Free Essay

Rational Expectation Theory

In:

Submitted By omagu
Words 4443
Pages 18
COURSE TITLE : ADVANCED MACRO ECONOMICS
COURSE CODE : ECN 703
REG NO: 15491119
NAME: GODWIN OMAGU
QUESTION: Given the 'Rational Expectations Theory' a short run tradeoff between the price level and unemployment can only exist if the economy agent can distinguish arbitrary from real shock. Discuss

Rational Expectations Theory

What is the 'Rational Expectations Theory'

The rational expectations theory is an economic idea that the people in the economy make choices based on their rational outlook, available information and past experiences. The theory suggests that the current expectations in the economy are equivalent to what the future state of the economy will be. This contrasts the idea that government policy influences the decisions of people in the economy.

BREAKING DOWN 'Rational Expectations Theory'

The idea is that rational expectations of the players in an economy will partially affect what happens to the economy in the future. If a company believes that the price for its product will be higher in the future, it will stop or slow production until the price rises. Because the company weakens supply while demand stays the same, price will increase. In sum, the producer believes that the price will rise in the future, makes a rational decision to slow production and this decision partially affects what happens in the future.
"Inflation-Unemployment Trade-off under Adaptive Expectation and under Rational Expectation"?
When agents in economy have adaptive expectations they predict future in the basis of what happened in the past. If we consider an inflation adjustment scenario, the expected inflation by the agents is directly dependent on the inflation that prevailed in the immediately previous period and the output gap.
Y = Yo + b(P - Pe) where Pe is expected price level
When agents have adaptive expectations there is an inflation inertia.
To reduce unemployment rate the government will try to stimulate the economy and if the economy was at its natural level of unemployment the will be inflationary pressure an inflation will increase. If the agents do not correctly predict the inflation they are likely to produce more. Say for example agents have an expectation that inflation will be 4% based on past experience. And with the government expansion output increases and inflation actually increases to say, 8%. Their nominal wages will adjust according to 4% but the real wage will actually decrease. As a rule of thumb you can remember that if the expected inflation is lower than the actual inflation then output increases and producers hire more workers thereby reducing unemployment. So, there is a trade off here between unemployment rate and inflation level as suggested by the Okun's law and Philips curve. However this is not the end of story. As soon as the workers realize that their real wages have reduced, they bargain for higher wages and eventually the whole change is reverted as firms' costs increase and they reduce output and fire workers to match the cost. This is also the reason why the long run supply curve is vertical.
With rational expectations ,however, it is a different story altogether. Rational expectations mean that the agents in economy apply all levels of reasoning to the available information to figure out the future scenario. They know the policy of central bank and government, they can correctly predict their actions and hence they know that inflation will be higher and simply ask for more wages. So no effect on output or employment and hence no tradeoff but only an increase in inflation. The policy will not be effective here. This is a concept in neo classical economics and is sometimes called as policy ineffectiveness proposition.

Economic analysis needs a theory of expectations

In the last few years, policymakers as well a s academicians have been recognizing the importance of expectations in economic decision making. They have found that expectations can be a key factor in a wide range of consumption, investment, and policymaking problems. In fact, it is hard to imagine an economic problem which does not include expectations. Most economic problems are inherently dynamic; in some way, time is involved. Time can be a cost of production, an element in the planning horizon, or an influence on preferences. Whatever the problem, though, once time becomes a factor, expectations must also, for what we think is going to happen tomorrow will affect the choices we make today

The consumption-saving problem faced by economic agents illustrates the key role of expectations in the decision process. One of the most successful theories
For explaining consumption and saving has been the permanent-income hypothesis.

Roughly speaking, it says that today's consumption and saving depend not only on today's spendable income, but on expected future income as well. Expected life-span, expected future tax liability, and expected earning potential can all affect economic agents' decisions on how much income to consume now and how much to save for the next period.
People who expected a shorter life-span, a new tax on consumption, or a higher
Salary might greatly increase their current consumption or saving.
Investment decisions are another kind of problem in which expectations play an obviously important role. What individuals invest today clearly depends on what returns and what risks they expect over the life of the investment.
One major influence on their expected returns and risks is their expected future tax liabilities. For example, congressional consideration of a windfall profits tax
Has undoubtedly increased the risks and reduced the investment individuals are willing to make in the oil industry. It would be easy to enumerate many other economic problems that are inherently dynamic and require a theory of expectations, but perhaps it is unnecessary. At least to some extent, economists have always agreed that expectations are critical at this level of analysis. Only recently, though, have they become aware that expectations are also important for analyzing economic stabilization policies. Like most other economic problems, stabilization policies must be analyzed in a dynamic framework .
What government does today—how it raises taxes, spends its revenues, and finances its deficits —affects the economic environment of the future. (And the government presumably cares about the future economy as well as the present.)

Once again, where time is a factor, expectations are critical.
People's decisions today depend on expectations of the future. Because government policies affect future outcomes, they affect people's expectations and thus affect people's current decisions. If today's policy actions do not take expectations into account, they may not have their intended effects. A theory of expectations, therefore, is a major ingredient for almost any analysis of economic behavior. In particular, it's a prerequisite for any model that is going to explain how economic decisions are made and how optimal government policies are formulated

The Adaptive Expectations Theory Recognizing the importance of developing a theory of expectations has proved much less controversial than agreeing on the
Best theory. Many have believed that the adaptive expectations theory, which assumes that expectations are simply an extrapolation of past trends, is the best we could do. But recent theoretical challenges, as well as recent experience, have raised serious doubts about the validity of modeling expectations this way. Model builders' initial attempts at constructing a theory of expectations were based on relatively simplistic assumptions. These attempts assumed either that agents expected no change or that they expected the change tomorrow to be the same as it was today. After some experimenting, econometricians found that they could get better fitting equations if they assumed that expected changes would be equal to a weighted average of past changes. This adaptive expectations model went virtually unchallenged until the 1970s.

The substantive issues economists first discussed about this theory were not those dealing with the validity of adaptive expectations but rather those questioning the size of the weights and the length of them lag distribution. If the weights were small and the lags were long, models that used the adaptive expectations scheme predicted that the trade-off between inflation and unemployment as quite favorable. Stimulative policy only had to increase inflation a little in order to lower real wages and boost employment and production for a relatively long time. If the weights were large and the lags were short, however, the inflation –unemployment trade-off was much less favorable.
Then reducing real wages required significantly more inflation, and the employment and production benefits didn't last nearly as long.
The discussion of weights and lags was not trivial as long as the adaptive expec-tations scheme remained unchallenged. The debate about the characteristics of the lag distribution continues even today as we hear both policymakers and economists argue about the costs and benefits of stimulating a recessionary economy that is suffering from double-digit inflation. Such debates, though , ignore more fundamental issues. While some economists are still trying to estimate the trade-off between inflation and unemployment, others are questioning the validity of the underlying theory.

Models based on adaptive expectations, which worked well in the 1960s, failed dramatically in the 1970s. In the early 1970s such models predicted, with a high degree of confidence, that the United States could drive its unemployment rate down to 4 percent if it were only willing to live with a 4 to 5 percent rate of inflation; with a 5 to 6 percent rate of inflation, it could virtually eliminate unemployment.
There was some debate about whether this trade-off could be repeatedly exploited, but most economists agreed that at least in the short run such a trade-off existed.
The actual 1970s inflation and unemployment statistics were a serious rejection of these models. Whether by design or not, we got much more inflation than most expected, yet unemployment climbed above 9 percent instead of falling to zero as predicted.

To some, this empirical rejection of standard macro econometric models came as no surprise because the theory of adaptive expectations is inconsistent with the rest of economic theory.
The fundamental principle underlying virtually all economic theory has been that agents always do the best they can for themselves, given their income, wealth and technological constraints. With the resources and tools available, firms produce until any extra output brings less revenue than the extra cost of production—that is, until maximum profits are collected .

Likewise, individuals consume until any extra current consumption is worth less than tomorrow's consumption—that is, until consumption is maximized over time. And likewise, workers continue working until any extra income they earn is worth less to them than the leisure they forego.
The theory of adaptive expectations is not consistent with this principle of optimization.
The adaptive expectations equations used for forecasting generally imply, that agents don't optimize.
They imply, instead, that agents can be systematically fooled so that obvious profits can go uncollected.

Adaptive expectations are irrational
A few examples will illustrate how agents fail to optimize when they base their expectations just on historical relationships, as the adaptive expectations scheme assumes.
Suppose the government announced a new higher rate of price supports for wheat. And suppose this policy change was advertised well in advance and had complete congressional approval. The wheat farmers who based their production and storage decisions only on past price behavior would make some very big mistakes—just as they would if they ignored the price implications of a new report on the Russian wheat harvest or a recent change in weather. The wheat farmers who based their decisions on such readily available information, as well as on the historical behavior of past prices, would obviously do much better.
In adaptive forecasting schemes, agents also fail to optimize in the wage bargaining process. If workers or their unions use only historical data to forecast future inflation, they can easily be misled into working for wages with lower purchasing power than desired.
Suppose the government announced that the accumulated federal deficit in the 1980s was going to grow twice as fast as it did in the 1970s and that the Federal Reserve was going to buy most of this new debt. Those unions that assumed prices were going to behave just as they did in the 1970s would agree to contracts that allowed their members' real wages to decline. Those unions that paid attention to the correlation between government financing and inflation would make much better deals for their members.

Under adaptive expectations, agents also fail to optimize when OPEC announces a change in its pricing policy. Suppose OPEC planned to double its price tomorrow. Firms that used a lot of energy would seriously understate their expenses if they only looked at the historical prices of oil not at probable future prices. The efficient firm would take this new information into account and make a much better decision.

By not using available information about current and future events, agents who form expectations adaptively can make some very obvious mistakes, leaving very obvious profits uncollected. The criticism of the adaptive expectations theory, though, goes much deeper. It is not only that mistakes are obvious, but also that they persist. Thomas Sargent(1976a, pp.316-18) has shown that when agents form expectations adaptively, one can easily devise a future path for any policy variable that can systematically and forever fool them. Adaptive expectations, therefore, are generally irrational expectations.

The Rational Expectations Theory
Recognizing the non optimality of the adaptive expectations approach, several researchers began to take a new theory pioneered by John Muth (1961) more seriously. Muth's idea was to model expectations the same way economists model other Economic behavior: by assuming agents maximize their objective functions subject to the constraints they face. With this in mind, Muth assumed that agents' subjective probability distributions are equal to the objective or actual probability distributions plus a random term, the variance of which depends on the information available to agents. He defined such expectations as rational. Rationality, therefore, is not perfect foresight; people can make mistakes. In fact, people can make lots of mistakes, but they will not be systematically wrong.
By assuming that agents use information efficiently, Muth was able to construct a theory of expectations that was consistent with the Rest of economic theory. Like other economic theories, Muth's implies that obvious uncollected profits do not persist. Constructing such a theory, however, was not the break – through that led a significant number of economists to abandon standard models.

The major breakthrough came when Robert Lucas showed that rational expectations models can explain a correlation between inflation and unemployment, a correlation similar to that represented by the Phillips curve.
Standard macroeconomics began with the notion that we could not explain unemployment with classical equilibrium models. In a nonstochastic, frictionless classical model, in which agents optimize and Markets clear, monetary policy is neutral. There is no correlation between inflation and unemployment, for there is no unemployment; in equilibrium, all who want to work can work. As the money supply increases and prices rise, real wages remain unchanged. Workers concerned about the purchasing power of wages raise their money wage demands, but firms are willing to pay the higher wages because their prices have increased. In the new equilibrium, nominal wages rise by the same amount as prices, leaving employment and production unchanged.

To explain the inflation-unemployment correlation represented by the Phillips curve, macroeconomists have argued that we had to abandon the assumptions of clearing markets and optimizing agents. James Tobin (1947), for example, assumed that agents were "irrational" in the labor markets. He recognized that such agents were incompatible with optimizing agents, but he contended that the only way to construct a model consistent with the correlation between inflation and unemployment was to drop the optimizing assumption. The non optimality assumption also implied that the correlation represented a trade-off that could be exploited by expansionary fiscal and monetary policies. We could reduce unemployment if we were willing to pay the price of a higher inflation rate.
Lucas' contribution was to show that the classical model was abandoned Prematurely (Lucas 1972, 1975). He proved that an essentially classical model — one based on the classical principle of optimizing agents and clearing markets —could generate a correlation between inflation and unemployment. He did this by extending classical theory to include uncertainty and information costs. In Lucas' new classical approach, agents face an information problem. In general, they do not know whether a change in the price of their labor is a real change (due, say, to an increase in demand for their services) or simply a reflection of a general rise in all prices. If an increase in the price of their labor occurred because of areal change in supply or demand, then agents would want to respond somehow. For instance, they might adjust the number of hours they were willing to work. If the increase in the price of their labor was merely the result of inflation, however, then they wouldn't want to respond.
The problem they face is that they don't know whether any specific change in their own price is real or not, so they don't know how to respond. When agents face this kind of uncertainty, some of them respond as if the price changes were real and not just the result of a general change in the price level. Under these conditions, unexpected movements in prices can generate real effects, such as the correlation between inflation and unemployment.

Challenges to Macro Models and Policies
The policy implications of this ne w micro theory are obviously much different from those of standard macroeconomics.
The theory suggests that there is no simple way to stimulate demand and move the economy along the Phillips curve toward higher output. In fact, Sargent and
Neil Wallace(1975) have shown that even within a standard macro framework, the inflation-unemployment trade-off doesn't exist when rational expectations are imposed. While policies can have real effects, the effects are much more subtle and complex than standard models have led us to believe.

Sargent and Wallace first showed that in ad hoc macroeconomic models, under certain conditions, rational expectations imply that policy is neutral. [They define an ad hoc model as one that is not derived from a consistent set of assumptions about individuals' and firms' objective functions and available information (Sargent and Wallace 1975, p. 241). ] If the public an d monetary y authority have access to the same information and if agents have identical preferences, then "the probability distribution of output is independent of the deterministic money supply rule in effect" (p.242). In an ad hoc model, one nonrandom money supply rule is as good as another.
They went on to show that, when these assumptions are relaxed, monetary policy can affect the distribution of output, but constructing the right policy nevertheless becomes very hard. When the monetary authority has more information than the public, for example, policy can affect the variance of output (though not the mean). To choose the right policy, however, the monetary authority must know precisely how the public's information differs from its own. When the Public is slow to learn about a policy change, for another example, the monetary authority can affect real output. But here again, the monetary authority must know precisely what the public knows, plus how it learns, before it can devise the right policy. Policy analysis no longer rests on estimating a simple relationship Between inflation and unemployment. It now requires the policymaker to know precisely how information sets differ and how people learn.
As Sargent and Wallace point out, this is such a subtle task it is likely to be an intractable econometric problem.
These results of the rational expectations research are often misinterpreted. Many think the theory of rational expectations says that monetary policy does not matter, that whatever the monetary authority tries to do, rational agents will undo. This, however, is the wrong implication. More accurately, the Sargent- Wallace results are a strong indictment of ad hoc macro models because they point out how little these models tell us about the impact of inflation. We know that inflationary policies matter. We know, for example, that inflation makes the real return on money negative; therefore, inflation must generally cause a declinee in all other real rates. We also know that inflation affects the value of agents' endowments and that not all agents are identical; therefore, inflation must affect real consumption and saving decisions.
Further, we know that agents' information sets differ among themselves and differ from the information sets of the monetary authorities; therefore, inflation must have an effect on the distribution of output. Yet, ad hoc macro models tell us nothing about these effects; they are not explicit enough to capture the impact of monetary policy. Without more explicit theories, we cannot even begin to understand how inflation affects the economy and how to construct appropriate policies.

The Dominating Theory
Some have alleged that the assumptions behind rational expectations are too unrealistic, that people just are not smart enough to be rational. They argue that people don't have enough information to make rational forecasts or that they don't know how to use the information efficiently. Both allegations are misleading. Most useful theories, after all, make some superficially unrealistic assumptions.
Furthermore, rationality does not depend on how much information agents have, but only on how they use their information. No matter how little information they have, therefore, agents have enough to satisfy the premises of rational expectations. The substantive issue is thus whether they use their information efficiently. Using information efficiently means only that agents cannot be systematically Wrong forever.
This is a realistic enough assumption. Although absolutely efficient use of information may not be descriptively realistic, would it be more realistic to assume people use information inefficiently ? That is, would it be more realistic to assume people are 95 percent, 50 percent, or 25 percent efficient ? I doubt it. Any number would be difficult to defend strictly on realistic grounds. Furthermore, anything less than 100 percent efficiency implies obvious uncollected profits, since people can be consistently fooled. Surely this implication cannot be justified on grounds of realism.

Most economists would agree that only empirical results can provide tests for choosing among competing theories . In economics, however, testing alternative theories is usually not very easy. Choosing between rational and adaptive expectations is a classic example. On the one hand, advocates of rationality contend that their theory can explain the shifting Phillips curve observed in the 1970s. The curve shifted, they believe, because inflation did not continue to surprise people. On the other hand, proponents of adaptive expectations claim that the Phillips curve shifted for reasons that had little to do with inflationary expectations. They argue that changes in the composition of the work force and the pricing Policies of OPEC were the major causes of the instability in the Phillips curve. Once these extraneous factors are taken into account, their autoregressive Equations fit the 1970s very well.

Based on goodness of fit, then, neither theory of expectations is clearly superior.
But Sargent (1976b) has shown that in a period when only one policy rule is in effect, this criterion can never be used to determine which theory is better. An adaptive expectations model can be constructed to fit the data just as well as a rational expectations model when there has not been a change in the policy rule.
Sargent's findings, however, do not rule out all tests; they only make the task more difficult. A way to test the validity of these theories is to test their stability under alternative policy rules. The only study I know of that has performed such a test found the rational expectations model superior. Salih Neftci and Sargent (1978) identified a break in monetary policy rule in 1968. After estimating a standard version of a macro econometric model for the years before 1968, they applied the model to the years after 1968 and found that it failed dramatically.
It was not stable. The rational expectations results, while not spectacular, were considerably better.
The model marginally passed a test of stability. This is an important test because an economic model must remain invariant When policy changes if it is to be useful for evaluating policies. With the empirical evidence available, then, the rational expectations theory cannot be dismissed, nor should its policy implications be ignored.

Conclusion
The rational expectations theory gives us a new perspective on policy analysis. For the first time, it gives us a coherent approach to modeling expectations that may be applied to many aspects of economic analysis.
Equally important, the rational expectations theory has some very negative implications.
It says that we currently know very little about the appropriate use of economic Policies It says that macroeconomists have to develop more explicit models of economic behavior.

It says that the answers we seek are much more subtle and complex than we
Once believed.
Because we know so little, economists and policy-makers should be considerably
Humbler in their policy prescriptions. Simple correlations between inflation and unemployment, for instance, cannot be reliable guides to policy.
At most, we can say that since policy actions can easily add to the economic uncertainty, whatever rules we happen to choose should be well defined and
Well understood.
For policymakers to advocate much more than this will require significant theoretical and empirical breakthroughs in research. In the meantime, it seems to me the best we can do is to follow policy rules which are stable and long-run. Who knows; we might even like the results we get.

References
Lucas, Robert E., Jr. 1972. Expectations and the neutrality of money .Journal of Economic Theory 4 (April): 103-24.

___________1975. An equilibrium model of the business cycle. Journal of Political Economy 83 (December): 1113-44.

Muth, John F. 1961. Rational expectations and the theory of price move- ments. Econometrica 29 (July): 315-35.

Neftci, Salih, and Sargent, Thomas J. 1978. A little bit of evidence on the natural rate hypothesis from the U.S. Journal of Monetary Economics 4 (April): 315-19.

Sargent, Thomas J. 1976a. Interest rates and expected inflation: a selective summary of recent research. Explorations in Economic Research: Occasional Papers of the National Bureau of Economic Research 3 (Summer): 303-25.

___________1976b. The observational equivalence of natural and unnatural rate theories of macroeconomics. Journal of Political Economy 84 (June): 631-40.

Sargent, Thomas J., and Wallace, Neil. 1975. "Rational" expectations, the optimal monetary instrument, and the optimal money supply rule. Journal of Political Economy 83 (April): 241-54.
Tobin, James. 1947. Money wage rates and employment. In The new

economics: Keynes' influence on theory and public policy, ed. Seymour Harris, pp. 572-87. New York: Knopf.

Similar Documents

Premium Essay

Rational Expectation

...RATIONAL EXPECTATION While rational expectations is often thought of as a school of economic thought, it is better regarded as a ubiquitous modeling technique used widely throughout economics. The theory of rational expectations was first proposed by John F. Muth of Indiana University in the early 1960s. He used the term to describe the many economic situations in which the outcome depends partly on what people expect to happen. The price of an agricultural commodity, for example, depends on how many acres farmers plant, which in turn depends on the price farmers expect to realize when they harvest and sell their crops. As another example, the value of a currency and its rate of depreciation depend partly on what people expect that rate of depreciation to be. That is because people rush to desert a currency that they expect to lose value, thereby contributing to its loss in value. Similarly, the price of a stock or bond depends partly on what prospective buyers and sellers believe it will be in the future. Expectational Error Models of the Business Cycle A long tradition in business cycle theory has held that errors in people’s forecasts are a major cause of business fluctuations. This view is embodied in the phillips curve (the observed inverse correlation between unemployment and inflation), with economists attributing the correlation to errors people make in their forecasts of the price level. Before the advent of rational expectations, economists often proposed to...

Words: 306 - Pages: 2

Free Essay

Essays in Accounting Theory: Corporate Earnings Management in a Dynamic Setting and Public Disclosure in the Financial Services Industry

...Essays in Accounting Theory: Corporate Earnings Management in a Dynamic Setting and Public Disclosure in the Financial Services Industry A Dissertation Presented to the Faculty of the Graduate School of Yale University in Candidacy for the Degree of Doctor of Philosophy by Kai Du Dissertation Director: Shyam Sunder December 2012 c 2012 by Kai Du All rights reserved. Abstract Essays in Accounting Theory: Corporate Earnings Management in a Dynamic Setting and Public Disclosure in the Financial Services Industry Kai Du 2012 This dissertation consists of three essays on the interactions between economic fundamentals and accounting information in three different settings: an infinite-horizon financial reporting problem, a coordination game with trading in the secondary market, and a bank which provides risk sharing among demand depositors. In the first essay, I propose a dynamic model of corporate earnings management in which investors have different expectations schemes. I find that while earnings management may exist when investors have rational expectations or misspecified Bayesian beliefs, it disappears in the long run of an adaptive learning process. The model also offers ample predictions on the time-series properties of asset prices and return predictabilities. The second essay studies the role of public disclosure by a distressed firm whose creditors engage in a coordination game with trading. I find that conditioned on the private information...

Words: 38087 - Pages: 153

Premium Essay

Microsoftword

...MANAGERIAL ACCOUNTING 00819 MANAGERIAL ACCOUNTING A 11:0 - 12:30 MW 142 00820 MANAGERIALACCOUNTING B 12:30 - 2:0 ST 142 00821 MANAGERIAL ACCOUNTING C 2:0 - 3:30 MW 142 00825 MANAGERIALACCOUNTING G 9:30 - 11:0 MW 142 00826 MANAGERIAL ACCOUNTING H 11:0 - 12:30 ST 142 00827 MANAGERIAL ACCOUNTING I 12:30 - 2:0 MW 142 00828 MANAGERIAL ACCOUNTING J 2:0 - 3:30 ST 142 00829 MANAGERIAL ACCOUNTING K 3:30 - 5:0 MW 142 MACRO ECONOMICS 01263 MACRO ECONOMICS A 5:0 - 6:30 MW 7072 01265 MACRO ECONOMICS C 9:30 - 11:0 MW 7072 01266 MACRO ECONOMICS D 11:0 - 12:30 ST 7072 01267 MACRO ECONOMICS E 12:30 - 2:0 MW 7072 01268 MACRO ECONOMICS F 2:0 - 3:30 ST 7072 01269 MACRO ECONOMICS G 3:30 - 5:0 MW 7072 01270 MACRO ECONOMICS H 5:0 - 6:30 ST 7072 BEHAVIORAL SCIENCE 00783 INTRODUCTION TO BEHAVIORAL SCIENCE A 3:30 - 5:0 MW 154 00784 INTRODUCTION TO BEHAVIORAL SCIENCE B 5:0 - 6:30 ST 154 00785 INTRODUCTION TO BEHAVIORAL SCIENCE D 9:30 - 11:0 ST 154 00787 INTRODUCTION TO BEHAVIORAL SCIENCE E 11:0 - 12:30 MW 154 00788 INTRODUCTION TO BEHAVIORAL SCIENCE F 12:30 - 2:0 ST 154 00789 ...

Words: 479 - Pages: 2

Premium Essay

Organizations as Rational Systems

...Organizations as Rational Systems Prepared by Anna Lin, 9041816 This paper introduces Rational System Perspectives in relations to four promin ent schools of organization theory; which are Taylor’s scientific management, Fayol’s general principles of management, Weber’s theory of bureaucracy and Simon’s discussion on administrative behavior. Rational System Perspectives There are two key elements characterizing rational systems: 1) Goal Specificity Specific goals support rational behavior in organizations by providing guideli nes on structural design, which leads to specify what tasks are to be performe d and how resources are to be allocated. 2) Formalization Formalization is an attempt to make behavior more predictable by standardizing and regulating. Formalization provides stable expectation, which is a precond ition to rationality. Selected schools The author related rational system perspectives to four schools of organizatio nal theories. Taylor’s Scientific Management (1911) Taylor Scientifically analyzed tasks performed by individual workers and disco vered the best procedure that would produce the maximum output with the minimu m input of resources. His attempts (to rationalize labor at level of the indiv idual worker )led to changes in the entire structure of work arrangement. Ther efore, efficiency improved. His four principles includes: 1) Develop a science for each element of an individual’s work. 2) Scientifically select and train...

Words: 1244 - Pages: 5

Free Essay

Barberisthaler 2003

...Chapter 18 A SURVEY OF BEHAVIORAL FINANCE ° NICHOLAS BARBERIS University of Chicago RICHARD THALER University of Chicago Contents Abstract Keywords 1. Introduction 2. Limits to arbitrage 2.1. Market efficiency 2.2. Theory 2.3. Evidence 2.3.1. Twin shares 2.3.2. Index inclusions 2.3.3. Internet carve-outs 3. Psychology 3.1. Beliefs 3.2. Preferences 3.2.1. Prospect theory 3.2.2. Ambiguity aversion 4. Application: The aggregate stock market 4.1. The equity premium puzzle 4.1.1. Prospect theory 4.1.2. Ambiguity aversion 4.2. The volatility puzzle 4.2.1. Beliefs 4.2.2. Preferences 5. Application: The cross-section of average returns 5.1. Belief-based models 1054 1054 1055 1056 1056 1058 1061 1061 1063 1064 1065 1065 1069 1069 1074 1075 1078 1079 1082 1083 1084 1086 1087 1092 ° We are very grateful to Markus Brunnermeier, George Constantinides, Kent Daniel, Milt Harris, Ming Huang, Owen Lamont, Jay Ritter, Andrei Shleifer, Jeremy Stein and Tuomo Vuolteenaho for extensive comments. Handbook of the Economics of Finance, Edited by G.M. Constantinides, M. Harris and R. Stulz © 2003 Elsevier Science B.V All rights reserved . 1054 5.2. Belief-based models with institutional frictions 5.3. Preferences N. Barberis and R. Thaler 6. Application: Closed-end funds and comovement 6.1. Closed-end funds 6.2. Comovement 7. Application: Investor behavior 7.1. 7.2. 7.3. 7.4. 7.5. Insufficient diversification Naive diversification Excessive trading The selling decision...

Words: 9136 - Pages: 37

Premium Essay

Does Loyalty Equal Dependence?

...need strategies to sustain loyal customers. Many believe that the amount of truth consumers place in companies might be abused, as loyalty sometimes equals strong dependence on suppliers. However, government’s role is to protect their citizens and prevent any actions that might violate ethics, but otherwise, the economy will be better off without intervention, referring to the belief of “Laissez-Faire” (Frank & Cartwright, 2013). The essay will aim to prove that loyalty does not cause overly-dependence if it does not influence ethics, and that consumers will seek for better option for themselves. The rational choice theory, which is the base of the microeconomic studies, states that individuals act rationally and choose the option that will provide them with the highest level of satisfaction (Frank & Cartwright, 2013). This theory resembles the fact that consumers are rational and their decision will always aim to yield the highest possible utility. This basically means that customers can only become loyal if the company puts an effort to maximize satisfaction and utility of their customers. Take another point, if the...

Words: 864 - Pages: 4

Premium Essay

Marketing

...PDF hosted at the Radboud Repository of the Radboud University Nijmegen This full text is a publisher's version. For additional information about this publication click this link. [http://hdl.handle.net/2066/19379] Please be advised that this information was generated on 2012-09-19 and may be subject to change. Buying Impulses: A Study on Impulsive Consumption Astrid Gisela Herabadi Buying Impulses: A Study on Impulsive Consumption Astrid Gisela Herabadi PrintPartners Ipskamp ISBN 90-9017360-9 Cover illustration: A part of the stone-reliefs in “Candi Borobudur” Buying Impulses: A Study on Impulsive Consumption Een wetenschappelijke proeve op het gebied van the Sociale Wetenschappen Proefschrift ter verkrijging van de graad van doctor aan de Katholieke Universiteit Nijmegen op gezag van de rector magnificus Prof.dr.C.W.P.M. Blom, volgens besluit van het College van Decanen in het openbare te verdedigen op woensdag 17 december 2003, des namiddags om 1.30 uur precies door Astrid Gisela Herabadi geboren te Bogor op 30 december 1969 Promotores: Prof. dr. B. Verplanken (University of Tromsø, Norway) Prof. dr. A.F.M. van Knippenberg Manuscriptcommissie: Prof. dr. J.A.J.P. Janssen Prof. dr. N.K. de Vries (Universiteit Maastricht) Prof. dr. M. Zeelenberg (Universiteit van Tilburg) Buying Impulses: A Study on Impulsive Consumption A scientific essay in Social Sciences Doctoral thesis to obtain the degree of doctor from the...

Words: 19590 - Pages: 79

Free Essay

Historical Institutionalism in Comparative Politics

...are commonly drawn between the “historical” and the “rational choice” variants of institutionalism and shows that there are more points of tangency than typically assumed. However, differences remain in how scholars in the two traditions approach empirical problems. The contrast of rational choice’s emphasis on institutions as coordination mechanisms that generate or sustain equilibria versus historical institutionalism’s emphasis on how institutions emerge from and are embedded in concrete temporal processes serves as the foundation for the second half of the essay, which assesses our progress in understanding institutional formation and change. Drawing on insights from recent historical institutional work on “critical junctures” and on “policy feedbacks,” the article proposes a way of thinking about institutional evolution and path dependency that provides an alternative to equilibrium and other approaches that separate the analysis of institutional stability from that of institutional change. INTRODUCTION Institutional analysis has a distinguished pedigree in comparative politics, and the “new” institutionalist literature of the past two decades has both sustained this venerable tradition and deepened our understanding of the role of institutions in political life. At the same time, recent work has given rise to new debates. It is now conventional to distinguish three different varieties of institutionalism: rational choice institutionalism, historical institutionalism...

Words: 8004 - Pages: 33

Free Essay

Rationality, Norms and Identity in Ir

...replace rationalism in explaining international political life. Constructivism maintains that identity or norms are causally prior to actors’ interests. Yet when there is conflict between pursuit of interests and maintenance of identity or norms, actors’ strong and well-defined self-interests can overrule their contested or unstable identity or norms. In short, causal arrows can flow in either direction between identity or norms and interests. This implies that rationalism and constructivism are complementary rather than competitive in explaining international political life. International Politics (2015) 52, 110–127. doi:10.1057/ip.2014.41 Keywords: rationalism; constructivism; rationality; norms; identity; international relations theory Introduction Since the 1990s, one of the major debates in International Relations (IR) scholarship has been between rationalism and constructivism (Katzenstein et al,...

Words: 8767 - Pages: 36

Premium Essay

Behavioural Finance Overview

...Behavioural Finance Topic 10 What it is: * Relatively new and controversial area in the study of finance. * Orthodox finance theory is based on a representative agent that is a rational utility ‘maximiser’ who makes unbiased forecasts about the future. * BF expands the attributes allowed for this representative, replacing the ‘rational’ agent with a ‘normal’ person who is susceptible to a range of cognitive illusions. How and why it began: * The idea that psychological factors may play a role in financial markets, as opposed to mant theorist have always known that less than rational behaviour has been a dominating feature of markets. * This counter act the rational utility maximising representative agent. Dividends: the dividend policy could be completely irrelevant to its share price. This can be shown with an example that if firm A was to pay a large dividene then its retained earnings fall. However if B paid a larger amount then the retainbed earnings is correspondingly higher. Which ever way you go the if the capitalisation is the same than the market will force the price up on the larger dividend company. Trading Volumes: Orthodox models of financial markets imply that there should be little trading in financial assets. The reason for this is that in a world that is rational why would anyone be selling an asset unless they had some information to suggest that they should – and if so, why would anyone else want to buy? Of course, some trading will...

Words: 2792 - Pages: 12

Premium Essay

Carlos Gohs

...BME5001 Leadership and Managerial Skills Carlos Ghosn and Nissan Motor Co., Ltd BME5001 Leadership and Managerial Skills 2014 According to Pearce (2012,pp162) *the practical interest in cultures began with a fascination with the power and strength of multinational Japanese corporations. It wasn’t one thing the Japanese did. Rather, management practices, employee perceptions, expectations and social environments all seemed to reinforce and work in concert to create Japanese corporations’ success”1. Hence, it is intriguing to have Nissan Motor Co Ltd (Nissan) as a case study feature; for an absolutely contrasting reason. Equally fascinating was that Nissan was revived by a non-Japanese leader; Chief Operating Officer (COO) - Carlos Ghosn (Ghosn). Many reasons could have brought about Nissan’s dire state. Since “what successful leaders do depends much on their particular situations than it does on matching cultural leadership practices to stereotyped images of another culture”1, this paper would focus on examining Ghosn’s leadership practices which revived Nissan. “Leadership is the guiding of others towards an objective”.1 To do that, “leaders must diagnose and clearly understand the situations in which they find themselves”1. When Ghosn arrived at Nissan, he assumed nothing, hit the ground to observe and listen to everything that was said and practiced by employees working the floor right up to divisional presidents; in order to understand...

Words: 1481 - Pages: 6

Premium Essay

Gfgfhgh

...or eat candy for dinner. Recent research in behavioral economics has identified a variety of decision-making errors that may expand the scope of paternalistic regula- Professor Camerer is the Rea and Lela Axline Professor of Business Economics, California Institute of Technology; Professor Issacharoff is the Harold R. Medina Professor of Procedural Jurisprudence, Columbia Law School; Professor Loewenstein is a Professor of Economics and Psychology, Carnegie Mellon University; Ted O’Donoghue is an Assistant Professor of Economics, Cornell University; and Professor Rabin is a Professor of Economics, University of California at Berkeley. Our thanks to participants at the University of Pennsylvania Law School Symposium on Preferences and Rational Choice, the University of Southern California Olin Workshop, the Columbia Law School faculty...

Words: 19930 - Pages: 80

Free Essay

The End of Rational Economics

...THE NEW ECONOMICS in the SPECIAL ISSUE NEW WORLD The End of Rational Economics Your company has been operating on the premise that people – customers, employees, managers – make logical decisions. It’s time to abandon that assumption. | by Dan Ariely IN 2008, a massive earthquake reduced the financial world to rubble. Standing in the smoke and ash, Alan Greenspan, the former chairman of the U.S. Federal Reserve once hailed as “the greatest banker who ever lived,” confessed to Congress that he was “shocked” that the markets did not operate according to his lifelong expectations. He had “made a mistake in presuming that the self-interest of organizations, specifically banks and others, was such that they were best capable of protecting their own shareholders.” Jacob Thomas 78 Harvard Business Review | July–August 2009 | hbr.org hbr.org | July–August 2009 | Harvard Business Review 79 THE NEW ECONOMICS in the NEW WORLD. We are now paying a terrible price for our unblinking faith in the power of the invisible hand. We’re painfully blinking awake to the falsity of standard economic theory – that human beings are capable of always making rational decisions and that markets and institutions, in the aggregate, are healthily self-regulating. If assumptions about the way things are supposed to work have failed us in the hyperrational world of IN BRIEF Wall Street, what damage have they done in other institutions » The global economic...

Words: 3426 - Pages: 14

Free Essay

House

...Lynn Silipigni Connaway OCLC Research Timothy J. Dickey OCLC Research Marie L. Radford Rutgers University “If It Is Too Inconvenient, I’m Not Going After It:” Convenience as a Critical Factor in Information-seeking Behaviors Note: This is a pre-print version of a paper forthcoming in Library and Information Science Research. Please cite the published version; a suggested citation appears below. Correspondence about the article may be sent to lynn_connaway@oclc.org. © 2011 OCLC Online Computer Library, Inc. 6565 Kilgour Place, Dublin, Ohio 43017-3395 USA http://www.oclc.org/ Reuse of this document is permitted consistent with the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution-Noncommercial-Share Alike 3.0 (USA) license (CC-BY-NC-SA): http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-sa/3.0/. Suggested citation: Connaway, Lynn Silipigni, Timothy J. Dickey, and Marie L. Radford. 2011. "'If It Is Too Inconvenient, I'm Not Going After It.:' Convenience as a Critical Factor in Information-seeking Behaviors." Library and Information Science Research,33: 179-190. doi:10.1016/j.lisr.2010.12.002 Pre-print available online at: http://www.oclc.org/research/publications/library/2011/connaway-lisr.pdf. “If It Is Too Inconvenient, I’m Not Going After It:” Convenience as a Critical Factor in Information-seeking Behaviors Lynn Silipigni Connaway OCLC Research Timothy J. Dickey OCLC Research Marie L. Radford Rutgers University Abstract In today’s fast-paced...

Words: 14194 - Pages: 57

Free Essay

The Thief of Time

...Press. Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data The thief of time: philosophical essays on procrastination / edited by Chrisoula Andreou and Mark D. White. p. cm. Includes bibliographical references and index. ISBN 978-0-19-537668-5 (hardback: alk. paper) 1. Procrastination. I. Andreou, Chrisoula. II. White, Mark D., 1971– BF637.P76T45 2010 128'.4—dc22 2009021750 987654321 Printed in the United States of America on acid-free paper To Mike and Kaemon and Paul and Ree Acknowledgments We owe special thanks to the Centre for the Study of Mind in Nature for funding a workshop in New York City in the summer of 2008 for the contributors to gather and share ideas; Jennifer Hornsby and Olav Gjelsvik, the research directors of the Rational Agency section of CSMN, played an integral role in...

Words: 125542 - Pages: 503