Free Essay

Work 420

In:

Submitted By leesheenyore
Words 8776
Pages 36
BIS Working Papers
No 420

On the correlation between commodity and equity returns: implications for portfolio allocation by Marco Lombardi and Francesco Ravazzolo

Monetary and Economic Department
July 2013

JEL classification: C11, C15, C53, E17, G17. Keywords: Commodity prices, equity prices, density forecasting, correlation, Bayesian DCC.

BIS Working Papers are written by members of the Monetary and Economic Department of the Bank for International Settlements, and from time to time by other economists, and are published by the Bank. The papers are on subjects of topical interest and are technical in character. The views expressed in them are those of their authors and not necessarily the views of the BIS.

This publication is available on the BIS website (www.bis.org).

©

Bank for International Settlements 2013. All rights reserved. Brief excerpts may be reproduced or translated provided the source is stated.

ISSN 1020-0959 (print) ISBN 1682-7678 (online)

On the correlation between commodity and equity returns: implications for portfolio allocation∗
Marco J. Lombardi† Francesco Ravazzolo‡ July 11, 2013

Abstract In the recent years several commentators hinted at an increase of the correlation between equity and commodity prices, and blamed investment in commodity-related products for this. First, this paper investigates such claims by looking at various measures of correlation. Next, we assess what are the implications of higher correlations between oil and equity prices for asset allocation. We develop a time-varying Bayesian Dynamic Conditional Correlation model for volatilities and correlations and find that joint modelling commodity and equity prices produces more accurate point and density forecasts, which lead to substantial benefits in portfolio allocation. This, however, comes at the price of higher portfolio volatility. Therefore, the popular view that commodities are to be included in one’s portfolio as a hedging device is not grounded.

Keywords: Commodity prices, equity prices, density forecasting, correlation, Bayesian DCC. JEL Classification : C11, C15, C53, E17, G17.
We thank seminar participants at the BIS, as well as at the ECB-NB “Modeling and forecasting oil prices”, MMF “Understanding Oil and Commodity Prices”, and CAMP “Forecasting and Analysing Oil Prices” workshops for helpful comments. We also gratefully acknowledge comments by Lutz Kilian and Dubravko Mihaljek. This paper is part of the research activities at the Centre for Applied Macro and Petroleum economics (CAMP) at BI Norwegian Business School. CAMP is supported by Statoil’s research program in petroleum economics. The manuscript was circulated initially with the title “Oil Price Density Forecasts: Exploring the Linkages with Stock Markets”. The views expressed in this paper are our own and do not necessarily reflect those of Bank for International Settlements and/or Norges Bank. † Bank for International Settlements, Centralbahnplatz 2, CH-4002 Basel (Switzerland). Email: marco.lombardi@bis.org ‡ Norges Bank and BI Norwegian Business School, Bankplassen 2, NO-0107 Oslo (Norway). Email: francesco.ravazzolo@norges-bank.no


1

1

Introduction

The past decade has witnessed a broad-based surge in commodity prices, with oil a frontrunner. The upward trend in prices has been ascribed to booming demand at the global level, but fluctuations around it have been substantial, especially after the onset of the Great Recession. Investing in commodities has generated hefty returns and has become increasingly popular, in spite of the high risks associated with this type of investment, due to the inherent volatility of commodity prices. Indeed, most fund managers have started advising their customers to devote a share of their portfolios to commodity-related products as part of long-term diversification strategy. This is often motivated by the fact that, over the long run, commodities are believed to display low correlation with other asset classes, most notably with equities (Gorton and Rouwenhorst [2006]). At the same time, substantial inflows into commodity-related investment products have led many commentators to speculate on whether commodities are increasingly behaving as an asset class. The empirical evidence on a lasting impact of financial investment on commodity prices is, at best, scant (see Fattouh et al. [2012] for a recent survey). In the segment of commodities, however, financial investors may have less commodity-specific knowledge and a different attitude compared to commercial players, and hence enter or exit trades based on their overall perceptions of the macroeconomic situation rather than market-specific factors. If this is the case, it would suggest that commodity prices are increasingly influenced by shocks coming from the demand side. This is a well-established fact in the literature on oil, following the seminal work by Kilian [2009]. The fact that equity prices are also likely to have been largely driven by shocks related to the global economic activity, especially in the aftermath of the financial crisis, could then explain the increase in correlations.1
1 Tang and Xiong [2010], on a similar note, report evidence of increased correlations between the returns of commodities that are included in indexes tracked by investment funds.

2

In this paper, we try to shed some light on these issues. If one looks at the most recent years, commodity and equity prices appeared to be increasingly correlated, both being apparently more sensitive to news concerning the global macroeconomic environment rather than to idiosyncratic and market-specific shocks. We first provide a complete characterization of this phenomenon, by computing correlations using different methodologies and trying to identify relevant turning points. Our results suggest that correlations, after having hovered around zero for more than a decade, have indeed increased markedly since mid-2008. The co-movements between commodity and equity prices have already been examined in the literature: Gorton and Rouwenhorst [2006] report that commodity returns display negative correlation with equity returns over a long sample, running from 1959 to 2004. B¨y¨¸ahin et al. [2010] explore the correlations on the pre-crisis period, failing to find u us evidence of significant changes. Using post-2008 data, B¨y¨¸ahin and Robe [2012] find u us that correlations between equities and commodities increased amid greater participation by speculators. Other papers focused more specifically on oil: Kilian and Park [2009] report that the response of equity prices to oil price shocks depends on the nature of the shocks; Cassassus and Higuera [2011] show that oil price changes are good predictors of equity returns; Chang et al. [2011] report evidence of volatility spillovers between oil and equity prices. To the best of our knowledge, no studies have examined yet the joint predictability of commodity and equity prices, nor implications of such predictability for asset allocation. To investigate to what extent co-movements between commodity and equity prices could be exploited to improve forecasts in either direction, we use constant parameter univariate and bivariate models for commodity and equity prices, and derive a time-varying Bayesian Dynamic Conditional Correlation (DCC) model (Della Corte et al. [2010]), which can account for the changes in the relationship between commodity and equity prices ob-

3

served after 2008. We conduct a density forecasting exercise and find that the DCC provides statistically superior density forecasts compared to a plain random walk model. We then assess the economic value of such forecasting gains by considering an assetallocation framework with commodities and equities. The use of a Bayesian estimation framework allows us to explicitly account for the fact that higher order moments and the full predictive densities of commodity and equity prices are uncertain and vary over time. Neglecting this and just focusing on mean and variances estimated on a fixed sample can lead to suboptimal allocation. The estimated predictive densities depend on the data and the prior, and account for estimation risk in the portfolio allocation; see Kandel and Stambaugh [1996], Barberis [2000], Avramov [2002], Cremers [2002], Kan and Zhou [2007] and Jacquier and Polson [2012]. Ravazzolo et al. [2008], Guidolin and Na [2008] and Pettenuzzo and Timmermann [2011] extend their analysis to account for instability uncertainty. Della Corte et al. [2011] and Della Corte et al. [2010] assess the economic value of volatility and correlation timing. We extend this literature by including in the asset allocation problem a new asset class, i.e. commodities. Our results indicate that using a time-varying joint model for commodity and equity prices leads to economic gains relative to passive strategies, especially at times of large price swings. At the same time, an investment strategy which also includes commodities in a portfolio produces substantially higher volatility than portfolios which do not include them. For short investment horizons this is evident for the whole sample and not only from September 2008 onwards, when correlations between equities and commodities increase. This is at odds with the common notion that commodities can serve as a hedge. The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 describes the data and documents changes in correlation over our sample. Section 3 presents bivariate models for commodity and equity prices and investigates their forecast accuracy. We then move to apply these findings to active asset allocation strategies in Section 4; Section 5 concludes.

4

2

Commodity and equity markets

The idea that commodity and equity prices should display a negative correlation can be deducted from expressing equity prices as the discounted value of future dividends. If prices of inputs in the production process (energy, metals, raw materials) increase, firms will see their profits shrink, other things equal, and will therefore have less dividend to distribute.2 In a sense, however, this suggests that commodity prices are driven exogenously. It is now widely acknowledged that this is not the case. Commodity price increases often come on the back of buoyant demand due to booming economic activity (Kilian [2009]). Therefore, the sign of the correlation becomes less clear-cut: both equity and commodity prices could increase on positive news about the global macroeconomic outlook materialize. Over the past years, market commentators have indeed often pointed at commodity and equity prices moving in the same direction as a consequence of more optimistic or more pessimistic expectations about the global economy. Kilian and Vega [2011] investigate formally the impact of various macroeconomic announcements on the oil price over a sample running from 1983 to 2008, but do not find a systematic relationship. In this section, we will gauge correlations between oil and equity returns using a number of different methods. To start with, we collected weekly returns generated by the Morgan Stanley Capital International global equity index (MSCI) and the Standard & Poor’s Goldman Sachs commodity index (SPGSCI), starting from January 1980 until December 2012, see Figure 1.3 Commodity prices are substantially more volatile as Figure 2 indicates. Figure 3 reports sample correlations computed on moving windows of different length; this is indeed what most commentators refer to when discussing co-movements of commodity and equity prices. It emerges clearly that correlations have been sometimes positive and sometimes negative, but on average have hovered around zero. In the recent
2 While this is likely to be the case for each individual firm, at the aggregate level things may be less clear cut, since increases in input prices can be passed through customers. 3 Data was obtained from Bloomberg.

5

episode, however, positive correlations appear to have been stronger and more persistent compared to the past: it started with the bursting of the financial crisis in 2008, and although correlations have recently declined, they are still positive. Using different windows alters somewhat the size of correlation, but the pattern remains. Instead of using rolling windows of different length, which spread the influence of extreme episodes or periods of market turbulence over time, one can use model-based approaches to estimating correlations. A popular approach is the Dynamic Conditional Correlation (DCC) model proposed by Engle [2002]:

yt vt

= Φ(L)yt−1 + vt = Ht0.5 εt , εt ∼ N (0, IN ), Ht = Dt Rt Dt (1)

2 2 Dt = diag{ωi } + diag{κi }vt−1 vt−1 + diag{λi }Dt−1 , i = 1, ..., N

Qt = S(ıı − A − B) + Aεt−1 εt−1 + BQt−1 Rt = diag{Qt }−1 Qt diag{Qt }−1 where yt is a (N × 1) vector of dependent variables, S is the unconditional correlation matrix of εt , A, B and S(ıı − A − B) are positive semidefinite matrices; see Appendix for model details. In a nutshell, the DCC is a multivariate GARCH model in which correlations are time-varying according to an autoregressive specification. As such, the DCC accounts for both the time-varying features of volatilities and correlations. The dynamic conditional correlations are reported in Figure 4. Although correlations appear to be smaller compared to those estimated using rolling windows, they still look persistently positive towards the end of the sample, in line with the findings of B¨y¨¸ahin u us and Robe [2012].4
The dynamics of the USD exchange rate could alter the correlation pattern, since non-US equities in the MSCI index are priced in US dollars. To control for this, we repeated our analysis with the S&P500 index in place of the MSCI index. The results in terms of correlation (see Figure 8 in the appendix), statistical predictability and economic gains (available upon request) are similar to those discussed in the remainder of the paper.
4

6

Since visual inspection reveals a persistent increase in correlation towards the end of the sample, we formally tested for a breakpoint in the correlation pattern using the methodology proposed by Andrews [1993] and Andrews and Ploberger [1994]. The results of the test point to a significant breakpoint on 5 September 2008, just before the bankruptcy of Lehmann Bros.5 Interestingly, the same breakdate is found on windowbased and model-based correlations. Again, this comes at no surprise if one takes into account that, in the downturn and the subsequent economic recovery, both commodity and equity prices are likely to have been driven by the same common shocks, i.e. news on the shape of the global macroeconomic outlook.

3

Joint forecasts of commodity and equity prices

The debate on the predictability of equity prices is still an open issue in empirical research, see for example Welch and Goyal [2008]. Market efficiency theories imply not predictability, whether market friction theories imply predictability. Evidence of predictability of oil prices has, on contrary, been subject to a break in recent years: from the mid-90’s, research evidence suggests not predictability where future prices contain all the relevant information and alternative models cannot improve forecast accuracy. However, very recent studies such as Baumeister and Kilian [2012] find that several (Bayesian) reduced-form Vector Autoregressive models outperform forecasts based on future prices in a real-time setting. Baumeister and Kilian’s models apply macroeconomic data to forecast oil prices, but they do not explore the linkage with equity prices. Furthermore, their analysis refers mainly to point forecasting. Kandel and Stambaugh [1996] and Barberis
The test was conducted using the average, sup and LM statistics, with the p-values tabulated by Hansen [1997]. All test statistics are significant at the 1% level. As recommended, we cut off the first and last 10% of the observations.
5

7

[2000], among others, discuss the role of parameter uncertainty and Bayesian analysis as tool to cope with for return predictability and for asset allocation. We produce weekly point and density forecasts for commodity and equity returns over the sample from 2005W1 to 2012W52 for a total of 417 weeks. We compute h = 1, 2, ..., 24 steps ahead forecast for each vintage using a bivariate Bayesian Vector Autoregressive model with Minnesota type prior (VAR), see Clark and Ravazzolo [2012] for details, and a bivariate Bayesian DCC model.6 The main advantage of density forecasting over a plain point forecast is that it can take into account higher moments, which are key ingredients for the asset allocation exercise and can lead to substantial economic gains. We compare these forecasts to a random walk (RW), i.e. the point forecast is taken to be today’s price and the predicted volatility is the sample standard deviation, as well as a Bayesian autoregressive model (AR). Bayesian inference on the listed models allows to derive complete predictive densities, whose statistical accuracy is evaluated in the forecasting exercise. More specifically, we consider several evaluation statistics for point and density forecasts previously proposed in the literature, see Billio et al. [2012] for a recent application. We evaluate commodity and equity forecasts separately in this section, and use marginal densities from bivariate models. We compare point forecasts in terms of Mean Square Prediction Errors (MSPE) 1 M SP Ek = ∗ t t e2 , k,t+1 t=t where t∗ = t − t + 1 and e2 k,t+1 is the square prediction error of model k. We evaluate the predictive densities using two relative measures. First, we consider a Kullback-Leibler Information Criterion (KLIC) based measure; see for example Kitamura [2002], Mitchell and Hall [2005], Hall and Mitchell [2007], Amisano and Giacomini [2007], Kascha and
Further details on the model and the estimation algorithm are reported in the appendix. Della Corte et al. [2010] present an application to assess the economic value of time-varying correlation timing.
6

8

Ravazzolo [2010]. The KLIC distance between the true density p(yt+1 |y1:t ) of a random variable yt+1 and some candidate density p(˜k,t+1 |y1:t ) obtained from model k is defined y as

KLICk,t+1 =

p(yt+1 |y1:t ) ln

p(yt+1 |y1:t ) dyt+1 , p(˜k,t+1 |y1:t ) y (2)

= Et [ln p(yt+1 |y1:t ) − ln p(˜k,t+1 |y1:t ))]. y

where Et (·) = E(·|Ft ) is the conditional expectation given information set Ft at time t. An estimate can be obtained from the average of the sample information, yt+1 , . . . , yt+1 , on p(yt+1 |y1:t ) and p(˜k,t+1 |y1:t ): y

KLIC k+1

1 = ∗ t

t

[ln p(yt+1 |y1:t ) − ln p(˜k,t+1 |y1:t )]. y t=t (3)

The KLIC chooses the model which on average gives higher probability to events that have actually occurred. In reality we do not know the true density, but for the comparison of two competing models, it is sufficient to consider the Logarithmic Score (LS), which corresponds to the latter term in the above sum,

LSk = −

1 t∗

t

ln p(˜k,t+1 |y1:t ), y t=t (4)

for all k and to choose the model for which the expression in (4) is minimal, or as we report in our tables, the opposite of the expression in (4) is maximal. Since the distribution properties of a statistical test to compare density accuracy performances, measured in terms of LS, are not derived when working with nested models 9

and expanding estimation windows, as is our case, we follow Groen et al. [2012] and test the null of equal finite sample forecast accuracy, against the alternative that a model outperformed the RW benchmark using the Harvey et al. [1997] small sample correction of the Diebold and Mariano [1995] and West [1996] statistic to standard normal critical values.7 Following evidence in Clark and McCracken [2012] for point forecasting, we apply the same test to investigate superiority in square prediction errors. Table 1 reports point and density forecast results. Absolute predictability for commodity returns is substantially lower than absolute predictability for equity returns: MSPEs are higher and LS lower for all horizons. Data characteristics discussed in section 2 can explain the result. However, the evidence is somewhat different for relative predictability and point toward density forecasting. The models produce very similar point forecasts; but the DCC model gives the highest LS for all the horizons in forecasting commodities, but not in forecasting equity returns. Therefore, equities seem to contain relevant information to forecast commodities, whether the opposite is not supported by our analysis. Ferraro et al. [2012] find opposite evidence when investigating exchange rate and oil price predictability: oil prices forecast exchange rates, but exchange rates do not forecast oil prices. However, reported improvements are often very small. Moreover, the DCC model gives more accurate forecasts relative to the RW benchmark for all the horizons up to 24 weeks and improvements in density forecasting are always statistically significant. So, a time-varying covariance matrix which can model instability in volatility and correlations between the two variables, as discussed in Section 2 is an important ingredient to predict higher moments of the joint commodity and equity predictive density. Figure 5 indicates that most of the gains are in September 2008; but for several horizons gains persist also in the aftermath of the Lehman bankrupcy.
7

Given that we maximise the LS, we use right-tail p-values for the LS test.

10

4

Asset allocation exercise

How should an investor read the results reported in the last two sections? On one hand, the finding that correlation has become positive in the aftermath of the crisis may suggest that commodities can no longer work as a hedge in one’s portfolio. On the other hand, the fact that commodity returns are predicted by equity returns may bring benefits if one follows a dynamic asset allocation strategy. To answer these questions, we need to investigate the economic value of jointly modelling commodities and equities in the setting of an investment strategy which allows both assets to be included in one’s portfolio. To this end, we develop an active short-term investment exercise. The investor’s portfolio consists of the equity index, the commodity index and risk free bonds only.8 At the end of each week t, the investor decides upon the fraction αs,t+h of her portfolio to be held in stocks, αc,t+h in the commodity index and the remaining part in the risk free asset for the period t + h, based on the forecast of the commodity and stock index returns. We constrain αs,t+h , αc,t+h not allowing for short-sales or leveraging (see Barberis [2000]) and to have at least 50% of the invested portfolio in risky asset. We assume that the investor maximizes a power utility function:
1−γ Rt+h , 1−γ

u(Rt+h ) =

γ > 1,

(5)

where γ is the coefficient of relative risk aversion and Rt+h is the wealth at time t + h, which is equal to

Rt+h = Rt ((1 − αs,t+h − αc,t+h ) exp(yf,t+h ) + αt+h exp(yf,t+h + yt+h )), ˜
8

(6)

The risk free asset is approximated by using the weekly federal funds rate; data was obtained from the Fred database at the Federal Reserve Bank of St Louis.

11

where Rt denotes initial wealth, αt+h = (αs,t+h , αc,t+h ), yf,t+h the h-step ahead risk free rate and yt+h the h-step ahead bivariate forecast of the commodity and stock index ˜ returns in excess of the risk free made at time t. Our investor does not rebalance the portfolios in the period from t to t + h, but keeps positions on the three assets constant.9 When the initial wealth is set equal to one, i.e. R0 = 1, the investor solves the following problem:

αt+h ∈[0,1]

max 2

αt+h ≤1

Et

((1 − αs,t+h − αc,t+h ) exp(yf,t+h ) + αt+h exp(yf,t+h + yt+h ))1−γ ˜ 1−γ

.

The expectation Et (·) depends on the predictive density for the commodity and stock excess returns, p(˜t+h |y1:t ) and the problem can be rewritten as: y

αt+h ∈[0,1]2

max

αt+h ≤1

u(Rt+h )p(˜t+h |y1:t )d˜t+h . y y

(7)

We approximate the integral in (7) by generating G independent draws from the predictive density p(˜t+h |y1:t ), yt+h , and then use a numerical optimization method to y ˜g find: 1 max αt+h ∈[0,1] G
G

g=1

((1 − αt+h ) exp(yf,t+h ) + αt+h exp(yf,t+h + yt+h ))1−γ ˜g 1−γ

.

(8)

We consider an investor who can choose between different forecast densities of the (excess) commodity and equity returns yt+h to solve the optimal allocation problem described above. We include three cases in the empirical analysis below and assume the investor uses alternatively the density from the RW and AR univariate models for each
In the case of dynamic asset allocation the long-run investor is allowed to rebalance her portfolio during the investment period, adjusting the portfolio weights to reflect new information that arrives. Solving the resulting dynamic programming problem is complicated due to the large number of state variables that enter the problem in a highly nonlinear way, see Barberis [2000] and Guidolin and Timmermann [2007].
9

12

series, the bivariate BVAR and the bivariate BVAR-DCC. Moreover, since the portfolio weights in the active investment strategies change every period, we include transaction costs of c = 0.05%, i.e. 5 basis points. We evaluate the different investment strategies for an investor with a risk aversion parameter γ = 5, as in Barberis [2000], by computing the ex post annualized mean portfolio return, the annualized standard deviation and the Sharpe ratio.10 We compare the wealth provided at time t + h by two resulting portfolios by determining the value of multiplication factor of wealth ∆ which equates their average utilities. For example, suppose we compare two strategies A and B. t t

u(RA,t+h ) = t=t t=t

u(RB,t+h / exp(r)),

(9)

where u(RA,t+h ) and u(RB,t+h ) are the wealth provided at time T + h by the two resulting portfolios A and B, respectively. Following West et al. [1993], we interpret ∆ as the maximum performance fee the investor would be willing to pay to switch from strategy A to strategy B.11 We infer the value added of strategies based on individual models and the combination scheme by computing ∆ with respect to three static benchmark strategies: holding only stock (∆s ), holding only commodities (∆c ), and holding 70% in equities and 30% in commodities (∆70/30 ). Finally we compute the certainty equivalent return (CER) for each strategy, in formula:

CERt+h = u−1 (Et (u(Rt+h ))),

(10)

where u1− is the inverse of the power utility function defined in (5). Strategy with maximum CER is preferred. We do not report the final value as for other alternative measures, but plot how cumulative difference between any strategy A and investing 100%
10 11

Results are qualitatively similar for γ = 2, . . . , 6. See, for example, Fleming et al. [2001] for an application with stock returns.

13

of the portfolio in the stock market: t CERDk,t+1 = s=t (CERA,t+h − CERs,t+h ),

(11)

where k = RW, AR, ..., F RR. If CERDk,t+h increases at observation t + h, this indicates that the strategy k gives higher CER than the benchmark strategy. Results in Table 2 strengthen the evidence reported in the section on point and density forecasting. The VAR and DCC models give higher SR than the RW and have positive ‘entrance fees’ relative to passive strategies for all the horizons. Gains are robust to reasonable transaction costs. The DCC provides the highest gains for horizons longer than two and up to eight weeks. Gains are substantial compared to alternative models for 2- and 4-weeks horizons. So, a joint modelling of commodity and equity returns with time-varying volatility can produce statistically and economically significant gains. To shed light how such gains are made, Figure 5 plots the CER differential relative to a passive strategy of investing 100% of the portfolio in stock prices over the sample period for a two weeks horizons. For all the six investment horizons we consider, the gains arise mainly in the second part of 2008, i.e. during the most turbulent time of the recent financial crisis, when equity and commodity prices are likely to have been driven by the same common shocks. However, the whole period from the beginning of the Great Financial Crisis from August 2007 to the end of the sample shows that the active strategies lead to economic gains. Those yielded by the DCC are marginally higher compared to RW models and substantially higher than AR and VAR models. We now turn to the question of what are the relative advantages of a portfolio including commodities in addition to equities and a risk-free asset. To answer this, we compare the results of Table 2 with those coming from a similar portfolio allocation exercise, in which the weight associated to commodities is set to zero. Results, reported in Table 3, suggest 14

that the inclusion of commodities in one’s portfolio has boosted returns when using a DCC model, in particular for horizons of 2 to 4 weeks. However, this comes at the price of a substantially higher volatility, irrespective of the model used. Therefore, the common lore that commodities should serve as a hedge does not seem to be solidly grounded. We compare the realized 1-year moving window standard deviation of the portfolio based on DCC forecasts which actively invests in both stock and commodity indexes and the risk free to an active portfolio that invests only on stock and risk free using a forecast from the RW model (since it produced more accurate predictions that the AR model). Figure 7 shows that the large increase in the volatility of the stock/commodity portfolio is attained in September 2008. Nevertheless, for horizons shorter than 8 weeks this portfolio has higher volatility than the portfolio without commodities for the whole sample.

5

Concluding remarks

This paper has shown that the correlation between commodity and equity returns has substantially increased after the onset of the recent financial crisis. We have then investigated the joint predictability of commodity and equity returns, and its benefits in a dynamic asset allocation exercise. Relative to a benchmark random-walk model, a bivariate Bayesian DCC model, which can account for time variation in the correlation pattern, produces statistically more accurate density forecasts and gives large economic gains in an asset allocation exercise. The value of an active strategy based on DCC forecasts is large compared to passive strategies during turbulent times. At the same time, an investment strategy which also includes commodities in a portfolio produces substantially higher volatility and not always produces higher Sharpe ratios. This is at odds with the common notion that commodities serve as a hedge. Private and institutional investors have displayed an increasing appetite for commodi-

15

ties over the past years. Our findings have far-fetching policy implications in this respect. On one side, our results provide empirical support for the inclusion of commodities in a portfolio. At the same time, however, we have also found that this comes at the cost of an increase in volatility. Therefore, the growing appetite for commodities is likely to produce more volatile portfolios. Digging further into the financial stability implications of the increasing correlation of commodity and equity returns is a relevant subject for future research.

References
G. Amisano and R. Giacomini. Comparing density forecasts via weighted likelihood ratio tests. Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, 25(2):177–190, 2007. D. W. K. Andrews. Tests for parameter instability and structural change with unknown change point. Econometrica, 61:821–856, 1993. D. W. K. Andrews and W. Ploberger. Optimal tests when a nuisance parameter is present only under the alternative. Econometrica, 62:1383–1414, 1994. D. Avramov. Stock return predictability and model uncertainty. Journal of Financial Economics, 64:423–458, 2002. N. Barberis. Investing for the long run when returns are predictable. Journal of Finance, 55:255–264, 2000. C. Baumeister and L. Kilian. Real-time forecasts of the real price of oil. Journal of Business and Economic and Satistics, 30(2):326–336, 2012. M. Billio, R. Casarin, F. Ravazzolo, and van Dijk H. K. Time-varying combinations of predictive densities using nonlinear filtering. Technical report, Norges Bank, 2012. 16

B. B¨y¨¸ahin and M. Robe. Speculators, commodities and cross-market linkages. Techu us nical report, CFTC, 2012. B. B¨y¨¸ahin, M. Haigh, and M. Robe. Commodities and equities: Ever a “market of u us one”? Journal of Alternative Investment, 12:76–95, 2010. J. Cassassus and F. Higuera. Stock return predictability and oil prices. Technical Report 406, Instituto de Economia, Pontificia Universidad Catolica de Chile, 2011. C.-L. Chang, M. McAleer, and R. Tansuchat. Crude oil hedging strategies using dynamic multivariate garch. Energy Economics, 33(5):912–923, 2011. T. Clark and M. W. McCracken. Advances in forecast evaluation. In A. Timmermann and G. Elliott, editors, Handbook of Economic Forecasting. Elsevier, Amsterdam, 2012. T. Clark and F. Ravazzolo. Comparing models of time-varying macroeconomic volatility. Technical Report 12-18, FRB of Cleveland Working Paper, 2012. K. J. M. Cremers. Stock return predictability: A bayesian model selection perspective. Review of Financial Studies, 15:1223–1249, 2002. P. Della Corte, L. Sarno, and I. Tsiakas. Correlation timin in asset allocation with bayesian learning. Technical report, Warwick Business School, 2010. P. Della Corte, L. Sarno, and I. Tsiakas. Spot and forward volatility in foreign exchange. Journal of Financial Economics, 100:496–513, 2011. F. X. Diebold and R. S. Mariano. Comparing predictive accuracy. Journal of Business and Economic Stastistics, 13:253–263, 1995. R. Engle. Dynamic conditional correlation: A simple class of multivariate generalized autoregressive conditional heteroskedasticity models. Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, 20(3):339–350, 2002. 17

B. Fattouh, L. Kilian, and L. Mahadeva. The role of speculation in oil markets: What have we learned so far? CEPR Discussion Papers 8916, C.E.P.R. Discussion Papers, 2012. D. Ferraro, K. Rogoff, and B. Rossi. Can oil prices forecast exchange rates? Working Paper 17998, NBER, 2012. J. Fleming, C. Kirby, and B. Ostdiek. The Economic Value of Volatility Timing. Journal of Finance, 56:329–352, 2001. G. Gorton and K. G. Rouwenhorst. Facts and fantasies about commodity futures. Financial Analysts Journal, 62(2):47–68, 2006. J. J. J. Groen, R. Paap, and F. Ravazzolo. Real-time inflation forecasting in a changing world. Journal of Business and Economic Stastistics, forthcoming, 2012. M. Guidolin and C. F. Na. The economic and statistical value of forecast combinations under regime switching: An application to predictable us returns. In D. E. Rapach and M. E. Wohar, editors, Forecasting in the Presence of Structural Breaks and Model Uncertainty, volume 3 of Frontiers of Economics and Globalization, chapter 16, pages 595 – 655. Emerald Group Publishing Limited, 2008. M. Guidolin and A. Timmermann. Asset allocation under multivariate regime switching. Technical report, 2007. S. G. Hall and J. Mitchell. Combining density forecasts. International Journal of Forecasting, 23:1–13, 2007. B. E. Hansen. Approximate asymptotic p-values for structural change tests. Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, 15:60–67, 1997. NBER

18

D. Harvey, S. Leybourne, and P. Newbold. Testing the equality of prediction mean squared errors. International Journal of Forecasting, 13:281–291, 1997. E. Jacquier and N. Polson. Asset allocation in finance: A bayesian perspective. In D. Dellaportas, N. Polson, and G. Stephen, editors, Hierarchical models and MCMC: a Tribute to Adrian Smith. Oxford University Press, 2012. R. Kan and G. Zhou. Optimal portfolio choice with parameter uncertainty. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analaysis, 51:385–424, 2007. S. Kandel and R. Stambaugh. On the predictability of stock returns: An asset allocation perspective. Journal of Finance, 51:385–424, 1996. C. Kascha and F. Ravazzolo. Combining Inflation Density Forecasts. Journal of Forecasting, 29(1-2):231–250, 2010. L. Kilian. Not all oil price shocks are alike: Disentangling demand and supply shocks in the crude oil market. American Economic Review, 99(3):1053–1069, 2009. L. Kilian and C. Park. The impact of oil price shocks on the u.s. stock market. International Economic Review, 50(4):1267–1287, 2009. L. Kilian and C. Vega. Do energy prices respond to u.s. macroeconomic news? a test of the hypothesis of predetermined energy prices. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 93(2):660–671, 2011. Y. Kitamura. Econometric Comparisons of Conditional Models. Discussion paper,, University of Pennsylvania, 2002. J. Mitchell and S. G. Hall. Evaluating, comparing and combining density forecasts using the KLIC with an application to the Bank of England and NIESER “fan” charts of inflation. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 67:995–1033, 2005. 19

D. Pettenuzzo and A. Timmermann. Predictability of stock returns and asset allocation under structural breaks. Journal of Econometrics, fothcoming, 2011. F. Ravazzolo, R. Paap, D. van Dijk, and P. H. Franses. Bayesian model averaging in the presence of structural breaks. In D. E. Rapach and M. E. Wohar, editors, Forecasting in the Presence of Structural Breaks and Model Uncertainty, volume 3 of Frontiers of Economics and Globalization, chapter 15, pages 561–594. Emerald Group Publishing Limited, 2008. K. Tang and W. Xiong. Index investment and financialization of commodities. Technical Report 16385, NBER, 2010. T. Tokuda, B. Goodrich, I. Van Mechelen, A. Gelman, and F. Tuerlinckx. Visualizing distributions of covariance matrices. Technical report, Columbia, 2012. I. Welch and A. Goyal. A Comprehensive Look at the Empirical Performance of Equity Premium prediction. Review of Financial Studies, 21(4):253–303, 2008. K. D. West. Asymptotic inference about predictive ability. Econometrica, 64:1067–1084, 1996. K. D. West, H. J. Edison, and D. Cho. A utility-based comparison of some models of exchange rate volatility. Journal of International Economics, 35(1-2):23–45, 1993.

20

Appendix A
DCC: a Bayesian estimation algorithm
The DCC model for the (N × 1) vector yt is formulated as: yt vt = Φ(L)yt−1 + vt = Ht0.5 εt , εt ∼ N (0, IN ), Ht = Dt Rt Dt (12)

2 2 Dt = diag{ωi } + diag{κi }vt−1 vt−1 + diag{λi }Dt−1 , i = 1, ..., N

Qt = S(ıı − A − B) + Aεt−1 εt−1 + BQt−1 Rt = diag{Qt }−1 Qt diag{Qt }−1 where S is the unconditional correlation matrix of εt , A, B and S(ıı − A − B) are positive semidefinite matrices. In our exercise N = 2, therefore the parameters A and B reduce to scalar and above conditions to A > 0, B > 0, A + B < 1. Following Engle [2002], the log likelihood can be expressed as: 1 lnL = − 2
T −1 −1 −1 (N ln(2π) + 2 ln |Dt | + vt Dt Dt vt − εt εt + ln |Rt | + εt−1 Rt εt−1 ) t=1

(13)

We estimate the DCC model using a Metropolis-Hastings algorithm. Define the vector αi = (Φ0 , ..., ΦL , ωi , κi , λi , A, B) , with Φ(L) = (Φ0 , ..., ΦL ), i = 1, .., N , and αj the j-th element of it. The sampling scheme consists of the following iterative steps.
∗ Step 1: At iteration s, generate a point αj from the random walk kernel

i−1 ∗ αj = αj + j ,

∼ N (0, Q),

(14)

s−1 2 where Q is a diagonal matrix and σj is its j-th diagonal element, and αj is the (s −

1)th iterate of αj . Therefore, we draw row elements of Φ0 , ..., ΦL and ωi , κi , λi , A, B

21

s−1 ∗ s ∗ independently. Then accept αj as αj with probability p = min 1, f (αj )/f (αj ) , where s−1 ∗ f () is the likelihood of model (12) times priors. Otherwise, set αj = αj . The elements

of Q are tuned by monitoring the acceptance rate to lie between 25% and 50%. Step 2: After M iterations, we apply the following independent kernel MH algorithm.
∗ Generate αj from ∗ αj = µi−1 + j , αj

∼ N (0, Qαj ),

(15)

where µαj and Qαj are, respectively, the sample mean and the sample covariance of the i ∗ first M iterates for αj . Then accept αj as αj with probability

p = min 1,

s−1 ∗ f (αj )g(αj ) s−1 ∗ f (αj )g(αj )

,

(16)

where g() is a Gaussian proposal density (15). Priors We set normal priors for Φ(L) with mean and variance equal to OLS estimates. The priors for ωi , κi , λi , A, B are uniform distributed and satisfy the restrictions ωi > 0, κi > 0, λi >, κi + λi < 1, A > 0, B > 0, A + B < 1. We note that different priors for the coefficients A and B of the correlation matrix should be considered if the dimension of the model is larger than two, see discussion in Tokuda et al. [2012].

22

Table 1: Forecast accuracy for commodity and equity returns
Commodity index h=2 RW AR VAR 12.890 12.991 12.836 -3.300 -3.495 -3.279 h=12 RW AR VAR 13.028 13.063 13.196 -3.266 -3.479 -3.593 Equity index h=2 RW AR VAR 8.088 8.116 8.345 -3.522 -4.174 -4.206 h=12 RW AR VAR 8.280 8.251 8.274 -3.666 -4.319 -4.301

h=1 RW AR VAR MSPE 12.864 13.002 12.965 LS -3.351 -3.341 -3.220 h=8 RW AR VAR MSPE 12.988 13.003 12.899 LS -3.269 -3.383 -3.398 h=1 AR VAR 8.256 8.536 -3.991 -4.124 h=8 AR VAR 8.191 8.294 -3.976 -4.316

DCC 12.978 -2.669∗ DCC 12.922 -2.661∗

DCC 12.980 -2.766∗ DCC 13.149 -2.880∗

RW 12.944 -3.259 RW 12.905 -3.263

h=4 AR VAR DCC 13.048 13.165 13.184 -3.567 -3.315 -2.645∗ h=24 AR VAR DCC 12.968 12.950 12.957 -3.699 -3.734 -2.972∗ h=4 AR VAR 12.968 12.950 -3.699 -3.734 h=24 AR VAR 8.437 8.426 -4.347 -4.397

RW MSPE 8.081 LS -3.573 RW MSPE 8.201 LS -3.560

DCC 8.515 -4.432 DCC 8.348 -4.181

DCC 8.355 -4.095 DCC 8.267 -4.003

RW 12.905 -3.263 RW 8.454 -3.473

DCC 12.968 -3.239 DCC 8.478 -4.275

Notes: RW , AR, V AR, DCC denote models as defined in Section 3; MSPE is the Mean Square Prediction Error; LS is the average Logarithmic Score. Lower MSPE and higher LS imply more accurate forecasts. One ∗ represent rejections of the null hypothesis of equal predictability following the Harvey et al. [1997] type of test at 10%.

23

Table 2: Economic value of portfolios with commodities
No transaction costs h=2 RW AR VAR DCC 2.95 2.98 2.69 4.09 16.75 16.71 17.07 16.43 0.06 0.06 0.04 0.13 90.07 90.52 77.03 116.03 36.02 36.46 22.97 61.97 28.83 29.28 15.79 54.79 h=12 RW AR VAR DCC 3.05 0.33 1.81 2.54 18.03 20.60 18.90 19.36 0.06 -0.08 -0.01 0.03 317.98 -106.26 86.98 107.12 920.78 496.55 689.79 709.93 353.53 -70.71 122.53 142.67 5 bp transaction costs h=2 RW AR VAR DCC 2.39 2.19 1.93 3.36 16.76 16.71 17.08 16.43 0.03 0.01 0.00 0.09 78.57 74.53 61.45 101.06 24.52 36.46 7.40 47.00 17.33 13.29 0.21 39.82 h=12 RW AR VAR DCC 3.01 0.27 1.76 2.45 18.03 20.59 18.90 19.35 0.06 -0.09 -0.01 0.02 316.00 -109.00 84.16 102.99 918.81 496.55 686.97 705.80 351.55 -73.45 119.71 138.54

Mean Ret St dev SR ∆s ∆c ∆ 70 − 30

RW 4.33 16.61 0.15 94.90 60.25 50.02 RW 4.63 22.12 0.12 101.14 87.11 26.45

Mean Ret St dev SR ∆s ∆c ∆ 70 − 30

h=1 AR VAR DCC 2.78 2.82 2.05 15.87 16.43 16.51 0.05 0.05 0.01 78.84 70.90 58.10 23.45 44.18 36.24 13.22 33.95 26.01 h=8 AR VAR DCC 3.55 5.29 5.24 23.05 22.89 22.87 0.07 0.15 0.16 15.62 103.73 104.39 0.59 88.70 89.36 -61.07 27.04 27.70

h=4 AR VAR DCC 2.61 2.96 3.30 17.36 17.57 17.73 0.04 0.06 0.08 106.63 103.65 110.79 106.12 103.13 110.27 38.46 35.47 42.61 h=24 RW AR VAR DCC 3.49 0.96 2.15 2.37 19.35 20.77 18.02 19.82 0.08 -0.06 0.01 0.02 680.53 158.93 500.64 362.04 2440.69 1919.08 2260.79 2122.20 910.50 388.90 730.61 592.01 RW 2.48 17.39 0.03 110.25 109.74 42.08 h=4 AR VAR DCC 2.35 2.74 3.04 17.36 17.57 17.72 0.02 0.05 0.06 99.24 97.29 103.39 101.12 96.77 102.87 31.07 29.11 35.21 h=24 RW AR VAR DCC 3.48 0.94 2.13 2.33 19.35 20.77 18.02 19.82 0.08 -0.06 0.00 0.01 679.46 157.47 499.03 359.16 2439.61 1919.08 2259.18 2119.32 909.43 387.44 729.00 589.13 RW 2.27 17.39 0.02 103.29 102.77 35.11

h=1 RW AR VAR Mean Ret 2.68 1.19 2.41 St dev 17.61 19.18 18.37 SR 0.04 -0.04 0.02 221.04 23.96 111.36 ∆s ∆c 379.60 182.52 269.93 ∆ 70 − 30 168.94 -28.13 59.27 h=8 RW AR VAR Mean Ret 2.60 1.09 2.32 St dev 17.61 19.18 18.37 SR 0.04 -0.05 0.02 ∆s 217.91 20.11 107.75 ∆c 376.47 182.52 266.32 ∆ 70 − 30 165.81 -31.98 55.66

DCC 2.87 18.74 0.05 120.01 278.58 67.92 DCC 2.74 18.73 0.04 115.10 273.66 63.01

Note: W N , AR, V AR, DCC denote individual models defined in Section 3; Mean Ret is the annualized mean portfolio return; St dev is the annualized standard deviation; SR is the Sharpe ratio. ∆s , ∆o , ∆f are the performance fees for switching from an active strategy to passive strategies holding only stock (rs ), only commodity (rc ), and the 70/30 passive strategy (rm ).

24

Table 3: Economic value of portfolios without commodities h=1 RW AR 2.92 0.83 10.31 14.43 0.10 -0.08 h=8 RW AR 2.80 1.51 10.51 14.77 0.08 -0.03 h=2 RW AR 2.87 1.18 10.07 14.79 0.09 -0.05 h=12 RW AR 2.78 1.56 10.67 13.70 0.07 -0.03 h=4 RW AR 2.90 1.68 10.24 14.73 0.08 -0.02 h=24 RW AR 2.88 2.75 11.73 12.05 0.07 0.06

Mean Ret St dev SR

Mean Ret St dev SR

Note: W N , AR: denote individual models defined in Section 3; Mean Ret is the annualized mean portfolio return; St dev is the annualized standard deviation; SR is the Sharpe ratio.

25

11.01.1980 11.01.1982 11.01.1984 11.01.1986 11.01.1988 11.01.1990 11.01.1992

MXWO

11.01.1994 11.01.1996
11.01.1998 11.01.2000

11.01.2002 11.01.2004
11.01.2006 11.01.2008

11.01.2010 11.01.2012

11.01.1980 11.01.1982
11.01.1984 11.01.1986

Figure 1: Commodity and equity returns

11.01.1988 11.01.1990
11.01.1992 11.01.1994 MXWO

11.01.1996 11.01.1998
11.01.2000 11.01.2002 11.01.2004 11.01.2006 11.01.2008 11.01.2010 11.01.2012 SPGCCI

26
0 2 4 6

8

-12 -0,8

-10

-8

-4

-2

-6
-0,4

SPGCCI

0,2

0,4

0,6

0

-0,6

-0,2

Note: Weekly returns of commodity and equity indexes (left panel) and average returns over a 1-year moving window (right panel).

0,5 1 2 3 MXWO

1,5

2,5

0 11.01.1980
11.01.1982

11.01.1984
11.01.1986 11.01.1988

11.01.1990
11.01.1992

11.01.1994 11.01.1996
11.01.1998 11.01.2000 11.01.2002 11.01.2004 SPGCCI

Figure 2: Commodity and equity volatilities

Note: Standard deviations over a 1-year moving window of commodity and equity returns.

27
11.01.2006 11.01.2008
11.01.2010 11.01.2012

Figure 3: Commodity and equity correlations

1M 1 0,8 0,6 0,4 0,2 0

3M

6M

1Y

11.01.1980

11.01.1982

11.01.1988

11.01.1990

11.01.1996

11.01.1998

11.01.1984

11.01.1986

11.01.1992

11.01.1994

11.01.2000

11.01.2002

11.01.2004

11.01.2006

11.01.2008

11.01.2010

-0,2 -0,4

-0,6 -0,8 -1

Note: Sample correlations between commodity and equity returns computed on moving windows of different length: 3-months (3M); 6 months (6M); and 1-year (1Y).

Figure 4: Dynamic Conditional Correlations between the MSCI and the SPGSCI
.8 .6 .4 .2 .0 -.2 -.4 -.6 80 82 84 86 88 90 92 94 96 98 00 02 04 06 08 10 12

Note: Correlations between commodity and equity returns estimated using a Dynamic Conditional Correlation model. The vertical dashed line marks the estimated breakpoint (5 September 2008).

28

11.01.2012

Figure 5: Log-Score Differentials
AR 300 250 200 150 100 50 0 −50 2005W1 VAR DCC 250 200 150 100 50 0 −50 −100 2005W1 AR VAR DCC

2007W1

2009W1

2010W52

2012W52

2007W1

2009W1

2010W52

2012W52

h=1
AR 300 250 200 150 150 100 100 50 50 0 −50 −100 −150 2005W1 2007W1 2009W1 2010W52 2012W52 0 −50 −100 2005W1 VAR DCC 300 250 200

h=2
AR VAR DCC

2007W1

2009W1

2010W52

2012W52

h=4
AR 200 150 100 0 50 −50 0 −100 −50 −100 −150 2005W1 −150 VAR DCC 100

h=8
AR VAR DCC

50

2007W1

2009W1

2010W52

2012W52

−200 2005W1

2007W1

2009W1

2010W52

2012W52

h = 12

h = 24

Note: Log-Score (CER) Differentials versus the Log-Score of the RW benchmark.

29

Figure 6: CER Differentials

WN 100

AR

VAR

DCC

COMMODITY

70−30

80

60

40

20

0

−20 2005W1

2007W1

2009W1

2010W52

2012W52

Note: Certainty Equivalent Return (CER) Differential at an horizon of two weeks, with respect to the CER of the passive strategy holding only equities, with transaction costs set at 5 basis points.

30

Figure 7: Volatility for portfolios with and without commodities
DCC 18 16 14 12 10 8 6 4 2005W1 RW 18 16 14 12 10 8 6 4 2005W1 DCC RW

2007W1

2009W1

2010W52

2012W52

2007W1

2009W1

2010W52

2012W52

h=1
DCC 20 18 16 16 14 12 10 8 6 6 4 2005W1 4 2007W1 2009W1 2010W52 2012W52 2 2005W1 2007W1 14 12 10 8 RW 22 20 18

h=2
DCC RW

2009W1

2010W52

2012W52

h=4
DCC 25 RW 25

h=8
DCC RW

20

20

15

15

10

10

5

5

0 2005W1

2007W1

2009W1

2010W52

2012W52

0 2005W1

2007W1

2009W1

2010W52

2012W52

h = 12

h = 24

Note: Standard deviation of portfolio returns including commodities (using a DCC model for the dynamic asset allocation) and excluding commodities (using a RW model for the dynamic asset allocation).

31

Figure 8: Dynamic Conditional Correlations between the S&P500 and the SPGSCI
.8 .6 .4 .2 .0 -.2 -.4 -.6 80 82 84 86 88 90 92 94 96 98 00 02 04 06 08 10 12

Note: Correlations between commodity and equity returns estimated using a Dynamic Conditional Correlation model. The vertical dashed line marks the estimated breakpoint (5 September 2008).

32

Similar Documents

Premium Essay

Log Book

...------------------------------------------------- MIDLANDS STATE UNIVERSITY FACULTY OF COMMERCE Department of Accounting Industrial Attachment Log Book Name : RAY Surname : PASIPAMIRE Reg. Number: R124609Y Period of Attachment: August 2014 to July 2015 Institution Attached to: Westrand Investment RECORD OF WORK DONE (AUGUST 2014) Week | Activity | Student’s comments | 18-23(Orientation Week) | * I was introduced to members of the staff and shown around all the property. * There was also a brief of the code of conduct. * I was told how the organisation operates as a micro finance company. | * I got to know what was expected of me. * I was in a position to be aware with how the micro finance works | 25-30(Loans Desk) | * Evaluating of applications, i.e. checking to see if they meet the requirements and how much they can borrow. * I also made the recording of the loans in the loans book as well as checking attachments on each and every form. | * Got knowledge on calculating the amount of money a client is eligible to receive * I also obtained the knowledge of how attachments like payslip and national ID are important on loan application forms especially for future reference. | Supervisor’s Remarks...

Words: 649 - Pages: 3

Free Essay

Group Consensus Report Busi520

...seven members with varying degrees of professional expertise in strategic marketing. That expertise ranges from backgrounds in the non-profit sector to occupational therapy, financial analysis, logistics, international consultancy, and corporate management. The specific work expertise related to marketing that is relevant to this class is also varied with some members having strong expertise in marketing, sales and business and financial relations, while others have had no experience at all in marketing. This sets up the members for an interesting working relationship. All have had ample experience doing group work in past classes at Liberty University. The group is dynamic in nature. All in all, the individuals are go-getters who work well both as managers and as team members or followers. There seems to be a common work ethic where all members have a strong sense of initiative and are autonomous and self-motivated. While clearly acknowledging that no one is perfect, all seem committed to strive for excellence. Most of the members are process oriented and there is a strong sentiment that the tasks, guidance and specific roles for each individual in the group will need to be clear at all times. All members work reasonably well under pressure, but some members feel that stress is best...

Words: 1291 - Pages: 6

Premium Essay

Business Purpose

...|Date Issued | |Business Environment | |Week beginning 11/02/13 | |Student Name |Student ID |Due Date – 03/06/13 | |Lecturer Name: Ibrahim kevin, Sujata,& Issac |Internal Verifier Name | | |Mr. M. Azam | Rules and regulations: |Plagiarism is presenting somebody else’s work as your own. It includes: copying information directly from the Web or books without | |referencing the material; submitting joint coursework as an individual effort; copying another student’s coursework; stealing coursework from| |another student and submitting it as your own work. Suspected plagiarism will be investigated and if found to have occurred will be dealt | |with according to the procedures set down by the College. Please see your student handbook for further details of what is / isn’t plagiarism.| Coursework Regulations   1. Submission of coursework must be undertaken according to the relevant procedure – whether online or paper-based. Lecturers will give information as to which procedure must be followed, and details of submission procedures and penalty fees can be obtained from Academic Administration or the general student handbook. 2. All...

Words: 2134 - Pages: 9

Premium Essay

Interview with My Mother

...Interview Project My person of choice to interview for this project was my mother. She has personally in business for well over 15 years. She is talented and knows what she is doing through and through, and has helped lead her team to the top many times. My mother Jill works as an area manager for SunTrust in the Charlotte area. I decided to pick her, not only to have someone to interview, but also to get to know her on a more personal level and to see personally how she truly feels about what she does. I set up the interview via email. It becomes difficult trying to get together and be able to sit down and personally conduct the interview when she is out and about working. I attempt to visit as often as I can, but there are some nights that she doesn’t get home until really late. She was welcome and willing to do it, and her answers gave me more of an insight of what she really does. Here are the following questions, as well as answers. 1.) a. How do you measure success? In many ways… as a leader I measure success by how well my team achieves various key measures. My personal success is when my team is considered successful by others. b. Where does that measurement stand now? Currently we are exceeding key metrics and a majority of the 18 branches I lead are at or above target for the 4th quarter. c. What actions are you taking to change the measurement(s) (in the right direction)? My goal is to have all branches achieve their goals so for those that are not at...

Words: 1194 - Pages: 5

Free Essay

Hr Job Analysis

...Notes for using the Job Analysis template Job analysis is an in-depth study of a job (not the person in the job). It provides information for job descriptions. In doing the analysis, you will need to gather information about the job, eg by interviewing employees, observing performance of certain tasks, asking employees to fill out questionnaires and worksheets, and collecting information about a job from other sources such as related units of competency. Whatever sources you use to get basic information on what the job entails, the analysis should end up with written results that can be reviewed by the incumbent, or other employees who know the job. During the review, duties, competencies, knowledge, skills, abilities, and other characteristics of the job can be added, deleted or modified. Job analysis is designed to provide a reliable method of quickly and effectively identifying critical competencies (ie knowledge, skills and abilities) and establishing the qualifications for a job or role. The step-by-step process below will assist you to complete a job analysis using the template provided. |Process |Explanation | |Step 1. Understand the job |Start by developing a complete understanding of the position. This is the foundation on which training (and | |including duties and tasks |other human resources processes) is based. The basis...

Words: 822 - Pages: 4

Free Essay

Math and Me

...Math and Me Vanessa Bashore MM212: College Algebra “We both just did out fives yesterday, how can she be doing her sixes already today?” I can remember thinking this like it was yesterday instead of 29 years ago. I was in first grade, and we were doing our times tables. I had been the first one to do all of my numbers so far in the class, and now Sara was up there doing her sixes before I knew them. That would just not do for me, so that night I went home and learned the rest of my numbers, six through nine, to be able to do them for the teacher the very next day. I guess you can say that this is where my love for math started. I am not saying that I never had to study or that I have never struggled with any math in my life, but for the most part, most of the math classes I have taken in my life have come pretty easily to me. I love when you are struggling with something in math and all of a sudden you have that a-ha moment where everything suddenly makes sense. In the past I have taken all the basics in math including Algebra and Geometry. However, these courses were also taken almost 20 years ago, and I have to admit that I am a bit rusty when it comes to all of the formulas and properties. Even though I may not remember all of the formulas, I still consider my previous courses a success. I may not remember the exact formula, but I do remember that the formulas exist and it is just a matter of looking the formula up and plugging in the right numbers to get the correct...

Words: 774 - Pages: 4

Free Essay

Best Workplaces

...profession in or subjects that we feel we are good at. However, all of this means absolutely nothing if we are not satisfied with the environment in which we work. In this assignment I will be discussing three companies from FORTUNE Magazine’s annual ranking of America’s “100 Best Companies to Work For”. I will be describing the work environment of these companies and identifying elements that promote motivation and cohesion among employees in these workplaces. Additionally, I will be relating my observations to materials found in our textbook. The first company that I will be discussing is Dreamworks Animation. According to the about section on their website, “DreamWorks Animation creates high-quality entertainment, including CG animated feature films, television specials and series and live entertainment properties, meant for audiences around the world. The Company has world-class creative talent, a strong and experienced management team and advanced filmmaking technology and techniques” (http://www.dreamworksanimation.com/company) Dreamworks Animation has also made this list of FORTUNE’S best companies to work for, for the last five years. An element within this company that fosters group cohesion is the area in which they work that allows for on campus events and activities that includes friends and family in addition to work colleagues. Throughout the year, Dreamworks...

Words: 903 - Pages: 4

Free Essay

Effective Follower

...particular is effective followers. How does an effective follower work and what does is it that drives them? There are five main characteristics that we are going to focus on for an effective follower and they are: dedication, independent thinker, active in the organization, self-management, and willing to take risks. Dedication is defined as the quality of being dedicated to a task or purpose, but it can also be interchanged with loyalty. An effective follower is someone who a colleague or manager can count on because they know that they will give it one hundred percent when it comes to completing a task. They tend to really believe in what they are doing and that is where the sense of dedication comes from. For example a dedicated employee would be willing to put in the long hours and extra time that it would take to complete a project. Their boss trusts that the work will not be sloppy or incomplete because their loyalty is outstanding. Dedication is very important to being an effective follower. A second important quality is being an independent thinker. In reference to the project example mentioned above an effective follower would be the person who would think outside the box for a solution to a problem. They do not rely on others when contemplating the options. This does not mean that they do not work well in teams. They are perfectly capable of participating in a group, but they do have the ability to work solo on an issue that might arise. It is because of this that they...

Words: 723 - Pages: 3

Premium Essay

How to Handle Resistant Employees Without Coming Out of My Comfort Zone and Stepping over Boundaries

...adding to the complexity is the fact that from time to time the stated reason hides the real deep personal reason. I have learned to recognize that people work through a psychological change process as they give up the old and come to embrace or reject the new. People may experience initial denial, and then begin to realize that the change can’t be ignored. Sometimes strong feelings may emerge, like fear, anger, helplessness and frustration. A person can accept the change either negatively, with feelings of resignation and complacency or positively, with enthusiasm to capitalize on the changes. You should always watch out for the ones who get stuck in one phase, and offer your support. Allow space for people to work through the stages and give them time to breath and listen with empathy. I have learned that there are many reasons why people are resistant to change, the first reason is that the person is in general against or negative towards all that is different or new. They would say things like we just don’t have time for that or its too early or too late for that. The second reason is that the person is not interested in the idea or change, or he/she has other goals that he/she wants to pursue. The third is that the person doesn’t understand the message and/or the consequences that the change will have on his /her work situation. The Forth reason is that the person doesn’t trust the person who communicates the change initiative. The last one is fear, like for example...

Words: 1697 - Pages: 7

Premium Essay

Webcom Assigment

...presentation of Microsoft's New Envisioning Center. What is interesting is the rest of the headline I mean work, play and live which seems like the try to evoke the feeling that it could influence and mainly improve the whole life easily. But it is obvious what the video will be about from the headline I would say. Proairetic code: There is clear storyline and what I found out really interesting, it is amount of examples of new technology working. The whole video is one big example of using technology which consists of smaller examples and we can say presentations. So for me it is examples and presentations what is the most significant point in the proairetic code of this video. Semic code: The first impression on me was big preassure on international expressing of video. A lot of nationalities and actually the family was international as well. Also the family looks happy (probably thanks to new technology) and the man looks really professional in the work. It seems like the expression would have been that successful and happy people use the products. Symbolic code: I found actually just one full-faced symbol and it was the toy of lion when children were working with the new tech. It was trying to show that it is so easy to use that even small child is able to work with that (and actually grandmother as well). Maybe man's cooking apron was symbol of possibility to work (cook) and use the new tech in the same time because the using of new tech "makes the cooking simple"...

Words: 308 - Pages: 2

Free Essay

Xzcxc

...BSP5003 Contemporary Issues in International Political Economy Essay 1 (Part 1) – Marking Criteria Which of the three major theoretical perspectives on International Political Economy (IPE) – i.e. liberalism, mercantilism, and structuralism – best explains the emergence, development and consequences of the major IPE issues in the world today, and why? (1,000 words) 1. Critical Review of a Body of Knowledge (Wider Reading and Criticisms) | Criteria | Achievement* | | A | B | C | D | E | * ------------------------------------------------- Does this work use key readings relevant to the subject – sources may include books, journals and the University’s electronic resources with limited reference to internet sources? | ------------------------------------------------- | ------------------------------------------------- | ------------------------------------------------- | ------------------------------------------------- | ------------------------------------------------- | * ------------------------------------------------- Does the literature on the three major perspectives on IPE include up-to-date material?------------------------------------------------- | ------------------------------------------------- | ------------------------------------------------- | ------------------------------------------------- | ------------------------------------------------- | ------------------------------------------------- | * ------------------------------------------------- ...

Words: 387 - Pages: 2

Free Essay

Ge Case

...1. Jack Welch launched a number of initiatives on taking charge of GE in 1981. Was there a strategy that was the driving force behind the initiatives? Were the initiatives effective in accomplishing what Welch was aiming for? When Welch became the CEO of GE in 1981, the US economy was reeling under recession. The challenge lied before the Welch to set a strategy to remain profitable through the recession and continue to be so. Welch responded by employing a strong strategy supplemented by the necessary structural changes. Welch followed the strategy of “as a unique, high spirited, entrepreneurial enterprise…… the most profitable, highly diversified company on earth with world quality leadership in every one of its product lines.” Clearly, Welch wanted the GE to be entrepreneurial, most profitable, diversified and quality leader this was the driving force behind the initiatives. Welch took the following initiatives, their effectives is tested below: a) Sell of Close – To be most profitable, GE needed to be in the business in which they had leadership and earning profits. And to come out of the businesses which were not profitable. Welch clearly articulated this by guiding to be either #1 of #2 in business of get out of it. As a result, GE sold more than 200 businesses. This initiatives was in perfect line with the strategy. Only by remaining #1 or #2, GE could remain most profitable. b) Diversification – GE made over 370 acquisitions, clearly moving on its strategy...

Words: 963 - Pages: 4

Premium Essay

Farm Girl

...Summary of Farm Girl Anderson Jude ENG 115 Professor Chris Swindell Strayer University October 23rd, 2013 The short story Farm Girl is an in depth look at life through the eyes of a young girl growing up with her family on a farm. Throughout this non-fiction story the author Jessica Hemauer, does an amazing job of describing her surroundings to pull the reader in and make them feel like they are there with her. She begins as a younger girl describing how difficult it is for a child to awake from a deep slumber, and immediately get to work doing jobs some grown men would cringe at. “Cleaning out various huts and pens and laying down fresh straw are part of our daily duties” (Hemauer, 2011 p. 84). She continues by explaining how this is the worst of the jobs she and her siblings endure, and how the dust makes it difficult for them to breathe, but they all know there is no use in complaining because it has to be done (Hemauer, 2011). She continues her story into her teenage years describing vividly the life and struggles of a teenage girl, especially one with so many responsibilities and restrictions. While in eighth grade she describes to the reader how unusual her life is in comparison to her classmates, and how she dislikes not being able to participate in extracurricular activities. However, she finally does get the chance to be normal as she defines it. “In eighth grade I really want to play basketball, and after begging and pleading with my parents, they finally say...

Words: 631 - Pages: 3

Free Essay

Communation

...effectively but sharing formulate though or even options: in addition by sharing each other thoughts which can enhance motivation. When the coworker are talking they must have a respectful and supportive members when they are working with their team members. When a team can cause communication to become effective and ineffective due to the different cultural dissimilar and having the degree in which a person have many different thought of the process. “A team that is a small group with complement skills, who work together to achieve a purpose and hold themselves accountable for it accomplishments” (2007). When there are team remember initiate the same thing and can end up with the same result as being fully effected by talking, listing, and understanding the rules and regulation. All of the member or coworkers must show respect for want of the idea that they share with the group in order to manage responsively. In every single healthcare environment they must are going to have to work together so...

Words: 832 - Pages: 4

Premium Essay

Teams

...put together to work on a task who just don't seem to make the same progress. Your answer as to what a team is may be working together with other people to figure out a problem; and you are exactly correct. Teams are better in some situations, but not necessary needed in all. In fact, they may have some disadvantages that are inappropriate for the work place. Teams typically outperform individuals when the tasks being done require multiple skills, judgment, and experience, but when the individual isn’t a team player, teams are just about as good as the individual himself. (Robbins and DeCenzo 275-84) Many times, teams are often confused with groups. Teams and groups are similar, but not completely. What differentiates both is that in a team, the members are committed to a common purpose, have a set of specific performance goals, and hold themselves equally responsible for the team’s results. A group is individuals working interdependent who come together to reach a particular objective. There are four types of teams that carry different level of effectiveness. They are: a working group, a pseudo team, a potential team, and a real team. In a working group, there is no work or opportunity to engage in that requires a mutual effort, so their performance is strictly based on each own member’s contribution and what they bring to the table. In a pseudo team, the member’s don’t focus on collective performance or have no interest in shaping a common purpose, so their work is poor. In a...

Words: 1091 - Pages: 5