Free Essay

The Benefits of Transaction Cost Economics

In:

Submitted By vinnybruen
Words 6341
Pages 26
THE BENEFITS OF TRANSACTION COST ECONOMICS: THE BEGINNING OF A NEW DIRECTION
Boudreau, Marie-Claude, University of Georgia, Athens, GA, USA, mcboudre@terry.uga.edu Watson, Richard T. University of Georgia, Athens, GA, USA, RWatson@terry.uga.edu Chen, Adela J. W., University of Georgia, Athens, GA, USA, chenjw@uga.edu Greiner, Martina, University of Georgia, Athens, GA, USA, mgreiner@uga.edu Sclavos, Peter, University of Georgia, Athens, GA, USA, psclavos@uga.edu

Abstract
In this conceptual paper, we argue that the organizational focus on transaction costs needs to be balanced by an attention to transaction benefits, both at the individual and organizational levels. To the transaction characteristics suggested by transaction costs economics, we add four additional ones likely to foster transaction benefits: intensity of knowledge, segmentation of knowledge, dispersion of knowledge, and scarcity of knowledge. The need to maximize transaction benefits while minimizing transaction costs results in the mixing of governance structures, where two (or more) “pure” governance structures are combined. We create a model of the relationships between transaction characteristics, mix of governance structures, transaction costs and benefits, and information systems; from an instantiated version of this general model, we elaborate four propositions. Moreover, with two “real world” examples (Google and JBoss), we illustrate the existence of the proposed transaction characteristics and mixed governance structures. We conclude by discussing how information systems generate opportunities for creating transaction benefits. Keywords: Transaction Cost Economics, Benefits, Governance structures.

1124

1

THE SINGLE MINDEDNESS OF TRANSACTION COST ECONOMICS

Transaction cost economics (TCE) is a highly influential theory. The initiating work (Coase 1937) has more than 5,000 citations,1 but it is not without its critics (Ghoshal 2005). TCE, especially as elaborated by Williamson (1975), advocates that for many situations a command and control hierarchical governance structure is needed to limit opportunistic behavior. This approach, however, can produce the very behaviors that command and control is supposed to limit (Ghoshal and Moran 1996). We contend that the shortcomings of TCE are due to its one-sided view of humans, who are guided by both rational and social goals (Simon 1957). Furthermore, TCE focuses only on one side of a transaction, the costs, and seems to ignore the benefits of a transaction, which frequently cater to the social side of humans. It is not surprising that Coase had a rather monocular economic view of a transaction. His work was written in the 1930s, when much of the world was blighted by an enduring depression. In an era of mass poverty when many were intensely focused on finding any sort of job, the rational human factor was supremely dominant and social needs were put aside. Conditions are quite different today. Affluence is widespread in developed economies, and those with highly developed skills are in much demand, in many cases irrespective of where they live. Those who design today’s organizations cannot ignore human’s social needs and will fail to engage fully their employees’ talents if they construct a command and control hierarchy. Indeed, it might be the case that rather than just balancing rational and social forces, organizational designers should heed the words of James Q. Wilson (1993), “On balance, I think other-regarding features of human nature outweigh the self-regarding ones,” and bias design towards our social inheritance. Furthermore, TCE was conceived in the era when physical goods dominated consumption and transactions were predominantly physical. TCE needs to be re-examined in the context of a service economy and electronic transactions. Many services have shifted from co-located labor-intensive delivery to self-service electronic consumption. Organizational designers cannot ignore the impact of information systems on governance structures. They enable organizations to create systems (e.g., email, video conferencing, databases) that enable many interdependent tasks (Thompson 1967) to be geographically distributed for the benefit of the organization and the individual. In designing these new structures, entrepreneurs need a framework, because, as one of the period’s most influential scholars of strategy Michael Porter asserts, managers prefer frameworks to theories (Argyres and McGahan 2002) for thinking about how to use information systems to create organizations. The organization’s focus on transaction costs needs to be balanced by an attention to transaction benefits. The organization is both a nexus of contracts (Demsetz 1988) and a nexus of relationships, and from our vantage point as IS scholars, these nexuses are mediated and enabled by information systems. In this article, we apply the transaction benefits perspective (Blomqvist, Kyläheiko, and Virolainen 2002, Watson et al. 2005) to understand how collaborate and cooperate now coexist with command and control in the mixed governance structure found in many current organizations (Adler 2001). We thus seek to uncover how both transaction costs and benefits intersect to create governance structures. We are particularly concerned with how the new administrative forms arising from the forge of the Internet are intertwining transaction costs and benefits to create mixed governance structures. We commence our investigation with a review of TCE (which is at the organizational level) and then elaborate on Watson et al’s (2005) idea of transaction benefits (which we posit are both at the individual and organizational levels). Thus, our units of analysis are both the organization and the individual, as some advocate (Rousseau 1985). We illustrate the mixed governance structures with
1

scholar.google.com on 2006.10.08

1125

examples of two recently emerged organizations, Google and JBoss, and then conclude with a discussion on how information systems create many opportunities for leveraging transaction benefits and mixed governance structures.

2

TRANSACTION COST ECONOMICS

TCE asserts that the transaction is the basic unit of economic activity, where a transaction “may be said to occur when a good or service is traded across a technologically separable interface” (Williamson 1993). A transaction cost is a cost incurred in making an economic exchange. Transaction costs are those over and beyond the price of the product or service procured. They broadly break down into motivation and coordination costs (Milgrom and Roberts 1992). Opportunism (Williamson 1985) and agency costs (Jensen and Meckling 1976) are components of motivation costs. Coordination costs include search (Stigler 1961), input coordination (Armen and Demsetz 1972), and measurement costs (Barzel 1982). In reality, these costs can be extended across multiple economic exchanges. Williamson defined a governance structure as an “institutional framework in which the integrity of a transaction or related set of transactions is decided” (Williamson, 1996, p. 11). Governance thus consists of formal and informal structures and rules that enable carrying out economic transactions in an economic manner (Wieland, 2005). TCE maintains that hierarchies and markets are alternative governance structures to organizing economic activity (Arrow 1974) and that firms need to align governance structure and transaction characteristics (Williamson 1985; Silverman, Nickerson, and Freeman 1997). The basic argument of TCE is that decision makers will choose whichever governance structure minimizes the total cost associated with a transaction (Coase 1937) (see Figure 1).

Transaction characteristics
Figure 1

Transaction costs

Governance structure

Transaction cost economics model

Although TCE mainly focuses on transaction costs, the basic criterion for organizing transactions is to economize on the sum of both production expenses and transaction costs (Williamson 1981). If the total cost of using a market is too high, other governance structures, such as hierarchical production in a firm, are more appropriate. TCE argues that transactions have distinct characteristics that, in combination with the attributes of alternate governance structures, produce different production and transaction costs. The three key transaction characteristics are (1) asset specificity, (2) uncertainty, and (3) frequency of transactions (Williamson 1981). Asset specificity refers to the degree to which the investments necessary for a transaction are specific to that particular transaction (Williamson 1981). If the transaction fails, the investments would be less valuable in some second best use (Williamson 1986). Such a situation can lead to dependencies between buyers and suppliers, since, for example, buyers cannot easily turn to an alternative supplier, and are thus “locked into” the transaction for a considerable time after (Williamson 1981). The transaction partner who invests in specialized assets is vulnerable to opportunism and will consequently make special efforts to protect investments by implementing, monitoring, and enforcing contractual safeguards (Rindfleisch et al. 1997). One solution to the safeguarding problem is to integrate vertically, i.e., to produce the good or service in a hierarchy rather than buying it on a market (Klein, Crawford et al. 1978). Hence, with higher levels of asset specificity, a firm will prefer to internally organize production instead of market governance. The second transaction characteristic, uncertainty, can come from different sources, most notably environmental variability and behavioral uncertainty (Rindfleisch and Heide 1997). Environmental uncertainty, such as technological uncertainty, deals with the difficulty to foresee and anticipate

1126

changes in the relevant environment (Rindfleisch and Heide 1997). When faced with high environmental uncertainty, writing complete contracts is difficult, and as unforeseen events emerge, contractual gaps might appear and require renegotiating and adaptation (Williamson 1979). Contract adaptation and re-negotiation are a costly process and will increase transaction costs. As to behavioral uncertainty, it is based on the threat of opportunism and refers to the difficulty of monitoring and evaluating the behavior and performance of the transaction partner. Whereas environmental uncertainty makes it impossible to specify contracts ex ante, behavioral uncertainty refers to the difficulty to verify the performance of the transaction partner ex post (Geyskens, Steenkamp et al. 2006). Governance structures have a varying ability to cope with certain kinds of uncertainty. It is assumed that with higher levels of uncertainty, firms tend to produce products and services internally. Finally, TCE asserts that the frequency of transactions influences both transaction and production costs. So far, this transaction characteristic has received little attention in academic research (Rindfleisch and Heide 1997; Geyskens, Steenkamp et al. 2006), and it should be of interest to information systems researchers because of the emergence of high transaction volume electronic partnerships (Chatterjee, Segars, and Watson 2006). In general, firms have an incentive to internalize production with increasing transaction frequency (Williamson 1987). Though other viewpoints implicitly argue that in the age of the Internet there are competitive advantages in externalizing many high volume transactions that can be executed electronically (Watson, Zinkhan, and Pitt 2004; Chatterjee, Segars, and Watson 2006; Glassberg and Merhout, 2007)

3

TRANSACTION BENEFITS

Beyond market and hierarchy, other governance structures have been suggested. Ouchi (1979, 1980) extended TCE by introducing the clan as a governance structure which, he suggested, should be used when performance ambiguity reaches very high levels. Clan governance requires extensive socialization and long-term relationships. The network is another governance structure, one that is “especially useful for the exchange of commodities whose value is not easily measured” (Powell, 1990, p. 304). The bazaar is yet another which appears to be particularly useful to describe the organization of open source software development (Demil and Lecocq 2003). Others have used the community as a better label to describe this phenomenon (Sharma et al., 2002). We argue that all of these alternative governance structures distinguish themselves from the traditional market and hierarchy governance structures in that they point to transaction benefits, in addition to transaction costs. Indeed, the focus of TCE is on transactions costs, but transactions also have benefits. In a manner analogous to transaction costs, transaction benefits are the benefits incurred in making an economic exchange (Watson et al. 2005). Transaction benefits are above and beyond those benefits of direct financial return. They can exist at an individual level and/or an organizational level. For example, at an individual level, a person employed by a firm gets direct benefits of a salary, health insurance, and so forth. The same person might gain transaction benefits of reputation, collegiality, intellectual challenge, skill development, and enhanced self-esteem. At an organizational level, a firm opting for a market governance structure might reap transaction benefits such as economies of scale due to specialization and flexibility (Blomqvist, Kyläheiko, and Virolainen 2002). Alternatively, the hierarchy as a governance structure might lead a firm to benefit from cumulative learning, increased economies of scope, and possible exploitation of monopoly power (Blomqvist, Kyläheiko, and Virolainen 2002). As to the community governance structure, it is well-suited to innovation, a crucial organizational benefit in a knowledge based economy (Adler 2001). Considering both transaction costs and benefits, a firm needs to consider all possible transaction characteristics. To those acknowledged by TCE, we propose that four additional transaction characteristics are relevant in the context of benefits: (1) the intensity of knowledge, (2) the segmentation of knowledge, (3) the dispersion of knowledge, and (4) the scarcity of knowledge. The

1127

open source community, as one of the more recent governance structures proposed (Sharma et al., 2002), is used to illustrate each of these transaction characteristics. Intensity of knowledge refers to the degree to which the execution of a transaction relies primarily on knowledge and skill rather than physical goods. In the case of a community such as the ones surrounding open source development, the nature of the transaction (i.e., software development) qualifies as knowledge intensive – more so than, for example, the manufacturing of widgets, which relies heavily on physical tools and goods. Given that modern economies are increasingly knowledge intensive (Adler 2001), the extent of this characteristic on business transactions is on the rise. Electronic networks enable knowledge work to be moved from co-location, physical settings to distributed communication networks. Moreover, whereas it is accepted that the hierarchy and market governance structures are effective in low-knowledge-intensity transactions (Adler 2001), another type of governance structure, or combination of them, may be called for when the intensity of knowledge of a transaction is high. Segmentation of knowledge is the need for involving more than two parties (the principal and the agent) to execute a transaction. Given a certain level of complexity, many more parties may need to be involved for a transaction to be executed and completed. Software development according to the open source model usually involves many often very independent parties, each specializing in a given area. As such, a given open source project may include a project leader, some core members, many active developers, peripheral developers, bug fixers, and bug reporters. Each party has its area of expertise, and all need to collaborate to achieve success. Such involvement of multiple parties is only possible if the transaction can be modularized, that is, divisible into concrete, smaller chunks (Gallivan et al., 1994). Dispersion of knowledge refers to the extent to which the knowledge required to accomplish a transaction is dispersed in multiple locations. Again, open source communities constitute a salient example of such a transaction, as it is typical for a given project to involve developers physically located in many different areas around the globe. Recruiting community members based on talent, unfettered by physical location, thus ensures that high quality expertise is provided and innovative ideas are contributed. For instance, open source firm Trolltech has employees originating from 20 different countries. The mantra for knowledge work is connection, connection, connection.2 Finally, scarcity of knowledge is the extent to which the knowledge required to accomplish a transaction is rare, i.e., possessed by relatively few individuals. Knowledge intensive industries, such as software development, are highly reliant on an elite and talented innovative core to create their future (e.g., product design team at Apple). Such personnel are not motivated by command and control or purely by financial returns. Open source developers, for example, highly value intellectual stimulation and self-improvement, among other motivating factors (Lakhani and Wolf, 2005). Consequently, additional individual benefits might need to be provided to entice such personnel in a given transaction. Thus, we believe that the TCE model needs to be extended by including transaction benefits (Figure 2). Also, we assert that with modern information systems, and more particularly the Internet, the influence of the aforementioned transaction characteristics is magnified. Indeed, with information systems, it is easier to manage knowledge intensive activities, as knowledge can be codified, captured, manipulated, stored, and communicated. Moreover, information systems can help in the handling of highly modularized transactions, such that the many parties involved in a complex task can still collaborate. Furthermore, information systems can make it easier for a dispersed group of people to collaborate, whether they reside in the same office building or are spread around the globe. Lastly, through information systems, it is possible for employers to get more efficient access to scare resources, that is, employees with sought skills are more easily reachable.
2

Real estate agents speak of location, location, location as the key to success.

1128

Figure 2.

Transaction costs and benefits model

To illustrate, consider the case of a firm in the software business that hires programmers to write code. The firm encounters all the traditional transaction costs (e.g., selecting employees, monitoring their performance, etc.) and major direct costs of paying the programmers. The favored governance structure is a hierarchy with high control mechanisms to motivate employees and coordinate their work. On the other hand, reflect on the situation of another firm that takes the approach of recruiting volunteers to work on writing similar software. In this case, the transaction costs are much lower, but not zero (Demil and Lecocq 2003), and the entrepreneur has few direct costs. However, in order to accomplish the project’s goals, the firm must find a way of creating individual transaction benefits in order to motivate the programmers because they receive no direct financial benefits. We postulate that transaction benefits and costs both influence the choice of governance structure, especially for the many modern firms with an emphasis on knowledge and innovation.

4

MIXING GOVERNANCE STRUCTURES

Each of the aforementioned governance structures, however, is a “pure” type, and as such, rarely uniquely fits a given situation. A combination of these governance structures is called for each organizational transaction a firm needs to execute (Adler 2001). Firms are thus generally using “mixed” governance structures (i.e., the combining of different governance structures) to handle different aspects of their business. Over time, given the characteristics of a transaction and its surrounding organizational context, mixed governance structures may be altered to adjust to specific organizational and individual needs. The search for organizational transaction benefits, combined with the need to provide employees with transaction benefits and to minimize organizational transaction costs, thus results in the mixing governance structures. The organization may operate in transaction cost mode for the bulk of its time, but if it also considers individual transaction benefits, such as when it gives discretion to employees over their time and task assignment, it will favor a mix of governance structures that will better leverage the need to minimize organizational costs and maximize individual benefits. The shift to an electronic network based knowledge intensive and service oriented economy facilitates governance mixing. Indeed, it is required if transaction benefits are to be provided for employees. Universities have long been based on a mix of governance structures, as faculty move between teaching (hierarchy) and research (community).

1129

Consideration of organizational transaction costs, individual transaction benefits, and organizational transaction benefits, and the notion of mixing governance structures lead to a general model, represented in Figure 3.

Figure 3.

Governance mixing relationships

An instance of this general model is presented in Figure 4. The most salient transaction characteristic, in this case, is scarcity of expertise. An appropriate mixed governance would combine hierarchy with community. As to the resulting benefits, we propose that innovation would be the most relevant at the organizational level and creative freedom would be an important one at the individual level. From this instance of the general model, we put forward four propositions.

Figure 4.

Particular Instance of Governance mixing relationships

Knowledge intensive industries, such as in the area of software development, often face the challenge of responding to a lack of talented and knowledgeable resources so as to stay competitive. Such human resources may be motivated by above average financial compensations, but other transaction benefits are typically needed to attract and retain them. Thus, combining governance structures to respond to this transaction characteristic is important. Accordingly, we propose that: P1. Governance mixing to support transaction benefits will be more prevalent in industries where there is a scarcity of expertise (e.g., knowledge intensive industries). Innovation is possibly the only form of competitive advantage, and thus an important organizational benefit, as many cutting edge firms, research and development units, and universities illustrate. When firms need innovation, strong hierarchical control or market discipline may not be the answer (Dyer 1996; Adler 2001). Innovation is possible when a community governance structure can be leveraged, in addition to possibly other governance structures (Adler 2001). We thus propose that: P2. Governance mixing supports greater innovation.

1130

Firms and their employees will use information systems to support alternate governance structures (Glassberg and Merhout, 2007), and, we propose, governance mixing. In particular, electronic networks will be used to enable employees to select when and where they work and with whom they connect, and they will also be used to enable access to electronic resources from any network connection. Thus, we contend that: P3. Information systems promote governance mixing because they support quick mode switching for individual employees and enable the connection of distribution employees. Similarly, and mainly for completeness as others have advanced this proposition, we propose that: P4. Information systems promotes innovation by supporting interactions between distributed knowledge workers with and without a firm. As the preceding propositions and as Figure 3 and Figure 4 suggest, information systems have a critical role to play in establishing transaction costs (Gurbaxani and Whang 1991; Malone, Yates, and Benjamin, 1987), as already recognized, and transaction benefits, as we suggest. Next, through the description of two recently emerged organizations, Google and JBoss, we illustrate the existence of some of the transaction characteristics discussed above, along with the existence of mixed governance structures.

5

GOOGLE

Incorporated in September 1998, Google Inc. operates the leading Internet search engine. As one of Silicon Valley’s hottest companies, it generates revenue primarily by delivering online advertising and has gained great prominence within a few short years. Headquartered in Silicon Valley, Google has offices throughout the Americas, Europe, and Asia Pacific. With legions of Google fans, the company has spawned a variety of products, concepts, and projects, such as Gmail, Google Map, Google Scholar, Google Earth, Google Print, etc. Nowadays it seems that Google is not merely an Internet search engine, rather it has transformed into something of a phenomenon. The trademark “Google” has even become an entry as a verb in the Merriam-Webster dictionary. A knowledge-intensive engineering company, many Google projects span geographically dispersed engineering offices. In pursuit of its mission of “organizing the world's information and making it universally accessible and useful,” Google has been focusing its efforts on managing knowledge and knowledge workers from offices around the globe – a growing team of talented programmers and computer scientists with expertise in a wide range of topics. Through a mixed governance structure, Google has made itself a workplace where knowledge flows freely and ingenuity is valued. First, a lot of Google’s creativity and spontaneity results from the freedom it has granted its engineers. Google’s well-known philosophy of “20 percent time” enables engineers to spend one day a week on personal interests. During the 20 percent of their office hours, they are free to explore and pursue projects which are not necessarily in their job scope, and to come up with innovative new ideas. With the freedom and well-equipped work environment enabling them to be as creative as they want, Google engineers derive job satisfaction from having their research interests highly respected, encouraged, and nurtured. Despite the lack of formal hierarchical control during the “20 percent time,” Google has also generated impressive outcomes by keeping its knowledge workers happy. According to Google's Vice President of Search Products and User Experience, it is estimated that half of new product launches originated from the “20 percent time” (Mayer, 2006). Google News, Google Suggest, AdSense for Content, and Orkut – products which might otherwise have taken an entire project cycle to launch, are some of the outcomes of the “20 percent time.” For example, Orkut, an Internet social network service, is named after a Turkish software engineer who created it during the 20 percent time at Google. Furthermore, Google has a flat organization, where engineers can communicate their ideas for a product or a strategic innovation through effective and efficient feedback loops, rather than moving

1131

them up a hierarchical political system. The organization strives to accommodate each engineer’s interests by giving them great discretion in joining the projects about which they are passionate. The open idea posting page and a company-wide suggestion box allow employees to post ideas, from feedbacks on day-to-day operations to a suggestion for the next killer application. The ideas will be peer-reviewed, and the best ones will get on the R&D agenda. Google has been portrayed by its fans as the ultimate work place for “techno geeks” – a place where recreational amenities and snack rooms are scattered throughout the campus, and where engineers are granted considerable freedom to pursue personal interests and collaborate with global Googlers who share the same passion. Under the mixed governance structure, each of Google’s engineers holds a position in the company’s hierarchy, while they work at their own discretion one day a week and during the other four days they are involved in different project teams, often with membership spanning different countries. In order to keep its competitive edge by retaining its creative engineers, Google constructs and preserves a collaborative and innovative ambience in the hierarchical command-and-order environment, by cultivating a relaxed company culture and emphasizing the fun elements at work – the funky office setup, the tweaking of its brand name, the pets allowed in the office policy, etc. This brief review of some key features of Google illustrates how corporations can blend a command and control hierarchy with the environment of a collaborate and control community. Google provides many individual transaction benefits to attract needed talent and engage them innovatively. The extent of innovation fostered by Google is the firm’s main organizational transaction benefit.

6

JBOSS

JBoss, since 2006 a division of Red Hat, was founded in 2001 and has since evolved into the market leader of the J2EE application server market as well as the professional open source movement (Watson et al. 2005). JBoss has created a profitable portfolio of successful open source products, with the JBoss application server as the lead product. A part of the proliferation of JBoss products can be ascribed to its organizational model that combines traditional software development with the strengths of software development in an open community. Software development is an excellent example of a transaction that frequently emphasizes the previously discussed transaction characteristics. Software development is indeed knowledge intensive work that usually relies on multiple parties that can be located at multiple locations and have specific, and often scarce, skills. Although software development as a transaction has been successfully organized within a hierarchy (traditionally software development process) and within communities (peer-production or bazaar software development process), JBoss manages to combine the strengths of both by organizing its software development process as a mixed form of hierarchy and community. Each governance form on its own exhibits specific benefits. One of the main strengths of the traditional software development process under a hierarchy is the possibility to purposefully coordinate and command the developers according to a broader road map. One of the main advantages of the more chaotic open source development process is the use of the contributions of a broad base of volunteer community members. In JBoss, a small group of core developers works within a traditional hierarchical employment relationship. These core developers guarantee the support, consistency, and accountability of the source code. At the same time JBoss has managed to attract a broad user base that contributes new code, tests new releases, debugs and contributes bug fixes, and provides general feedback about the software product. The users are self-organized into a community and voluntarily help and advance JBoss products. The mix between community and hierarchy governance structures gives the individual employees as well as the organization several transaction benefits. On the individual side, the community model allows the employees to work relatively independently at different physical locations. This individual benefit simultaneously allows JBoss to recruit the most talented developers worldwide who are

1132

already familiar with the product through participation in the community and are able to produce code immediately. The employment contract under the hierarchy model guarantees the employees a reliable income stream that they would not have in a pure community model. On the organizational side, the organization is able to profit from the contributions of a wider participant base than would be possible under a hierarchy governance form. Although each contribution of the users within the community might be small, collectively they significantly influence the innovative and qualitative development of the software. Almost none of the contributions alone would justify an employment contract and still JBoss is able to profit from the diffused knowledge of its customers through incorporating the user community in its development process and ensure, for example, higher turnover rates for bug fixes Concurrently, JBoss ensures the quality and integrity of the source by employing the group of core developers within a traditional command structure hierarchy. JBoss thus merges two governance structures and is able to benefit from the innovative benefits of the community governance structure as well as the coordination and command benefits of the hierarchy governance structure.

7

CONCLUSION

When a new technology is introduced, we often see initially only the obvious consequences, such as replacing an old work habit with the new technology (e.g., email is a substitute for letter writing) and the foreseen theoretical consequences are limited. With time and musing, we start to see deeper patterns. As a result, some fundamental ideas and entrenched theories, when re-examined for the impact of technological change, need elaboration (e.g., Glassberg and Merhout, 2007). Furthermore, a social-based theory that has its origins in a different social milieu might need extending to account for societal, organizational, and cultural changes over time. In this paper, we examined a well-accepted theory, transaction cost economics, to see how it would explain contemporary governance structures. We introduced individual and organizational transaction benefits as a parallel to organizational transaction costs to explain the mixed governance structures we see operating in some firms, particularly those in knowledge intensive industries reliant on scarce human talent. Because information systems, specifically electronic networks, change the way in which people can interact, they open opportunities for fashioning new relationships among employees and between employees and the firm. These new relations create occasions for establishing additional transaction benefits. The firm then faces the problem of how to operate in the dual mode of minimizing transactions costs while maximizing transaction benefits. We suggest, based on observation of some knowledge management firms and insight, that some firms now dynamically mix governance modes so they can use hierarchies to manage transaction costs and communities to drive innovation. Both the firm and its employees learn how to operate in this dual governance setting. As IS scholars, we need to continue to investigate the deeper implications of technological change. Our contributions will be more valuable when we show how to elaborate existing theories (and more importantly develop new theories) compared to taking existing theories and applying them in an IS setting. Such innovation and fundamental improvement needs nourishment and encouragement and should not be judged by the same standards as applying theory to an IS problem if we are to avoid suppressing innovation (Horrobin 1990; Dirk 1999). It is in this spirit that we present an extension of TCE that we believe is innovative. It is, however, the beginning of a new direction and will need much research and elaboration before it can stand on the same podium as TCE, but we should remember that TCE started as an undergraduate’s musing (Coase 1937) on the nature of the firm.

1133

References
Adler, Paul S. (2001). Market, hierarchy, and trust: the knowledge economy and the future of capitalism. Organization Science, 12 (2), 215-234. Alchian, A. and Demsetz, H. (1972). Production, information costs, and economic organization. American Economic Review, 62, 777-795. Argyres, N. and McGahan, A.M. (2002). An interview with Michael Porter. Academy of Management Executive, 16 (2), 43-52. Arrow, K.J. (1974). The limits of organization (Fels lectures on public policy analysis). 1st Edition. Norton, New York. Barzel, Y. (1982). Measurement costs and the organization of markets. Journal of Law and Economics, 25, 27-48. Blomqvist, K., Kyläheiko, K. and Virolainen, V.M. (2002). Filling a gap in traditional transaction cost economics: Towards transaction benefits-based analysis. International Journal of Production Economics, 79 (1), 1-14. Chatterjee, D., Segars, A.H. and Watson, R.T. (2006). Realizing the promise of e-business: developing and leveraging electronic partnering options. California Management Review, 48 (4), 60-83. Coase, R. (1937). The Nature of the Firm. Economica, 4, 386-405. Demil, B. and Lecocq, X. (2004). Neither market nor hierarchy or network: the emerging bazaar governance. Available from http://opensource.mit.edu/papers/. Demsetz, H. (1988). The theory of the firm revisited. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 4, 141-161. Dirk, L. (1999). A measure of originality: The elements of science. Social Studies in Science, 29 (5), 765-776. Dyer, J. H. (1996). Does governance matter? Keiretsu alliances and asset specificity as sources of Japanese competitive advantage, Organization Science, 7(6), 649-666. Geyskens, I., Steenkamp, J. and Kumar, N. (2006). Make, buy, or ally: A transaction cost theory metaanalysis, Academy of Management Journal, 49 (3), 519-543. Ghoshal, S. (2005). Bad management theories are destroying good management practices. Academy of Management Learning & Education, 4 (1), 75-91. Ghoshal, S. and Moran, P. (1996). Bad for practice: A critique of the transaction cost theory. Academy of Management Review, 21 (1), 13-47. Glassberg, B. C. and Merhout, J. W. (2007). Electronic markets hypothesis redux: where are we now?. Communication of the ACM 50(2), 51-55. Gurbaxani, V. and Whang, S. (1991). The impact of information systems on organizations and markets. Communications of the ACM, 34 (1), 59-73. Horrobin, D.F. (1990). The philosophical basis of peer review and the suppression of innovation. Journal of the American Medical Association, 16, 1438-1441. Jensen, M.C. and Meckling, W.H. (1976). Theory of the firm: managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics, 3, 303-360. Klein, B., Crawford, R.G. and Alchian, A.A. (1978). Vertical Integration, Appropriable Rents, and the Competitive Contracting Process. Journal of Law and Economics, 21(2), 297-326. Lakhani, K. and Wolf, R.G. (2005). Why Hackers Do What They Do: Understanding Motivation and Effort in Free/Open Source Software Projects, In: Feller, J., B. Fitzgerald, S. Hissam, K. Lakhani (eds.), Perspectives on Free and Open Source Software, MIT Press, Cambridge. Malone, T.W., Yates, J., and Benjamin, R. I. (1987). Electronic markets and electronic hierarchies, Communications of the ACM, 30(6), 484-497. Mayer, M. (2006). Nine lessons learned about creativity at Google. Available from http://edcorner.stanford.edu/authorMaterialInfo.html?mid=1554. Milgrom, P.R. and Roberts, J. (1992). Economics, organization, and management. Prentice-Hall, Englewood Cliffs, N.J. Ouchi, W.G. (1980). Markets, bureaucracies, and clans. Administrative Science Quarterly, 25 (1), 129-141.

1134

Raymond, E.S. (2001). The cathedral and the bazaar: musings on Linux and Open Source by an accidental revolutionary. O'Reilly, Cambridge, Mass. Rindfleisch, A. and Heide, J.B. (1997). Transaction Cost Analysis: Past, Present, and Future Applications. Journal of Marketing, 61(4), 30-54. Rousseau, D. (1985). Technology in organizations: A constructive review and analytical framework. In Assessing organizational change (Seashore, S.E. and Lawler, E.E., Eds), JAI Press, Greenwich, CT. Sharma, S., V. Sugumaran, and B. Rajagopalan. (2002). A Framework for creating hybrid-open source software communities. Information Systems Journal 12 (1):7-25. Silverman, B.S., Nickerson, J.A. and Freeman, J. (1997). Profitability, transactional alignment, and organizational mortality in the U.S. trucking industry. Strategic Management Journal, 18, 31-52. Simon, H.A. (1957). Models of man: social and rational. Wiley, New York. Stigler, G.J. (1961). The economics of information. Journal of Political Economy, 69 (3), 213-225. Thompson, J.D. (1967). Organizations in action. McGraw-Hill, New York. Uzzi, B. (1996). The sources and consequences of embeddedness for the economic performance of organizations: The network effect. American Sociological Review, 61, 674-698. Watson, R.T., Boudreau, M.-C., Greiner, M., Wynn, D., York, P. and Gul, R. (2005). Governance and global communities. Journal of International Management, 11 (2), 125-142. Watson, R.T., Zinkhan, G.M. and Pitt, L.F. (2004). Object orientation: a tool for enterprise design. California Management Review, 46 (4), 89-110. Watson, R.T., Wynn, D. and Boudreau, M.-C. (2005). JBOSS: The Evolution of Professional Open Source Software. MIS Quarterly Executive, 4(3), 329-341. Wieland, J. (2005). Corporate Governance, Values Management, and Standards: A European Perspective, Business Society, 44, 74-93. Williamson, O.E. (1975). Markets and hierarchies: analysis and antitrust implications. Free Press, New York. ———. (1979). Transaction-Cost Economics: The Governance of Contractual Relations. Journal of Law and Economics, 22(2), 233-261. ———. (1981). The Economics of Organization: The Transaction Cost Approach. The American Journal of Sociology, 87(3), 548-577. ———. (1985). The economic institutions of capitalism: firms, markets, relational contracting. Free Press, New York. ———. (1986). Economic Organization. Firms, Markets and Policy Control. New York University Press, Washington Square, New York. ———. (1993). The economic analysis of institutions and organizations - In general and with respect to country studies. OECD, Paris. ———. (1996). The mechanisms of governance. Oxford University Press, New York. Wilson, J.Q. (1993). The moral sense. Free Press, New York.

1135

Similar Documents

Premium Essay

Valuation of Intellectual Property: Approaches

...creation of Human mind but to know the value or to trade that property we have to “value” them. The three main approaches are Market Approach, Income Approach & Cost Approach. Introduction Business enterprise is comprised of Working Capital, Fixed Assets, Intangible Assets and Intellectual Property. The increasing challenges of corporate world everyone wants to earn competitive advantages over others resulting into more dependence on Intellectual Property . Intangible assets Working Business Fixed Capital Enterprise Assets Intellectual Property According to economic theory, the value of an asset is best determined by the market, in the form of a transaction between two unrelated entities dealing at arm’s length. Unfortunately, intangible assets and IP that will eventually support products seldom benefit from open market conditions, either due to novelty or secrecy factors. In consideration of the growing investments required to develop and market products, there is a growing need for assessing the economic value of such IP as early as possible in the product development cycle. Value assessment is not an accounting operation but rather an attempt to reconcile information pertaining to a given IP or business project, such as development costs, expectation of income, comparative advantages and market data, for the purpose of making better strategic decisions. There are three main approaches used for...

Words: 1278 - Pages: 6

Premium Essay

Issue in Financial Reprotinh

...is useful for making and evaluating decisions about the allocation of scarce resources 5. Measurement of comprehensive income Income Less: Expenses = Profit or loss for the period +/- Items of other comprehensive income =Total comprehensive income for the period 6. Other comprehensive income Changes in asset revaluation surplus, actuarial gains and losses on defined benefit superannuation plans, gains and losses arising from translating the financial statements of a foreign operation, gains and losses on remeasuring available-for-sale financial assets, effective portion of gains and losses on hedging instruments in a cash flow hedge 7. The face of the statement of comprehensive income must include amounts for: -Revenue -Finance costs -Equity accounted share of profit or loss of associates [covered in ACCT6010] -Tax expense -Profit or loss on discontinued operations -Profit or loss for the period -Each component of other comprehensive income, classified by nature -Total comprehensive income 8. Recognition of asset: “Assets" are future economic benefits controlled by the entity as a result of past transactions or other past events. An asset should be recognised in the statement of financial position when and only when: 1)...

Words: 1213 - Pages: 5

Premium Essay

Balance of Advantages of the Uk Joining the Emu and/or Using the Euro as a Functional Currency

...functional currency. Contents Contents 2 1. EXECUTIVE SUMMARY 3 2. INTRODUCTION 3 2.1. HISTORY OF INSOMNIA PLC 3 2.2. SCOPE OF BUSINESS 3 2.3. CURRENT EXPOSURES 4 2.3.1. TRANSACTION EXPOSURE 4 2.3.2. ECONOMIC EXPOSURE 4 2.3.3. TRANSLATION EXPOSURE 4 2.4. HEDGING 5 3. EFFECTS OF UK JOINING EMU ON INSOMNIA PLC 5 3.1. COST SAVINGS ON CROSS-BORDER TRANSACTIONS 5 3.2. STABILITY OF PRICES 6 3.3. PRICE TRANSPARENCY 6 3.4. OTHER EFFECTS 6 4. USING EURO AS A FUNCTIONAL CURRENCY OF INSOMNIA PLC 7 5. CONCLUSION 8 6. BIBLIOGRAPHY 9 1. EXECUTIVE SUMMARY It has been found that UK joining EMU as well as accepting the Euro as a functional currency will bring more benefits to Insomnia plc than staying outside of the Economic and Monetary Union or continuing using Pound Sterling as a functional currency. Both of the choices will decrease the currency exchange rate fluctuation risk which was found to be the most significant to the company. Analysis were based mainly on academic articles, European Central Bank (ECB) publishing’s, and International Accounting Standards (IASs). 2. INTRODUCTION “The Economic and Monetary Union is an agreement between participating European nations to share a single currency, the Euro and a single economic policy with set conditions of fiscal responsibility. There are currently 27 member-states of varying degrees of integration with the EMU” (EU4Journalists) Currently there are 16 member states who...

Words: 3577 - Pages: 15

Premium Essay

Fra Exam Notes

...information asymmetry, act in self interest * debt Stewardship – compliance with delegated authority Agency Cost of equity Perquisite consumption – Manager give themselves more luxury than would seem reasonably from the principals point of view. E.g. corporate jets and huge officers with expensive art Risk aversion – managers and shareholders may prefer different levels of risk when it comes to project selection. Shareholders would generally prefer more risky investment because they are well diversified and know that any loss will be offset by another investment. Managers however are generally not as diverse, if the firm suffers a substantial loss, their salaries may be at risk, or it would be extremely difficult to find another job. Hence managers are usually more reluctant to take risk than the shareholders. Agency cost of debt Claim dilution – The value of existing debtholders’ claims can be diluted by the issue of additional debt of the same or higher priority. Asset substitution – If a firm sells debt for the stated purpose of investing in a low risk project, for example like a building, and subsequently invests in a high risk project, for example mineral exploration, the value of the debt falls while that of the equity rises. Accounting Standards Harmonisation Benefit – For users, consistency in interpretation of financials * For preparers, reduced costs in restating and reconciling reports Disadvantages – culture differences,...

Words: 4023 - Pages: 17

Premium Essay

Management

...the specific definition of an asset? According to the Statement of Financial Accounting Concepts No. 6, Assets are probable future economic benefits obtained or controlled by a particular entity as a result of past transactions or events. The kinds of items that qualify as assets under the definition in paragraph 25 of Concept Statement 6 are also commonly called economic resources. They are the scarce means that are useful for carrying out economic activities, such as consumption, production, and exchange. An asset has three essential characteristics: (a) it embodies a probable future benefit that involves a capacity, singly or in combination with other assets, to contribute directly or indirectly to future net cash inflows, (b) a particular entity can obtain the benefit and control others' access to it, and (c) the transaction or other event giving rise to the entity's right to or control of the benefit has already occurred. The common characteristic possessed by all assets (economic resources) is "service potential" or "future economic benefit," the scarce capacity to provide services or benefits to the entities that use them. In a business enterprise, that service potential or future economic benefit eventually results in net cash inflows to the enterprise. In a not-for-profit organization, that service potential or future economic benefit is used to provide desired or needed goods or services to beneficiaries or other constituents, which may or may not directly result...

Words: 1107 - Pages: 5

Premium Essay

Economics Notes

...Chapter 1 – Reasoning with Economics: Models and Information • Economists base much of our thinking on simplified models of reality that neglect many details o Models that apply to a broad range of situations must be simple, but they can help you think logically no matter what happens in your market. • Why be abstract when you have facts? o Reality is so complex and our mental capacities so limited that we must be selective in what we think about. • Economists are human and they have values and beliefs that might render their objectivity suspect o Positive economics describes and analyzes things as they are (or as objectively as they can be seen) o Normative economics is about how things “ought to be” – it explicitly acknowledges the researcher’s values.  Whatever positive theory may say, an economist’s normative views on prostitution or the drug trade might lead her to recommend that these activities remain illegal. • Rationality o Economics studies the choices people make in the face of constraints that limit their options o Economics studies the allocation of scarce resources among competing goals.  Underlying both definitions is an assumption that people act rationally, with an eye towards attaining objectives they have chosen. o Rationality does not mean that people are computers  People may not perfectly understand their own preferences or do not know how best to overcome the obstacles that stand between them and their goals. o What rationality offers...

Words: 7244 - Pages: 29

Free Essay

Outsourcing

...for improving an organization’s functionality. While outsourcing advantages can reap benefits of improved productivity and lowered costs, the disadvantages must be taken in consideration to reach success. Analyzing the different aspects of: why is outsourcing necessary, what are the potential advantages and disadvantages, and is it cost effective upon a thorough review of the market and costs associated are essential. Outsourcing a Source with Strategic and Effective Techniques The ways in which business decisions take place are increasingly complex, costs are an important part of decisions, especially the make or buy decision that is important in determining if outsourcing of off shoring takes place. The majority of literature focuses on the production cost, but these are not the only costs that need to be considered, less visible, but just as important are the transaction costs, Jacobides and Winter (2005) argue that transaction costs can be just as important as production costs, and are key in the outsourcing decisions, Barney (1991) argues it is used in the way resource allocations is assessed. To consider this it is necessary to look at how transaction cost economics can be applied to business decisions and the way that outsourcing takes place. In order to examine this concept, and the way in which transaction costs are impacting on business will first define the term transaction costs, and the way in which it is impacting on outsourcing decisions, following this the underlying...

Words: 2418 - Pages: 10

Premium Essay

Accounting Concepts, Assumptions, Principles, Elements Key Things to Know Objectives of Financial Reporting: 1. Provide Useful Information to Investors and Creditors for Decision Making (Assume Users Have a “Reasonable

...measurable with sufficient reliability 3. Relevance: makes a difference in the decision 4. Reliability – representationally faithful, verifiable, neutral Accounting Underlying Assumptions - Basis for Generally Accepted Accounting Principles (GAAP) Entity Assumption - each business is its own “accounting” entity. Periodicity Assumption - divide economic activities into time periods for reporting. Going Concern Assumption - the company will remain in business and will carry out existing commitments. Assets will be used to bring future benefit and liabilities will be paid. Monetary Assumption - assume the dollar is stable over time. No adjustments are made for inflation or deflation. Accounting Principles: Historical Cost - Assets...

Words: 1011 - Pages: 5

Premium Essay

Acc34 Ch4Exercisesolutions

...Exercise 4.1 Cash transaction a |Document |Receipt (Copy) | b |Transaction |Cash sale (of 2 top hats) | c |Account |Debit |Credit | | |$ |$ | |Bank |220 | | |Sales | |200 | |GST Clearing | |20 | |Cost of Sales |100 | | |Stock Control | |100 | d |Explanation |The GST is collected from the customer on behalf of...

Words: 853 - Pages: 4

Premium Essay

Managerial Economics

...CHARACTERISTICS OF PURE CAPITALISM Although there are as many economic systems as there are countries, we will discuss the basic elements of pure capitalism. Purely capitalist economies are characterized by exclusive private ownership of productive resources and the use of markets to allocate goods and services. Pure capitalism stands in stark contrast to socialism, which is characterized by partial or total public ownership of productive resources and centralized decision making to allocate resources. Capitalism in its pure form has probably never existed. In all countries characterized as capitalist, government plays an active role in the promotion of overall economic growth and the allocation of goods and services through its considerable control over resources. The reason we examine capitalism in its pure form is essentially twofold. To begin with, most western, developed, economies fundamentally are capitalist, or market, economies. Moreover, and perhaps more important, understanding capitalism in its pure form will better position the analyst to understand deviations and gradations from this “ideal” state. Economies that are characterized by a blend of public and private ownership is known as mixed economies. Most of the discussion in this text will assume that our prototypical firm operates within a purely capitalist market system. Although the complete set of conditions necessary for pure capitalism is not likely to be found in reality, an understanding...

Words: 2270 - Pages: 10

Free Essay

Eco 450 Week 5 Mid Term Exam

...increase in spending for homeland security this year will: Question 2 Following the circular flow of a mixed economy, firms receive a flow of dollars from and send goods and services to: Question 3 In 2008, which country listed below has the highest percentage of government spending relative to GDP? Question 4 Federal government expenditures in the United States account for about: Question 5 A mixed economy is one in which: Question 6 The extra benefit on one more unit of a good or service is its: Question 7 Normative economics is: Question 8 Diamonds are sold by a monopoly firm that maximizes profits. Then it follows that: Question 9 Positive economics: Question 10 If the efficient output of a good is produced each week, then the Question 11 The current competitive market price of fish is $3 per pound. A chemical producer emits effluent into a lake used by a commercial fishing firm. Each ton of chemical output causes a 20-pound reduction in the annual catch of the fishing firm. Assuming that transactions costs are zero and the chemical firm has the legal right to dump effluent into the lake, Question 12 Assuming a product can be manufactured competitively without any externalities at an efficient quantity of 500 units and an efficient price of $150.00 per unit, what efficient quantity-price net subsidy combination would be consistent with a corrective subsidy for a positive externality? Question 13 If a positive externality prevails in the market for...

Words: 3097 - Pages: 13

Premium Essay

Quiz 1

...com/tutorials/economics/4259/eco-550-week-2-quiz-1/ Question 1 1.  When multiple facts about a sample set are known, a(n) _____ heuristic makes the choice on the basis of the first category of facts in which the samples differ. elimination representative recognition availability Question 2 1.  Which of the following products can be sold through mass advertising? A new electrocardiogram machine to be used by medical examiners A mainframe computer installation A new health insurance policy A new brand of baby diapers Question 3 1.  A model of choice in economics starts by assuming that: people try to minimize their losses. people try to maximize their consumption. people try to minimize their costs. people try to maximize their utility. Question 4 1.  _____ is an online venue where businesses and individuals can hedge their uncertainty about whether legislation that affects them will be enacted. The American Civics Exchange Tradesports The Iowa Electronic Markets The Gallup and Roper surveys Question 5 1.  _____ have the ability to recognize constraints and may choose to incur the costs of altering them. Economists Rational people Entrepreneurs Research groups Question 6 1.  Assume that a cargo ship carrying the merchandise of a cloth merchant has been wrecked. Such a setback will be accounted as the merchant’s: sunk cost. deadweight loss. marginal cost. opportunity cost. Question 7 1.  Publicly available data on production costs and box office...

Words: 1457 - Pages: 6

Free Essay

Rmb as Regional Internalization Currency

...following  the  enhanced  economic  and  trade  relationship  between  China  and  Asian  economies,  and  China’s  increasing  importance  in  the  world  economy,  China’s  national  currency,  the  renminbi  (RMB)  will  be  getting  global  from  Asia.  As  regional  internationalization of RMB is double­edged, in order to eliminate the financial risks brought by  this  process,  maximize  the  benefits,  it  is  necessary  for  China  to  consider  the  trade  off  between  costs and benefits of RMB internationalization. RMB internationalization is a dynamic process, in  accordance with the different level of the process, the phased strategy should be implemented, and  the corresponding policies should be pursued too.  Key word: RMB internationalization  Cost and benefit  Roadmap  Introduction  If you travel in the Asian region, you will notice that the Chinese renminbi is appearing more  often in shops and restaurants, driven by the rapid growth in mainland tourist volumes. Will  Chinese Renminbi be the next world currency? Since 2000, RMB internationalization has  attracted great attention from the policymakers and the academics both at home and abroad. There  is sizable RMB circulation in China’s neighboring countries and economies, even RMB can be  fully convertible in some developed countries, some of neighboring countries and economies  treated RMB as a reserve currency. This is a new economic phenomenon for both China and the  world. Because in economic development history...

Words: 5146 - Pages: 21

Free Essay

Cost of Acpital

...rents present in their strategic assets. The firm-specific nature of strategic assets implies that they be financed primarily through equity; other less specific assets should be financed through debt. Firms are likely to suffer increased costs and decreased performance if they do not adopt suitable governance structures in their transactions with potential suppliers of funds. INTRODUCTION The recently developed “resource-based view of the firm” seeks to focus the attention of researchers and managers alike on the unique and hard-to-copy strategic assets of the firm [7, 61]. Firms earn economic rents from these assets when there is an initial level of asymmetry in resource endowments, there is imperfect mobility of these assets, the market for these assets is imperfect, and competitors cannot easily obtain similar assets [2, 6, 7, 20, 24, 48]. Strategic assets provide the firm with a source of steady stream of rents so that it gains a sustained competitive advantage over its rivals. While researchers in this area have a general agreement over the characteristics of strategic assets (albeit adopting slightly different terminology occasionally), more rigor is required to understand how firms translate the value of strategic assets to economic rents. Differences in the perspectives adopted by researchers generate different implications regarding the source of sustained competitive advantage [56]. For instance, Barney [7] suggests that such advantages depend “in a critical way,...

Words: 8274 - Pages: 34

Premium Essay

Feasability

...System Proposal is attached, along with the detailed feasibility study. The highlights of the feasibility analysis are: Technical Feasibility The Students Uniform Information and Inventory System is feasible technically, although there are some risks. (1) Risk regarding familiarity with the system is high * Most of the workers are a little inexperienced with any computer systems. * The management has never used any automated transaction. * Troubleshooting will be hard, because they are all non-IT personnel. (2) Risk regarding familiarity with the technology is medium * The management has never used any automated transaction. * Only few of the workers have knowledge in using a computer. (3) The project size is considered medium risk * The project team consists of 5 members. * The system timeframe will exceed as much as the study will be finished and implemented. * The workers are required to be oriented on this automated business. Economic Feasibility Intangible cost and benefits * Smooth transactions * Improved students’ satisfaction Organizational Feasibility The objective of the system is to access the student uniform information easily, will be able to search, update and evaluate. It can identify whether the uniform is available for release or not and this will aim to locate to whom and when the uniform was released. This project is sponsored by Mrs. Mignonette M. Paulines, IRGO Director, Des.. Mrs. Mignonette is well...

Words: 529 - Pages: 3