis has only worsened as of summer 2011 raising questions about the economic future of the eurozone and sending shock waves through economies around the world. Greece was the first state to receive a bailout from the European Union and the International Monetary Fund, surprisingly followed only six months later by Ireland. The goal of this thesis is to analyze the challenges posed to smaller, weaker economies within the eurozone, specifically Greece and Ireland, since the recent eurozone financial crisis. This study is based on the experiences of both Greece and Ireland as very different members of the single currency. How and why did these states meet the criteria for euro convergence? To what extent was there support for the euro in both countries in the past? To what extent is there support today after the near collapse...

Words: 30568 - Pages: 123

Free Essay

Economics

...Co-Creating Our Future on Planet Earth Creating Unity from our human diversity. Skip to content * Home * About * Last 2000 Posts in Order ← Civil war up, humanism down: Pepe Escobar, by Pepe Escobar The Oracle Report, Monday, April 13, 2015 → :) :) :) Iceland Stuns Banks: Plans To Take Back The Power To Create Money Posted on April 13, 2015 by Jean By Raúl Ilargi Meijer Zero Hedge April 1, 2015 Submitted by Raul Ilargi Meijer via The Automatic Earth blog, Who knew that the revolution would start with those radical Icelanders? It does, though. One Frosti Sigurjonsson, a lawmaker from the ruling Progress Party, issued a report today that suggests taking the power to create money away from commercial banks, and hand it to the central bank and, ultimately, Parliament. Can’t see commercial banks in the western world be too happy with this. They must be contemplating wiping the island nation off the map. If accepted in the Iceland parliament , the plan would change the game in a very radical way. It would be successful too, because there is no bigger scourge on our economies than commercial banks creating money and then securitizing and selling off the loans they just created the money (credit) with. Everyone, with the possible exception of Paul Krugman, understands why this is a very sound idea. Agence France Presse reports: Iceland Looks At Ending Boom And Bust With Radical Money Plan Iceland’s government is considering a revolutionary monetary proposal...

Words: 36517 - Pages: 147

Free Essay

Marketing

...Co-Creating Our Future on Planet Earth Creating Unity from our human diversity. Skip to content * Home * About * Last 2000 Posts in Order ← Civil war up, humanism down: Pepe Escobar, by Pepe Escobar The Oracle Report, Monday, April 13, 2015 → :) :) :) Iceland Stuns Banks: Plans To Take Back The Power To Create Money Posted on April 13, 2015 by Jean By Raúl Ilargi Meijer Zero Hedge April 1, 2015 Submitted by Raul Ilargi Meijer via The Automatic Earth blog, Who knew that the revolution would start with those radical Icelanders? It does, though. One Frosti Sigurjonsson, a lawmaker from the ruling Progress Party, issued a report today that suggests taking the power to create money away from commercial banks, and hand it to the central bank and, ultimately, Parliament. Can’t see commercial banks in the western world be too happy with this. They must be contemplating wiping the island nation off the map. If accepted in the Iceland parliament , the plan would change the game in a very radical way. It would be successful too, because there is no bigger scourge on our economies than commercial banks creating money and then securitizing and selling off the loans they just created the money (credit) with. Everyone, with the possible exception of Paul Krugman, understands why this is a very sound idea. Agence France Presse reports: Iceland Looks At Ending Boom And Bust With Radical Money Plan Iceland’s government is considering a revolutionary monetary proposal...

Words: 36542 - Pages: 147