Free Essay

Tokugawa Commercialization

In:

Submitted By zhanghonda
Words 7973
Pages 32
Journal of Banking & Finance 25 (2001) 535±554 www.elsevier.com/locate/econbase

Eciency of the Dojima rice futures market in Tokugawa-period Japan
Shigeru Wakita
*
Faculty of Economics, Tokyo Metropolitan University, 1-1 Minami-Osawa, Hachioji-shi, Tokyo, 192-0397 Japan Received 21 May 1998; accepted 20 December 1999

Abstract Co-integration analysis is applied to historical data (1760±1864) from the worldÕs ®rst well-established futures market, in rice at Dojima (in Osaka, Japan). The market shows a strong seasonal character. The summer market was strongly characterized by producersÕ hedging behavior, and may be called a ``commodity-oriented futures market''. On the other hand, the spring and autumn markets in the middle of Tokugawa era were ``®nancial'' markets, characterized by the unbiasedness hypothesis from the theory of rational expectations. Ó 2001 Elsevier Science B.V. All rights reserved. JEL classi®cation: G13; N25 Keywords: Futures market; Market eciency; Cointegration; Osaka

1. Introduction In Tokugawa-period Japan (1603±1867), the rice trading center was Osaka, a city called the ``kitchen for the country''. It was there that clan governments (Han) across the land shipped much of the rice they collected as land tax in lieu of cash. In Dojima, the site of the rice trading activities, a rice futures market
*

Tel.: +81-426-77-2307; fax: +81-426-77-2304. E-mail address: wakita@bcomp.metro-u.ac.jp (S. Wakita).

0378-4266/01/$ - see front matter Ó 2001 Elsevier Science B.V. All rights reserved. PII: S 0 3 7 8 - 4 2 6 6 ( 0 0 ) 0 0 0 8 7 - X

536

S. Wakita / Journal of Banking & Finance 25 (2001) 535±554

continuously operated. Standard textbooks on futures markets (e.g., Due, 1989; Blank et al., 1991) identify the Dojima rice market as ``the worldÕs ®rst well-established futures market'', and the Chicago Commodity Exchange Handbook explicitly states that futures trading originated in Osaka. During the past 50 years, this rice market has been well-investigated in Japan, and in English literature, Schaede (1989) o€ers an excellent description of it. Schaede has also identi®ed the Dojima rice market as a futures market by examining the following criteria: (1) only exchange members can participate in the market; (2) contracts traded are standardized; (3) for each position, a ``good-faith'' money has to be deposited at the clearinghouse; (4) trading is not bilateral, but the clearinghouse enters each transaction as a third party and guarantees the ful®llment of all contracts; (5) the contract runs for a certain trading period and open positions are reassessed daily in accordance with price ¯uctuations; and (6) positions dissolved before the end of the trading period are cleared by cash settlement. Schaede has concluded that the market practices generally satis®ed these criteria. Inspite of careful examination of institutional setup of the market, Schaede, as well as many studies in Japan, have not analyzed it quantitatively because of the lack of reliable data. A recent paper by Ito (1993), however, has used standard techniques of present-day economics, i.e., he demonstrated that the Dojima rice market failed to satisfy the ``unbiasedness'' condition of the rational expectations test. In fact, Ito concluded that the market cannot be deemed to have consisted of participants who were using information e€ectively, and thus it was not ``ecient''; a conclusion based on the fact that (i) the futures price in the market on average failed to predict the spot price accurately, and (ii) the stock of rice at the time of forecasting had a strong correlation with the ex post forecast error. This suggests that, contrary to the high degree of institutional perfection attributed to the market by the existing studies, the market was considerably limited in its ability to process information. On the other hand, when considering the periodÕs patterns of rice production and transportation, many institutional features seem to justify calling trading operations in the market ecient. It is this contradiction that underlies the purpose of the present paper. That is, to undertake an empirical analysis of the market by taking such features into account, and to demonstrate that rational expectations were indeed at work in providing an e€ectively operating futures market. The type of study used here is also meaningful in that, provided the theoretical constraints existing at the time are properly understood, it shows that standard analytical techniques of modern economics can be used for an analysis of economic phenomena taking place several hundred years ago. Moreover, it can elucidate across time and space our understanding of the universal nature of the market mechanism. Compared to the present-day economy, which has a complex institutional setup and is subject to frequent violent shocks, the economy in the Tokugawa

S. Wakita / Journal of Banking & Finance 25 (2001) 535±554

537

era was simpler and changed at a much slower pace; key features allowing us to assume with greater ease how a theoretically conceptualized economic model is supposed to operate. When considering that there exists an extensive time series of quantitative data on the rice trading activities in Dojima, it becomes quite apparent that the market serves as an ideal locus for verifying economic theory, while also o€ering a unique set of data factually substantiating the theory of a futures market with a level of precision that has not been reached by any other set of empirical data. Subsequently, a brief overview of the Dojima rice market is presented in Section 2, being followed in Section 3 with a description of a theoretical seasonal pattern of markets emphasizing particular features of the market. Then, after data are described in Section 4, a test of unbiasedness is conducted in Section 5; one which shows that the market followed a very regular seasonal pattern. Finally, more detailed discussions of the summer market are discussed in Section 6, with conclusions being contained in Section 7. 2. The Osaka rice market In the Tokugawa era, the rice collected as tax by clan governments was shipped to their warehouses in Osaka for sale at the Dojima rice market, and then ultimately for distribution to consumers at large. A clanÕs warehouse issued a promissory note called a ``rice ticket'' promising to deliver a speci®ed amount of warehouse-stocked rice to a particular individual on a speci®ed date. Gradually, as rice tickets began to be transacted as negotiable instruments, an increase occurred in transactions based on purely speculative motives and on transactions in rice tickets for rice not yet shipped to Osaka. Taking note of this reality, the Shogunate government in 1730 issued an ocial permit to the Dojima rice market ratifying rice futures trading operations which had been going on for some time. 1 In addition to tickets for shomai (genuine rice), tickets for choaimai (rice on books) were transacted, with the settlement of deals by the delivery of actual rice being prohibited for choaimai transactions. The exact relationship between the price of shomai, that of choaimai, and the actual market price of rice relative to how ``spot'' and ``futures'' prices in present-day futures market are related to each other is rather complicated and cannot be answered in a straightforward manner. However, given that this paper is mainly concerned

1 Rice trading in the Kitahama market, the predecessor to the Dojima market, is vividly described by Ihara Saikaku (1642±1693), a realistic novelist of the early Tokugawa period, in his Nihon Eitaigura, especially in its ®rst volume, ``Namikaze Shizukani Jintsumaru''. (The Jintsumaru, a sea-going merchant ship, has a calm passage.)

538

S. Wakita / Journal of Banking & Finance 25 (2001) 535±554

with the period when the market remained relatively stable (Miyamoto, 1988), we shall treat transactions in choaimai as similar to those in an ordinary commodity futures market. Trading in rice futures then, unlike trading in the present-day futures market, was conducted in three seasonal markets, i.e., 1. The spring market: January 8±April 28 (called ``winter trading'' along with that in the below autumn market). 2. The summer market: May 7±October 9 (called ``summer trading''). 3. The autumn market: October 17±December 24 (called winter trading). During each seasonal market, the maturation date for rice futures extended only up to the ``closing date'' of that market. In other words, a speculative deal on spring market rice futures was carried out by forecasting the rice price as of April 28 at the latest, and no deal could be made on rice futures to be delivered at harvest time later in the year or in the following year. In this regard, the rice futures market was radically di€erent from contemporary futures markets, where risks in principle can be hedged against an in®nite time horizon through various ®nancial instruments. 2 This particular institutional feature of the Dojima market is nevertheless convenient for identifying the motive behind transactions in each season. That is, the summer market seems to have primarily catered to the need for hedging against the risk of an unsatisfactory harvest; whereas the primary function of the autumn market opening shortly after the harvest may have been to facilitate hedging against the risks of shipping harvested rice to Osaka and determining the quantity that would actually be shipped. The spring market, on the other hand, can reasonably be characterized as the market for transactions of
2 For further details on the institutional aspects of the Dojima rice market, see Shimamoto (1953), Miyamoto (1988, especially Chapter 3), Shade (1989), Susuki, (1940), Suzuki, (1935), and Wakita, (1996). In characterizing the rice market as a ®nancial securities market, Shimamoto attaches importance not to ``futures'', but to ``spot'' rice or Shomai. To be sure, the shomai price and the current price were not necessarily identical, especially toward the end of the Tokugawa era. However, the discrepancy between the two was due to the fact that shomai transactions were carried out as trades of rice tickets, which were often issued in excess of the amount of rice actually stored in the clan governmentsÕ warehouses. It should be noted, moreover, that with the passage of time, the duration between the issuing of rice tickets and the actual delivery of rice on those tickets gradually extended to one year or more, with the result that rice tickets became characterized increasingly as securities issued by feudal lords, or pieces of collateral put up by them to borrow money in the rice market to ®nance their budgets. This helps explain the question which Ito (1988) ®nds puzzling i.e., why the spot and futures prices tended to disagree on the date of maturation of future transactions. This fact also justi®es MiyamotoÕs attempt to establish a link between the rice ticket price, which re¯ected pure speculative transactions and the actual market price. Shimamoto emphasizes this latter fact, characterizing the choaimai market as a ``gambling market'' and the shomai markets as a ``securities market'', and arguing that the futures price was connected far more closely with the actual market price than the modern conventional wisdom would suggest. This was because the futures price was formed independently of the behavior of the clan governments.

S. Wakita / Journal of Banking & Finance 25 (2001) 535±554

539

the rice already stored in Osaka as well as the additional shipments of rice from the colder Hokuriku districts which usually arrived in April. In any case, it is clear that maintaining a market that can handle a diversity of transactions in futures commodities involves considerable costs; and in fact, no such futures market operates today that handles transactions over an extended time horizon like this. The division of the year into three separate trading seasons is therefore considered a rational means of minimizing both the cost of maintaining the futures market and that of transactions. 3. Theoretical seasonal patterns of futures and spot prices Considering the existence of seasonal markets in accordance with the production pattern of rice, we are viewing the Dojima rice market not as a ®nancial securities exchange but instead as a commodity futures market in which clan governments were the suppliers and the Osaka rice merchants were the buyers. With this in mind, a question arises as to what sort of relationship must the spot and futures prices satisfy within a commodity futures market. Two theories exist pertinent to the question: one, advanced by Working (1948) and others, attaches importance to the physical factors of the commodity concerned; while the other, advanced by Keynes (1930) and others, attaches importance to the risk premium involved. The following equation, which incorporates the two theories, describes the theoretically desirable relationship between spot and futures prices: Futures premium ˆ …Futures prices À Spot prices†aSpot prices ˆ Interest rate À Marginal convenience yield À Cost of storing and transporting stocked rice ‡ Risk premiumX …1† If the Dojima rice market had been a pure ®nancial securities exchange incapable of readjusting the demand for and the supply of rice, both the convenience yield and the stock-carrying cost would have been irrelevant such that the risk premium would have had a positive e€ect on the futures premium. The implications of each of the terms in (1) are discussed below: 1. The ``interest rate'' has a positive e€ect on the futures premium. In any market it must usually and theoretically be positive, re¯ecting the opportunity cost when money can be invested in other interest-bearing assets. 2. The ``convenience yield'' represents the extent by which the utility derived from the purchase of actual rice at present exceeds the utility derived from rice futures. In the autumn and spring markets, which opened soon after harvest time, due to a sucient rice stock the current convenience yield must have had a very small e€ect on the futures premium. On the other hand, in

540

S. Wakita / Journal of Banking & Finance 25 (2001) 535±554

the summer market operating during the o€-crop season, this value should have had a large negative e€ect on the futures premium. 3. While the ``cost of storing stocked rice'' would be fairly large in modern times, rice storage during the Tokugawa era was practically free since it was stored in warehouses operated by the ruling samurai class. Accordingly, this makes it dicult to surmise that the opportunity cost of storage found its way explicitly into the rice futures price. 4. In contrast, ``the cost of transporting stocked rice'' which would be small today was quite sizable at the time. It should be remembered, however, that (i) this cost would have a€ected the price evenly across all seasons, and (ii) even more importantly, the maritime transportation of rice to Osaka from various localities entailed great risks, e.g., a shipwreck or long delays due to bad weather; risks that naturally led to substantial risk premiums making maritime shipping an important factor a€ecting the rice trading in Dojima. 3 Miyamoto (1988) showed that the rice stock in Osaka typically reached its peak in November, then declined subsequently. In other words, it is reasonable to surmise that this transportation-related risk presented itself in the autumn market producing a positive e€ect on the futures premium. It was also present in the spring market, since shipments from the colder Hokuriku districts typically arrived in April. 5. The production-related risk premium is the most important factor; especially so in the summer market when the market-supplying clan governments needed to hedge against such risk. The risk premium at this time directly re¯ected the uncertainty of the coming harvest, and produced a negative e€ect on the futures premium. 6. In the autumn and spring markets, where the harvest yield was known and trading was to be cleared before the next harvest, no risk peculiar to rice production could have been present. Thus, the risk premium, if present at all in the autumn and spring markets, could only represent the default risk of borrowers, producing a corresponding positive e€ect on the futures premium seen in an ordinary ®nancial market. In summary, as a commodity futures market, the Dojima rice market would have behaved as follows. In the summer market, which opened while rice was growing, either the convenience yield or the risk premium (re¯ecting clan governmentsÕ willingness to hedge against the uncertainty of the coming harvest) caused the futures premium to be lower; whereas in the autumn and spring markets, which opened during the transportation seasons and were a€ected by both the uncertainty in the amount of rice to be shipped to Osaka and the risk of transportation, the futures premium would be relatively lower.
A well-known story is told of Kinokuniya Bunzaemon, who made fortunes by shipping Kishu (presently Wakayama) oranges to the consumer market of Edo (presently Tokyo) by risking the loss of ships on the way.
3

S. Wakita / Journal of Banking & Finance 25 (2001) 535±554

541

4. Data The stage is now set for an empirical analysis. As mentioned, monthly data are necessary for looking into the seasonal pattern of rice prices, with the respective data source being the ``Otsu Kokurui Sonota Soba-hyo'' (Table of Prices of Grains and Other Commodities in Otsu) provided by Tsuruoka (1972). 4 The prices used are those covering the period prior to the Tenpo era (1830±1843), i.e., the years from 1760 to 1827 when rice prices remained relatively stable (Miyamoto, 1988). Although times exist when trading was suspended by the Shogunate or data are otherwise unavailable, and the data do not include prices at maturity dates, this particular time series is nevertheless quite useful due to covering such an exceptionally long period. Fig. 1 plots the spot and futures prices over the entire period, where it is immediately evident that the shomai and choaimai prices are closely linked; a feature indicating that the e€ects of over-issuing rice tickets, which would cause a di€erence between the two prices, were rather insigni®cant, at least over the period concerned. 5 The e€ect of having no information on the prices at maturity dates prevents conclusively determining whether or not there was arbitrage between actual rice and futures rice (see Ito, 1993). Nonetheless, it seems plausible to assume that there was arbitrage at the time, as supported by Yamagata Banto (1748±1821), a merchant-intellectual of Osaka, in his work Yume no Shiro (1802): ``Rice sold on a rice ticket and choaimai are like day and night... Although the prices of the two are usually at variance with each other, the prices of shomai and choaimai become identical at the end of April, October, and December, and thus they are of the same blood''. 6 Fig. 2 shows monthly average prices, where quite amazingly, the relationship between the two prices changes from one season to the next in the exact, distinct pattern suggested by conventional theory of a commodity futures market.

4 For currently available data on the trading in Dojima, see Miyamoto (1988, p. 364). The data compiled in the ``Yagi Sobacho Tsuiko'', as reproduced in Shimamoto (1970), are best suited for an empirical analysis, and are in fact used by several authors including Ito (1993). However, they are too small in size to be used in identifying a seasonal pattern. 5 Since the time span for hedging against risks is not in®nite in the time series data used here, there is no need for the prices series to be of a random walk nature. In order to determine whether the data have a unit root, a simple DF-test was conducted on all the samples i.e., all monthly data, not monthly averages data, as well as month-on-month annual data, e.g., annual data of January prices etc., but a unit root could not be detected (a coecient ranging from 0.6 or 0.3). The frequent occurrence of missing data, which causes frequent jumps in the samples, tends to make it more likely for a unit root to be detected as is evident from Fig. 1, where the movement of prices is very stationary before the Tenpo era. 6 The quotation is from Nihon Shiso Taikei, 43: Tominaga Nakamoto, Yamagata Banto (Collected Anthologies of Important Philosophical Works in Japan, 43: Tominaga Nakamoto and Yamagata Banto), Iwanami Shoten, p. 398.

542

S. Wakita / Journal of Banking & Finance 25 (2001) 535±554

Fig. 1. Prices of shomai and choaimai.

Because the price should re¯ect all available information on the prices of the commodity at the time of maturity, the movement of the price of a commodity futures must be stable over the transaction period such that futures prices become a means of hedging against the expected risk over the transaction period. The above understanding also asserts that futures and spot prices must move in close linkage with each other during the transaction period, unless of course some factors which do not widen the spread between the two ¯uctuate violently. This cuts a stark contrast to the commodity futures market of today, where (i) ®nancial commodities can be traded in numerous combinations such that a risk involved in the trading of a certain commodity can be hedged against over a virtually in®nite time horizon, and (ii) the transaction period for one commodity can never be identi®ed clearly and independently of the transaction periods of other commodities. The transaction period in the Dojima rice market was rigidly de®ned in a manner that the risk involved in a futures transaction could be hedged against only over the duration of the seasonal market concerned, this being the reason why the relationship between the spot and futures prices followed a ®xed seasonal pattern. Moreover, according to conventional theory of commodity futures market operation, in the summer market where transactions could be made in futures for the new crop of rice to be harvested in the months of September and October, the spot price must have decreased in line with the futures price. Indeed, the trajectory of the spot price (Fig. 2) is clearly in agreement with this theory,

S. Wakita / Journal of Banking & Finance 25 (2001) 535±554

543

Fig. 2. Seasonal ¯uctuation of spot and futures prices.

since it stays at low levels in the summer market, where futures for the forthcoming crops of rice could be transacted, and at high levels in the autumn and spring markets, where such futures could not be transacted. Moreover, the time series plotting of the spot prices in both markets (Fig. 3) suggests that this tendency is robust. However, a question naturally arises as to why arbitrage fails. In this context, it should be remembered that the suppliers in the Tokugawa period, i.e., ruling samurai class, were becoming poor and faced severe liquidity constraints. Thus, it is possible that they needed to sell rice futures immediately after the market opened. The e€ect of a futures market on the movement of spot price has never in my knowledge been demonstrated in a more straightforward manner than can be seen by this simple procedure of plotting monthly changes in the average price.

544

S. Wakita / Journal of Banking & Finance 25 (2001) 535±554

Fig. 3. Average prices in the spring and summer markets.

Such a clear-cut seasonal pattern in the price movement seems to re¯ect the fact that rice production in the Tokugawa era was fairly stationary, being quite similar to the assumptions postulated under any standard theoretical model. Finally, Fig. 4 shows us the futures premium for the entire sample, where even though it is dicult to tell which price remained higher over the entire period, during the great famine of Tenmei the shomai price shoots up to very high levels while the choaimai price remains somewhat lower. In any case, however, if my hypothesis is valid, then it should be possible to establish that the spread between the spot and futures prices presented a clear-cut seasonal pattern in each month of the year and in each seasonal market. To con®rm this, the futures premium was regressed on both a seasonal dummy and that for the great Tenmei famine. Fig. 5 shows the coecient for the seasonal dummy and its standard deviation. Note that the seasonal pattern of the futures premium is stable, with the futures price exceeding the spot price in the spring market. Also, the greatest margin occurs in May, the ®rst month of the summer market, becoming narrower as the settlement time approached. 5. Unbiasedness What underlies the stable futures premium in each month of the year? To answer this question, we must ®rst examine whether futures prices were determined by a rational prediction of the closing prices in each market. If so, it becomes possible to analyze the e€ects on the futures premium. For this purpose, an unbiasedness test is used like Ito (1993), i.e., where the hypothesis of rational expectations is rejected and the same test is carried out again with the exception that monthly data are used. The regression equation is

S. Wakita / Journal of Banking & Finance 25 (2001) 535±554

545

Fig. 4. Futures premium (%) from 1759 to 1859.

546

S. Wakita / Journal of Banking & Finance 25 (2001) 535±554

Fig. 5. Seasonal patterns of futures premium.

log …shomai price as of the closing month† ˆ a ‡ b log …choaimai price† ‡ et Y …2† where et is the error term. Because the closing shomai price is not known, the shomai prices in April, September, and December are used as the closing price of the spring, summer, and autumn markets, respectively. Our objective here is to determine whether the F-test supports the restriction that a ˆ 0 and b ˆ 1, i.e., whether the futures price was equal to the spot price on average. 7 Tests of non-stationary time series are considered as well. First, DF and ADF unit root tests are conducted for spot and futures prices from 1760 to 1827 (Table 1), with Table 2 presenting the results. Next, co-integration tests are considered. Brenner and Kroner (1995) propose the following co-integration test using standard hypothesis testing D log St ˆ a ‡ bD log ftYtÀ1 ‡ d… log ftÀ1YtÀ2 À log StÀ1 † ‡ et Y where D is the di€erence operator, St the shomai price at t, and ftYtÀ1 the choaimai price at t À 1 expiring at time t. The unbiasedness hypothesis in this
7 As is evident from the calendar schedule, the transaction period for rice futures, for instance, was not ®xed, and the estimation errors in each seasonal market were necessarily correlated with each other. Moreover, the pattern of such correlation was not stable. Because of these factors, it is dicult to take into account a possible error structure in the estimation.

Table 1 Test of rational expectation: Unbiasedness
Apr. May Jun. Jul. Aug. Sep. Oct. Nov. Dec.

Jan.

Feb.

Mar.

1760±1827 a

b

R D.W. F(0, 1)

2

)0.116 (0.344) 1.023 (0.083) 0.749 1.693 1.379

)0.056 (0.304) 1.010 (0.073) 0.772 1.712 0.875

)0.732ÃÃÃ (0.163) 1.173ÃÃÃ (0.039) 0.939 1.729 13.879ÃÃÃ )0.085 (0.128) 1.020 (0.031) 0.950 2.574 0.355 0.155 (0.423) 0.960 (0.104) 0.594 1.510 0.166 0.188 (0.279) 0.953 (0.069) 0.769 1.619 0.261 0.278 (0.355) 0.933 (0.086) 0.701 1.555 0.318 )0.068 (0.239) 1.011 (0.058) 0.834 1.883 3.388ÃÃ

1.146ÃÃ (0.446) 0.717ÃÃÃ (0.110) 0.424 1.648 3.295ÃÃ

1.031ÃÃ (0.465) 0.742ÃÃ (0.115) 0.405 1.517 2.751Ã

)0.348ÃÃÃ (0.121) 1.087ÃÃÃ (0.030) 0.958 1.499 4.332ÃÃ

)0.209ÃÃ (0.092) 1.046ÃÃ (0.022) 0.975 1.054 19.829ÃÃÃ

1830±1864 a

b

R D.W. F(0, 1)

2

)0.478 (0.486) 1.127 (0.109) 0.829 1.028 6.049ÃÃÃ

)0.608 (0.359) 1.154 (0.080) 0.896 0.985 9.716ÃÃÃ

)0.744ÃÃ (0.344) 1.182 (0.077) 0.904 1.021 10.088ÃÃÃ )0.664 (0.663) 1.188 (0.153) 0.711 1.847 9.539ÃÃÃ )1.054 (0.530) 1.287 (0.123) 0.812 1.190 23.933ÃÃÃ )1.029 (0.628) 1.281 (0.146) 0.753 1.330 18.285ÃÃÃ )0.551 (0.446) 1.161 (0.103) 0.835 1.314 17.377ÃÃÃ )0.832 (0.301) 1.216 (0.069) 0.926 1.065 25.366ÃÃÃ

)0.937ÃÃÃ (0.283) 1.224 (0.063) 0.937 1.127 15.548ÃÃÃ

)0.261 (0.363) 1.081 (0.081) 0.876 1.881 8.776ÃÃÃ

)0.280 (0.202) 1.073 (0.045) 0.958 2.122 7.271ÃÃÃ

)0.361 (0.153) 1.090 (0.034) 0.976 2.028 11.814ÃÃÃ

1760±1864 a

b

S. Wakita / Journal of Banking & Finance 25 (2001) 535±554

R D.W. F(0, 1)

2

)0.752 (0.229) 1.180 (0.054) 0.867 1.424 6.143ÃÃÃ

)0.681 (0.185) 1.163 (0.043) 0.899 1.630 7.926ÃÃÃ

)0.891 (0.122) 1.213 (0.029) 0.955 1.417 28.881ÃÃÃ

)0.615 (0.106) 1.149 (0.025) 0.962 1.779 22.149ÃÃÃ

)0.592 (0.327) 1.155 (0.079) 0.724 1.728 5.325ÃÃÃ

)1.062 (0.327) 1.269 (0.079) 0.748 1.423 9.858ÃÃÃ

)1.365 (0.311) 1.344 (0.075) 0.792 1.370 16.373ÃÃÃ

)0.907 (0.210) 1.230 (0.051) 0.876 1.434 17.378ÃÃÃ

)0.928 (0.109) 1.233 (0.026) 0.963 1.145 55.423ÃÃÃ

)0.492 (0.200) 1.124 (0.047) 0.883 1.606 7.527ÃÃÃ

)0.454 (0.116) 1.107 (0.027) 0.950 1.940 7.745ÃÃÃ

)0.475 (0.063) 1.112 (0.015) 0.985 1.665 28.258ÃÃÃ

***

**

Signi®cant at 1% level. Signi®cant at 5% level. * Signi®cant at 10% level. 547

548

S. Wakita / Journal of Banking & Finance 25 (2001) 535±554

Table 2 Tests for unit roota SPOT N Jan. Feb. Mar. Apr. May Jun. Jul. Aug. Sep. Oct. Nov. Dec. a FWD ADF(1) )3.99 )3.95 )5.47 )5.41 )4.46 )4.40 )4.08 )4.09 )5.48 )5.84 )5.25 )5.45 )4.91 )5.16 )4.50 )4.75 )4.42 )4.67 )3.51 )3.57 )4.91 )4.87 )5.10 )5.08 DF )4.74 )4.69 )4.66 )4.62 )5.73 )5.67 )5.66 )5.69 )5.36 )5.65 )5.71 )5.87 )5.12 )5.27 )5.21 )5.33 )5.18 )5.33 )5.17 )5.20 )5.70 )5.65 )5.67 )5.63 ADF(1) )4.07 )4.02 )5.44 )5.38 )4.54 )4.48 )3.80 )3.84 )5.61 )6.04 )4.97 )5.17 )5.09 )5.35 )4.66 )4.84 )4.67 )4.88 )3.88 )3.92 )4.78 )4.71 )4.89 )4.85

DF )4.72 )4.68 )4.34 )4.30 )5.62 )5.57 )5.94 )5.94 )5.48 )5.75 )5.45 )5.59 )4.99 )5.15 )4.70 )4.86 )5.02 )5.21 )4.78 )4.83 )5.47 )5.43 )5.65 )5.64

5% Critical Value ()2.92) ()3.50) ()2.91) ()3.48) ()2.91) ()3.48) ()2.91) ()3.49) ()2.91) ()3.49) ()2.91) ()3.48) ()2.91) ()3.48) ()2.91) ()3.48) ()2.91) ()3.49) ()2.92) ()3.50) ()2.91) ()3.48) ()2.91) ()3.49)

I I,T I I,T I I,T I I,T I I,T I I,T I I,T I I,T I I,T I I,T I I,T I I,T

52 52 60 60 62 62 56 56 58 58 65 65 61 61 61 61 58 58 50 50 62 62 58 58

Period ˆ 1760±1827. I: Intercept, T: Trend, N: Number of observations.

regression is satis®ed if …aY bY c† ˆ …0Y 1Y 1†. Table 3 gives the results, where the data do not exhibit non-stationarity and are similar to test results using regression (2). Furthermore, a simple test using (2) can utilize the data in the presence of missing data, and therefore I will discuss the result derived from this test using (2). As in Ito (1993), the test generally entails a joint hypothesis, risk-neutrality, and rational expectations. Although it should also take into account the interest rate and cost of stock maintenance, lack of such data prevents using these variables; and hence, the test should be regarded as dealing with a special case in which both variables are set to 0. For these reasons, a rejection of the unbiasedness hypothesis does not necessarily mean that the rational expectations hypothesis is rejected. As shown in Table 1 during the period from 1760 to 1827, the unbiasedness hypothesis cannot be rejected for six months of the year, i.e., January, February, April, July, August, and October. It is, however, rejected in September and December, although the fact that the constant term assumes signi®cantly large values and the value of b is close to 0 suggests that the excluded e€ect of the interest rate can be signi®cant in

Table 3 Error correction model of unbiasednessa Mar. 58 0.965 1.807 )0.006 (0.005) 1.042 (0.028) 0.710 (0.136) 3.242Ã 2.296 12.171ÃÃ 7.893ÃÃ 3.797Ã 1.328 (0.127) 0.446 (0.127) 0.585 (0.107) 0.638 (0.133) 0.796 (0.127) 1.503 1.022 (0.032) 1.148 (0.041) 1.029 (0.033) 1.128 (0.087) 1.038 (0.075) 0.998 (0.035) 0.750 (0.141) 1.169 0.000 (0.005) 0.010 (0.007) 0.008 (0.005) 0.014 (0.012) 0.013 (0.012) 0.000 (0.004) 0.005 (0.008) 0.911 (0.055) 0.852 (0.189) 1.165 48 0.958 1.518 54 0.951 2.435 64 0.944 1.998 56 0.818 2.152 56 0.823 2.094 50 0.953 1.770 40 0.879 1.917 Apr. May Jun. Jul. Aug. Sep. Oct. Nov. 59 0.951 2.002 )0.26 (0.007) 0.981 (0.029) 0.734 (0.127) 20.410ÃÃ Dec. 52 0.985 1.831 )0.12 (0.004) 0.988 (0.019) 0.624 (0.117) 22.164ÃÃ

Jan.

Feb.

Observations 2 R D.W.

43 0.965 1.473

55 0.944 1.596

a

)0.008 (0.005)

)0.009 (0.006)

b

0.981 (0.035)

0.976 (0.039)

d

0.843 (0.091)

0.715 (0.175)

F(0, 1, 1)

2.713

2.936Ã

a

S. Wakita / Journal of Banking & Finance 25 (2001) 535±554

*

Period ˆ 1760±1827. Signi®cant at 10% level. ** Signi®cant at 5% level.

549

550

S. Wakita / Journal of Banking & Finance 25 (2001) 535±554

these months. In other words, given the fact that the unbiasedness hypothesis is found to have held for six months of the year, and given also the incompleteness of the data for some of the remaining months in which the hypothesis is found to be statistically rejected, the evidence derived by the test is not strong enough to deny unbiasedness. ItoÕs rejection of the unbiasedness hypothesis is probably due to pooling of data over all the seasonal markets, and my analysis seems to suggest that his conclusion was based on large prediction errors for May and June. Despite inadequacy in the data used, because the unbiasedness hypothesis could not be rejected for six months of the year, and because b assumed a value quite close to unity even in the remaining months (except for May and June), such features could very well justify that rational expectations were at work in the Dojima rice market. The spring and autumn markets assuredly appear to represent pure ``securities exchange markets''. For one thing, they were open in the months when transactions could be carried out without giving much consideration to the forthcoming production. And, more importantly, the closing date for each market was speci®ed so that transactions in futures for delivery after the harvest were not possible. In other words, the spring and autumn markets lacked the important functions of a commodity futures market. One factor that may still characterize these markets as commodity futures markets is the risk involved in the transaction of rice, as previously pointed out. In theory, this factor should have the e€ect of widening the futures premium in a commodity futures markets; whereas in reality, the e€ect of this factor adds up to a positive value (Fig. 5) indicating that these markets were not equipped with important attributes of commodity markets. Regarding the rejection of the unbiasedness hypothesis for May and June, this might be attributed to a possibility that the futures market in these months was strongly a€ected by the suppliersÕ willingness to hedge against the uncertainty in the coming harvest and by the convenience yield of rice, which will be examined in the next section. 6. The summer market It seems worthwhile to look more closely into the factors responsible for the larger futures premium as well as the rejection of the unbiasedness hypothesis in May and June. It does not stand to reason that the market participants became irrational only during May and June, being more plausible to assume that the futures premium widened in May and June on a regular basis due to the systematic e€ect of a particular factor. This brings us back to the four factors in Eq. (1). Given the fact that the futures premium widened only during the summer market, where the spot price

S. Wakita / Journal of Banking & Finance 25 (2001) 535±554

551

remained higher than the futures price, two of the four factors, i.e., the interest rate and the costs of storing and transporting the stock of rice, may safely be removed from consideration. The two remaining factors are the producers' willingness to hedge against risks, as emphasized by Keynes (1930), and the convenience yield of actual rice, as emphasized by Working (1948). The futures premium itself can be explained by either theory, but it is important to note that the absolute levels of both the spot and futures prices remained low in the summer market (Fig. 2). Put brie¯y, KeynesÕs theory tries to explain a growing premium primarily by the emergence of an excess supply caused by the selling of futures by suppliers; whereas in contrast, WorkingÕs theory is characterized by its emphasis on the emergence of an excess demand caused by an increase in the ``convenience yield'' as the primary factor responsible for the wide premium. Given the fact that both the spot and futures prices remained low in the summer market, it is possible to assume that the premium widened not because of an increase in the ``convenience yield'' as suggested by Ito (1993) within the framework of Fama and French (1988), but rather because of ``excess supply'' emphasized by Keynes. 8 In fact, it seems reasonable to regard the Dojima rice market as an institution that catered primarily to enhancing the ``convenience yield'' for the sake of city dwellers, rather than one designed to facilitate smooth cashing of the rice collected by the ruling samurai class as land tax. Admittedly, as shown in Figs. 1 and 3, during extraordinary times such as the period of the Great Tenmei Famine, the spot price soared more rapidly than the future price such that a large premium occurred. On the whole, however, it seems appropriate to regard the summer market as a commodity futures market where producers could hedge against risk. 7. Conclusions It has been shown that the Dojima rice market was an economically rational institution where the movement of rice price followed a clear-cut seasonal pattern. Major ®ndings are summarized as follows: 1. During the period under study, the movement of the price of choaimai (i.e., the price of rice futures) and that of the price of a rice ticket (i.e., a certi®cate for actual rice) or the price of shomai were interlocked with each other.
8 Ito (1993) refutes KeynesÕs explanation as irrelevant by referring to the fact that the futures premium was positive on average, and by interpreting this as pointing to the tendency for the futures price to bring down the spot price. There is nothing strange about this conclusion, because ItoÕs test is based on the data pooled across all seasonal markets, two-thirds of which pertained to the spring and autumn markets, where the producersÕ willingness to hedge against risks was totally irrelevant.

552

S. Wakita / Journal of Banking & Finance 25 (2001) 535±554

2. In the summer market, where transactions in futures for the forthcoming crop of rice were possible, both prices remained low. On the other hand, in the spring and autumn markets, where such transactions were impossible, both prices stayed high. 3. The spring and autumn markets were characterized by unbiasedness in the sense of rational expectations, suggesting that the factors peculiar to a commodity futures market did not signi®cantly a€ect the futures premium. 4. The futures premium in the summer market increased on a regular basis; a phenomenon that is not ascribed to an increase in the convenience yield of actual rice, but rather to the producers' risk-hedging behavior. Basically, the summer market was strongly characterized as a commodity futures market, while the spring and autumn markets were not. The institutional setup of the market was such that transactions in spot rice took the form of transactions in ``rice tickets'' as in transactions in securities. Given the fact that these securities transactions were linked with futures transactions during the spring and autumn markets, it is reasonable to consider these markets as securities futures markets; in fact, this institutional feature allows us to aptly call the Dojima rice market the worldÕs oldest securities futures market. Some words must be said about an important question stemming from the above assertion; i.e., should these securities be characterized as certi®cates for a real commodity, or rather as ®nancial securities? In other words, should the Dojima rice markets be characterized as a commodity futures market or as a ®nancial futures market? This question has been discussed repeatedly for years. My own position is to consider it for the most part (summer market and classi®cation into three seasonal markets) as a commodity futures market heavily in¯uenced by the pattern of rice production. However, if one focuses on the individual spring or autumn market alone, both markets are characterized as ®nancial markets. Taken together then, the Dojima rice market functioned both as a single goods commodity futures market and ®nancial futures market. It should be remembered, though, that the economic system of that era pivoted around what might be called the ``rice standard'', and as such, might therefore be described far more accurately than any present-day economy by simply using an abstract, one-sector optimal growth model. If the 18th century Japanese economy is reappraised from the standpoint of such a model, it is possible to regard the stock of rice and the production pattern as the major determinants of the real interest rate. Accordingly, it may not be far-fetched to say the koku (5.119 US bushels), the unit by which the stipend of a samurai was calculated, was actually the unit for expressing nominal wages. The procedure used for analyzing the Dojima rice markets is qualitatively di€erent from that justi®able for analyzing a futures market of today, which is not only small compared with the size of the economy as a whole, but is also complemented by a multitude of well-developed ®nancial markets. Today, analyzing the futures market with a partial equilibrium methodology, which

S. Wakita / Journal of Banking & Finance 25 (2001) 535±554

553

Fig. 6. Impact of the government order of 1762 on the futures premium. Note: In December 1761 the Shogunate issued a government order to levy a tax named Goyokir on rich merchants in Osaka in order to purchase rice.

uses as given the interest rate determined in the extensive ®nancial markets, may well be justi®ed. In contrast, it seems quite dicult to determine in a straightforward manner whether the Dojima rice market was a ®nancial securities exchange or a commodity futures market. As a matter of fact, the ShogunateÕs policies for rice price regulation, such as its ``Order on Purchased Rice'', often had the e€ect of causing much strain not simply on the rice market but also on the money market in general. For example, a sudden increase in the futures premium caused by the 1761 order (Fig. 6). An inquiry into this last aspect, which will require a more sophisticated analysis, is left as a challenging task for future research. Acknowledgements The author would like to thank Masahiro Kawai, Naoto Kunitomo, Satoshi Nakanishi, Jun Suzuki, seminar participants at the Japan statistical Institute, and two anonymous referees for their helpful comments and suggestions.

References
Blank, S.C., Colin, A.C., Brian, H.S., 1991. Futures and Option Markets. Prentice-Hall, Englewood Cli€s, NJ. Brenner, R.J., Kroner, K.F., 1995. Arbitrage, co-integration, and testing the unbiasedness hypothesis in ®nancial markets. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 30 (1), 23±42.

554

S. Wakita / Journal of Banking & Finance 25 (2001) 535±554

Due, D., 1989. Futures Markets. Prentice-Hall, Englewood Cli€s, NJ. Fama, E.F., French, R.K., 1988. Business cycles and the behavior of metal prices. The Journal of Finance XLII, 1075±1093. Ito, T., 1993. 18-Seiki Dojima no kome sakimono shijo no kouritsusei ni tsuite (On the eciency of the rice futures market of Dojima in the 18th century). Keizai Kenkyu 44 (4), 339±350. Keynes, J.M., 1930. A Treatise on Money. Macmillan, London. Schaede, U., 1989. Forwards and futures in Tokugawa-period Japan. Journal of Banking and Finance 13, 487±513. Shimamoto, T., 1953. Tokugawa Jidai no Shoken Shijo no Kenkyu (A Study in the Securities Markets in the Tokugawa Period). Sangyo-Keizaisha. Shimamoto T. (Ed.), 1970. Dojima Kome-kaisho Bunkenshu (Collected Documents of The Dojima rice market). Tokoro Shoten. Susuki, S., 1940. Dojima Kome Shijo-shi (A history of The Dojima rice market). Nihon Hyo-ronsha. Suzuki, N., 1935. Osaka ni okeru Bakumatsu Beika Hendo-shi (A History of the Fluctuations of Rice Price in Osaka toward the End of the Tokugawa Period). Shikai Shobo (a reprint edition published in 1977 by Kokusho Kankoukai). Tsuruoka, M., 1972. Kinsei Beikoku Torihiki Shijo to shiteno Otsu (Otsu as a Rice and Grain Markets in the Pre-Modern Era). Shiryokan Kenkyu Kiyo, No. 5. Miyamoto, M., 1988. Kinsei Nihon no Shijo Keizai (The Market Economy of Pre-Modern Japan). Yuuhikaku. Wakita, S., 1996. Kinnsei Osaka Dojima kome sakimono sizyou ni okeru gouriteki kitai no Serest (The rational expectations in the rice futures market of Osaka, in the 18th century). Keizai Kenkyu 47 (3), 238±247. Working, H., 1948. Theory of the inverse carrying charge in futures markets. Journal of Farm Economics 30, 1±28.

Similar Documents

Free Essay

Mike

...Japan was first published in 1932 and used in U.S. college classrooms into the 1980s. In it, he described the Tokugawa period (1603-1868) as an era of oppressive “feudal” rule. In this view, hierarchical divisions between samurai, peasant, artisan, and merchant were strictly maintained. Sansom described a system in which swaggering samurai used their swords to cut down commoners. Miserable peasants barely eked out a living, and urban merchants were scorned as unethical profiteers. According to Sansom, change was loathed. The government kept the rest of the world out, denying “themselves all the gifts which the West then had to offer.” This move, said Sansom, “arrested the cultural development of Japan” (Sansom 1932, 455, 457). Scholars today largely dismiss this view. Yet it remains pervasive. Films and manga comics glorify samurai bravado. But they ignore much else about the period. Thus, even the well-informed often are surprised when they read more recent histories of the period. Such newer works describe the political system as a rational “integral bureaucracy.” This system was “not merely a samurai institution.” Rather, it depended on non-elite “commercial agents and activities” (Totman 1981, p. 133). Newer histories call the era “a time of extraordinary social growth and change. In terms of population and production, urbanization and commercialization, and societal sophistication and elaboration, the century was one of unparalleled development.” ...

Words: 293 - Pages: 2

Free Essay

Demographic

...Course: Date: Christianity in the Tokugawa Period Teather, Rhiannon A. The Palme of Christian Fortitude: Japan’s martyrs in seventeenth-century records. Bristol University. 6.3 (2014): n.p. Web. 3 April 2016.Teather highlights key reasons that informed Tokugawa’s persecution of Kirishtans (Roman Catholic Christians) during his reign. The article goes further to show the wrong reception that western Christian missionaries were received with described as cold and filled with intimidation. Munson, kabuki. The opening, closing and re-opening of Japan? Japanese foreign relation before during and after the Takugawa Shonjugate (1600-1868). Rondolph-Macon college. (2013): n.p. Web. 3 April 2016. Kibuki discusses the state of Christianity in Japan after Portuguese missionary’s arrival. It explains Japans understanding of missionaries and the adoption of a “closed country” ideology by Takugawa’s leadership. Sadler, Leon. Takugawa Ieyasu Shogun: “The old Badger.” makers of history. 5.5 (1977): 723-760. Web. 3 April 2016. Sadler highlights Tokugawa’s leadership perspectives before the arrival of missionaries, during their arrival and later discusses the measures that he took to prevent the spread of Christianity. Sadler further addresses Takugawa’s stature as a military figure and outlines the reasons that led him to accept persecution as a mode of punishment for Kirishitans and rebels. Reischauer, Ochoa. “A cautious view of Tokugawa.” Hail Japanese history. 11(1977): 11-12...

Words: 614 - Pages: 3

Premium Essay

Who Was Responsible For The Meiji Restoration

...The two actors that was responsible for the major achievements of the Meiji Restoration were Hisamitsu of Satsuma domain and Kido Takayoshi of Choshu domain. The two were both daimyos, the great lords ofthe Shogun. In order to overthrow Tokugawa Shogunate, Hisamitsu and Takayoshi joined together to form an alliance because they wanted to Emperor Komei to be in charge. The reason behind all this was because they believed that Komei was able to deal with foreign threats. They did not want to suffer like China did after the Opium Wars, therefore they felt like it was important to have a strong Emperor to defend them from foreign threats, especially the Western imperial power. However, due to the fact that the Emperor died so early, his son took over the throne....

Words: 513 - Pages: 3

Premium Essay

Shōgun Chapter Summary

...Reminiscent of 1600 historical fiction books, Shōgun begins a few months before the Battle of Sekigahara. A Dutch ship come ashore an island and they’re not really sure where they are. The interesting thing about this book is that you see two perspectives and the characters are completely different: an English captain of a Dutch ship John “あんじん”(Pilot) Blackthorn and the rising daimyo, Toranaga Yoshi. An exciting scene happened eight chapters into the book. Another daimyo from another part of the country wants to speak with Blackthorne and sends someone to Toranaga palace to request him. On their way to meet the daimyo, there’s a storm while they’re still four or five hours away from shore. The sailors, first of which is a Portuguese pilot...

Words: 336 - Pages: 2

Premium Essay

Unit 3 Terms

...1. Absolute Monarch-form of government where the monarch (usually a king or queen) has absolute power; monarch has unrestricted political power over the sovereign state and it’s people; usually born into power 2. Age of Reason-18th century movement that followed after the mysticism, religion, and superstition of the Middle Ages 3. Agrarian-cultivated land; person who advocates a redistribution of landed property, especially as part of a social movement 4. Akbar The Great (Mughal India)-Mughal emperor from 1556-death; extended power over most of India Continent; united Muslim and Hindu peoples with his policy of religious cooperation 5. Atheists-person who lacks the belief in the existence in God’s or a God 6. Batavia, Indonesia-Fort established in 1619 as headquarters of Dutch East India Company operations in Indonesia; today the city of Jakarta. 7. Calvin, John-1509-1564. French theologian. Developed the Christian theology known as Calvinism - believed in predestination and a strict sense of morality. Attracted Protestant followers with his teachings. 8. Cash Crop-readily salable crop that is grown and gathered for the market (vegetables, cotton, tobacco) 9. Circumnavigation- travel all the way around the Earth 10. Colonization-physical process whereby the colonizer takes over another place, putting its own government in charge and either moving its own people into the place or bringing in indentured outsiders to gain control of the people...

Words: 2104 - Pages: 9

Premium Essay

Tokugawa Ieyasu Research Paper

...Tokugawa Ieyasu, the man responsible for the longest shongunate in Japan’s history, the Tokugawa shongunate. A man with such an accomplishment would only be talked from generation to generation as an example of a leader that drastically change Japans’ traditions and history. Ieyasu was one of three founders of the unified Japan, along side his former, Lord Oda Nobuga and Toyotomi Hideyoshi. Ieyasu achieved what most of his previous allies did not, a military regime so powerful and capable of uplifting Japan’s national spirit and traditions after the civil unrest and constant wars that once flew over this country. There is no doubt that Tokugawa’s regime was responsible for social change in Japanese society towards a medieval ruling. Junnosuke...

Words: 1250 - Pages: 5

Premium Essay

Tokugawa Religion: The Most Successful Eras In Japanese History

...Tokugawa Religion The period between 1603 and 1868 presented one of the most remarkable eras of the Japanese history. This period is referred to as Tokugawa Japan. The era is mostly characterized with the widespread peace that spurned a period of two and a half centuries as well as heightened technological and economic growth. The period is also known for its strong political formation as well as a cultural domination that was supported by various factors. One of the elements that provided a strong support for the period was the religious structure practiced by the communities during the era. It is important to note that religion is also an important consideration when looking at the elements that resulted in Tokugawa. The prominent religious beliefs...

Words: 1260 - Pages: 6

Free Essay

How Alternate Attendance Brought the Rise and Fall of the Tokugawa Period

...How Alternate Attendance Brought the Rise and Fall of the Tokugawa Period The turn of the seventeenth century ushered in a new era in Japanese history when the emperor of Japan appointed Tokugawa Iesyasu to shogun. To ensure that his family would retain this power, Tokugawa implemented measures to prevent the overthrow of his shogunate. One of these measures was sankin kotai, or alternate attendance, which assisted in perpetuating his family’s power for two-hundred fifty years. This system would also contribute to the demise of Tokugawa dominance as well as preparing Japan for the future. The system of alternate attendance required the daimyo from each han to journey to Edo to meet with the shogun every two years. Tokugawa initiated this system to keep an eye on the daimyos and keep them from planning and preparing for an overthrow of his power. To ensure that the daimyos would come to Edo, he commanded that the wives and kids of each daimyo must reside in Edo. Tokugawa used his power to control when each daimyo would have to arrive in Edo to make sure that two of them would not meet up on the way. The daimyo’s procession to Edo was a very elaborate affair with hundreds of samurai and personal attendants accompanying him to flaunt his wealth. These grand processions would show that the daimyo have great respect for Tokugawa and they would commonly bring gifts such as horses or swords. The alternate attendance system also established Edo as the political center of Japan...

Words: 776 - Pages: 4

Premium Essay

Naruto

...“A War Set To Win” I believe it takes a refined and experienced leader to tell a great speech. In this scene, a shinobi (Ninja) from the village hidden in the sands shows many characteristics that I personally believe make him a great leader. His speech in the scene was given among the shinobi alliance, which is all the ninja in the world who want to save the world against the Akatsuki. The speech takes place before the war is about to set off against the leaders of the Akatsuki leaders, Obito Uchiha and Kabuto Yakaushi. It may not seem like it’s such a war, but the two enemies have the power to summon any ninja that has died. The reason the enemies have brought up the war is to acquire the last tailed beast which is Naruto. Naruto’s power is very important because he contains the nine tails Chakara, which has the ability to destroy the world or put all shinobi under an evil spell called the infinite Tsukuyomi. Gaara plans through his speech to motivate the shinobi alliance to protect his friend Naruto from being killed like he once was by the enemies. Gaara feels the same pain as Naruto does because Gaara also had a tailed beast inside of him (which was the one tailed raccoon.) The only reason Gaara has not died was because Naruto Saved him by using a forbidden technique to restore all the life back into him. Gaara views Naruto as the hero who saved him and will do anything to save him. I believe the speech couldn’t have been as great if it was told by another character....

Words: 1893 - Pages: 8

Premium Essay

Ap World History Dbq Essay

...Japan went through a period of national isolation from the outside world (the “sakoku” period) during the late 1600s. The Tokugawa rulers wanted cultural particularism and they could achieve this by having no contacts abroad, so that Japan could engage in introspection. During the Tokugawa period, knowledge of other countries was rather restricted, but toward the end of this period there were few Japanese who speculated where Japan stood in relation to the West. The general population, however, was ignorant to the significance of other better nations existing and expressed little interest concerning the West. Hirata Atsutane, for example, thought he was certain of Japan’s superiority because of the fact that the sun first shines on Japan each...

Words: 1495 - Pages: 6

Premium Essay

Feudalism to Modernity: Japan's Transition

...Question: What steps did Japan take to reform its system of feudalism to a more modern form of government? The 18th through 19th century was truly an imperialistic era orchestrated by military superiority by the West. In the interest of avoiding battles they undoubtedly would have lost, East Asian nations signed lopsided treaties that benefited the West. Not only did the treaties open East Asian ports for trade, a demand the West insisted on, but in some cases they included land cessions to the West. The Japanese, having witnessed the demise of the once great Qing Dynasty, were determined to avoid the same destructive folly in their homeland. Japan embarked on a thorough introspection and restructuring that resulted in a modern form of government. Japan was in a new era and they would soon become East Asia’s greatest power. The Shogunate unintentionally sparked the beginning of the restoration period in Japan when he reversed the nation’s long standing sakoku—closed door policy. Many of the samurai and nobles thought the Shogun was showing weakness when he conceded to America’s demands and signed an unequal treaty favoring the West. The first step towards reform began when Japanese troops seized the Imperial Palace and convinced the young Emperor that the Shogun must be overthrown in order to usher in a new imperial era of leadership in Japan. This led to the Boshin War which was a civil war led by imperial forces to uproot the Shogun and his supporters. The Shogun submitted...

Words: 663 - Pages: 3

Free Essay

Ninja History

...and assassination, and open combat in certain situations. Their covert methods of waging war contrasted the ninja with the samurai, who observed strict rules about honor and combat. The shinobi proper, a specially trained group of spies and mercenaries, appeared in the Sengoku or "warring states" period, in the 15th century, but antecedents may have existed in the 14th century, and possibly even in the 12th century (Heian or early Kamakuraera). In the unrest of the Sengoku period (15th–17th centuries), mercenaries and spies for hire became active in the Iga Province and the adjacent area around the village of Kōga, and it is from their ninja clans that much of our knowledge of the ninja is drawn. Following the unification of Japan under the Tokugawa shogunate (17th century), the ninja faded into obscurity. A number of shinobi manuals, often centered around Chinese military philosophy, were written in the 17th and 18th centuries, most notably theBansenshukai (1676). By the time of the Meiji Restoration (1868), the tradition of the shinobi had become a topic of popular imagination and mystery in Japan. Ninja figured prominently in folklore and legend, and as a result it is often difficult to separate historical fact from myth. Some legendary abilities purported to be in the province of ninja training include invisibility, walking on water, and control over the natural elements. As a consequence, their perception in western popular culture in the 20th century is often based more on...

Words: 289 - Pages: 2

Premium Essay

Importance of

...refused to bow, the samurai was legally entitled to chop off the recalcitrant person's head. Samurai answered only to the daimyo for whom they worked. The daimyo, in turn, answered only to the shogun. There were about 260 daimyo by the end of the feudal era. Each daimyo controlled a broad area of land, and had an army of samurai. The Farmers / Peasants: Just below the samurai on the social ladder were the farmers or peasants. According to Confucian ideals, farmers were superior to artisans and merchants because they produced the food that all the other classes depended upon. Although technically they were considered an honored class, the farmers lived under a crushing tax burden for much of the feudal era. During the reign of the third Tokugawa shogun, Iemitsu, farmers were not allowed to eat any of the rice they grew. They had to hand it all over to their daimyo, and then wait for him to give some back as charity. The Artisans: Although artisans produced many beautiful and necessary goods, such as clothes, cooking utensils, and woodblock prints, they were considered less important than the farmers. Even skilled...

Words: 1404 - Pages: 6

Premium Essay

Dear Emperor Meiji

...Ambroos Rentmeester Wolvenstraat, Amsterdam 1016EE May 4, 1899 Emperor Meiji Yubinbango 100-8111 Tokyo Chiyado, Chiyado 1-1v Dear Great Emperor Meiji, I am a humble Dutch trader that has heard of the concerns that bringing Japan out of isolation has brought forth. This letter is written on behalf of many other Dutch traders who completely support your most wise decision to open up the gates of Japan. Coming out of isolation has helped strengthen both our economies and relationship. Despite the benefits that opening trade has led to many benefits for both the Dutch and Japanese, we are aware of the doubt that rests among your people. As a country, we completely support your choice and hope that the uncertainty part of your people hold will not prevent, but further our countries trade. Because of our trade in the Edo Period, we gained considerable wealth exporting beautiful Japanese products, such as silk, porcelain and cotton, as well as providing bits of knowledge for Japan and outside nations. However that wealth never went past a certain point because of the restricted laws, and as a result many of the Japanese products we received came through China. During the mid Edo period both our countries suffered a huge loss due to the crash of the Dutch East India Company. Independent Dutch traders were also unapproved by the bakufu, which worsened the situation. As the only foreign company Japan traded with, your limited link to the outside world decreased substantially...

Words: 651 - Pages: 3

Premium Essay

How Did the Tokugawa Period Contribute to the Economical and Political Success of Modern Japan?

...How did the Tokugawa Period contribute to the economical and political success of Modern Japan? Introduction: Important aspects of the Tokugawa period led to the development of Early Modern Japan. The Tokugawa Shogunate’s evolving economic and political structure became the foundation for the political economy of the rapid modernisation of Japan, which was to follow after. Tokugawa Leyasu, the great Shogun This period between 1603 (when Tokugawa Leyasu became the great “Shogun” of the Tokugawa Shogunate) and 1867 (when Tokugawa Yoshinobu formally returned political authority to the emperor) is also called the Edo Period. Edo is the former name for what is now Tokyo. This period was named after Edo castle, where the emperor lived, and was also the headquarters of the feudal government at the time. This period in Japan’s history has also been interpreted in contrary ways- once dismissed as the “Feudal dark age” it is now looked upon as the “ Golden Age of Peace and Prosperity”, before the arrival of Western imperialism changed Japan’s place in the world forever. For centuries before and after the Tokugawa Shogunate, the Emperor reigned powerless in Kyoto, while military men really ran the country. Edo Castle today [ 1 ] Edo Castle today [ 1 ] Edo Castle today, Chiyoda, Tokyo , Japan Edo Castle today, Chiyoda, Tokyo , Japan Edo Castle c. 1638 What was the structure of the “Four class system” introduced in the Tokugawa Period? The Tokugawa Shogunate...

Words: 1352 - Pages: 6