Free Essay

A Co-Evolution Model of Competitive Mobile Platforms

In:

Submitted By reeki
Words 11617
Pages 47
Journal of Theoretical and Applied Electronic Commerce Research ISSN 0718–1876 Electronic Version VOL 6 / ISSUE 2 / AUGUST 2011 / 31-49 © 2011 Universidad de Talca - Chile

This paper is available online at www.jtaer.com DOI: 10.4067/S0718-18762011000200005

A Co-Evolution Model of Competitive Mobile Platforms: Technoeconomic Perspective
Perambur Neelakanta1 and Raef Yassin2
Florida Atlantic University, Department of Computer and Electrical Engineering & Computer Science, 1 neelakan@fau.edu, 2 yassin@fau.edu
Received 13 January 2011; received in revised form 10 April 2011; accepted 18 May 2011

Abstract
A model depicting competitive technoeconomics of business structures specific to mobile-platforms is developed. The underlying co-evolution of large, competing enterprises of mobile-platforms that face customerchurning due to application-preferences and pricing structures in the deregulated ambient is viewed in the perspectives of nonlinear logistic systems akin to that of biological ecosystems. Relevant considerations are decided by and embodied with several stochastically-interacting subsystems. Hence, the temporal dynamics of competition/co-evolution of known competitors in the mobile-platform market, like Android, Symbian and iPhone is depicted by a novel model posing dichotomy of prey-predator flip-flops in the market; and, an asymptotic projection of ex post computations of underlying technoeconomics into the ex ante region would correspond to futuristic forecasts on the performance of test platforms. Further, computed results are exemplified with a sample calculation and associated sensitivity details.

Keywords: Mobile-platform, Co-evolution, Competition, Prey-predator model, Technoeconomic forecasting

31 Perambur Neelakanta Raef Yassin

A Co-Evolution Model of Competitive Mobile Platforms: Technoeconomic Perspective

Journal of Theoretical and Applied Electronic Commerce Research ISSN 0718–1876 Electronic Version VOL 6 / ISSUE 2 / AUGUST 2011 / 31-49 © 2011 Universidad de Talca - Chile

This paper is available online at www.jtaer.com DOI: 10.4067/S0718-18762011000200005

1 Introduction
Developed in this paper is a co-evolution model that describes the growth/decay dynamics across competitive, (mobile-platform)-centric business structures. It is based on relevant analogy of dichotomous prey-predator states observed in bio-ecology; and, the modeling is done to provide an apt description of competitive market structures in Mobile OS industry. Appropriate model-validation of the proposed method is done via a set of data pertinent to realworld competitors in the mobile-platform market, such as Android, Rim and iPhone. An asymptotic projection of underlying technoeconomics into the ex ante region can offer a meaningful forecasting of associated market issues. The mobile platforms mentioned above, broadly refer to the gamut of hardware and software environments developed for smart-phones, handheld devices (like PDAs), tablet computers and other information appliances that are smart by virtue of included embedded systems, and/or other mobile and wireless devices. Typically, iPhone, Android, Symbian, Palm and Windows Mobile are examples of mobile platforms. In essence, a mobile operating system, also known as a mobile OS, a mobile platform, or a handheld operating system, refers to an operating system that controls a mobile device or information appliance. It is based on principles similar to traditional operating systems like Windows, Mac OS, or Linux that control a desktop computer or laptop. But Mobile OS systems are simpler and concerned with wireless versions of broadband and local connectivity, mobile multimedia formats, and different input methods. The mobile OS is conceived to facilitate via software platforms Internet-like end-to-end architectures in digital mobile environment. This Internet-mobile convergence inculcates an open and modular concept in the Internet architecture outmoding the classical, closed and integrated architectures of the telecommunication company (telco). Thus, unlike classical telecommunication, modern and/or next-generation perspectives of telco industry including mobile platforms portray a digital ecosystem [1]-[2], [11]-[12]. Admob [3]-[4] has recently released a report giving details on mobile Internet usage across the world and it points out that in the recent past usage of smartphones has surged and accounts for maximum mobile usage [14]-[15].

1.1

Evolution of Technoeconomic Systems: Bio-system Analogy

The concept of biological ecology rightly fits to describe the temporal evolution of technoeconomics [5]-[6], [18] in systems like telecommunication companies (telcos) that include Mobile OS services. That is, the relationships that exist inherently between and among organisms in a biological ecosystem can be analogously adopted to model the technoeconomics of the systems that represent a community composed of multiple, independent individuals and/or organizations (enterprises) sharing a common, business-centric mission and responsibility. Relevant efforts, at least partly apply to automated and intelligent workflows, for example in mobile platform context, securely exchanging protected information and optimally using digital media. Further, seamless functioning as a single, dynamic and complex unit with no single subunit being totally in charge in controlling the process is implicit in such operations. More so, similar to biological ecosystems that model the inter-relatedness of various interactions among biological species, the information technology (IT) and/or Mobile-OS centric industries and businesses also fit into an intersection of variety of social, economic, and even political ecosystems. The biotic components depicting species like plants, animals, bacteria etc. of the bio-ecosystem correspond to endogenous factors in the technoeconomics of systems implemented or produced from, within the IT-centric computational/communication efforts. They refer to all variables that are determined within the model. Contrast to endogenous variable, an exogenous variable is directly amenable for manipulation by the programmer/service provider; and, in a broad sense such exogenous considerations can be equated to the abiotic influences of the bio system such as the habitat (ponds, lakes, sea, desert etc.) and weather features like temperature, rain, snow etc. In general, considering the cyber infrastructure of telecommunications supporting IT, it is often attempted to comprehend how the data (information) flows along many steps in a chain and across vagaries of interactive steps (protocols). Self-organizing tug-of-war of goal-seeking computational iterations controls the rate of growth analogues to say, photosynthesis in biological sense of ecology; and corresponding rate of fall/decay is similar to biological decomposition. Further, the rate at which resources of interacting units are reused in telco context corresponds to recycling of nutrients in biosystems and retiring selectively of obsolete and redundant components across telco network is akin to natural selection in biology.

1.2

Scope of the Present Study

The present paper exclusively addresses an example case-study and feasibility of modeling of the growth/decay dynamics of competitive (mobile-platform)-centric systems in terms of technoeconomic considerations specified via observed traffic shares. Relevant evolution and devolution issues are modelled using the bio-ecology analog of dichotomous prey-predator growth dynamics [5]-[6], [18]. Hence the conceived scope of this study converges to address the following deliverables described in the subsequent sections: 32 Perambur Neelakanta Raef Yassin

A Co-Evolution Model of Competitive Mobile Platforms: Technoeconomic Perspective

Journal of Theoretical and Applied Electronic Commerce Research ISSN 0718–1876 Electronic Version VOL 6 / ISSUE 2 / AUGUST 2011 / 31-49 © 2011 Universidad de Talca - Chile • • • • • • • •

This paper is available online at www.jtaer.com DOI: 10.4067/S0718-18762011000200005

Viewing the digital mobile communication platforms analogous to evolving biological ecosystems Identifying specific mobile platform services that had faced in the recent past, dynamically varying technoeconomic performance in their operations Marking the events of ups and downs in the technoeconomic performance of the businesses across the aforesaid temporal dynamics Developing a nonlinear system model to describe the underlying dynamics Introducing dichotomous (flip-flop) evolution (growth) and devolution (decay) considerations in the dynamics pursued Using real-world economic data available (on Symbian, Android, iPhone etc.), validating the model developed Presenting a discussion on the heuristics of the theoretical model developed, which conforms to real-world technoeconomic performance details Making relevant conclusions on the observations made.

2 Co-evolution of Competitive Mobile OS Business Structures
The conceived pursuit of modeling the business structure of mobile digital communication in a competitive market ambient is based on co-evolution concept described below. For example, it is possible to consider the growth prospects of mobile platform industry, where, relevant (growth) parameters refer to the underlying techno- and/or technoeconomic-centric considerations and activities. Such activities normally involve both activity-reinforcing and activity-impeding processes negotiated by (augmentative and annihilating) information-flow between interacting subunits controlled by the associated cybernetics of self-organizing mechanism [7] dictating the technical/business progress (or deterioration) of co-existing units. The growth/decay then conforms to co-evolution considerations [11], [16]. Co-evolution in Nature refers to a joint progression of evolution/growth of closely-associated and coexisting species. Mostly such co-evolution is competitive and in a broader sense involves predator–prey relationships with an evolutionary advance in the predator, for instance, triggering an evolutionary response in the prey. Often, such preypredator states may also flip-flop along the time-scale. It is attempted in this study to model the aforesaid coevolution paradigm with a dichotomous pre-predator suite applied to competing Mobile OS environment involving nonlinear logistics similar to relevant biological ecosystem considerations. In this perspective, the proposed model in this study conforms to a complex system embodied with several stochastically interacting subsystems; and, the model is specifically applied to describe the technoeconomic co-evolution fitted to competitive corporate businesses like mobile platforms [5]-[6], [18]. Further, telco-like enterprises can be viewed as complex systems as indicated by Neelakanta and Deecharoenkul [9]. Relevant evolution models that can be ascribed to these business structures portray the growth and futuristic welfare of the industry in conformance to the prevailing competitive market vis-à-vis the underlying application needs/demands, service expansions, revenue growth, decision-making strategies and customer population/preferences etc. Also, pertinent to the cyberspace of Mobile OS service provisioning, the co-evolution models can lead to predicting the survival of underlying businesses implicated by interacting and competing aspects of customer expectations, variety in services (applications), compliance with government regulations, relative customer-churning, revenue/return-on-investment (RoI) etc. In short, developed in this study is an algorithmic approach that describes the stochastical growth of (mobileplatform)-centric technoeconomics as a co-evolution paradigm under a competitive environment involving a dichotomous pre-predator suite. Three Mobile OS competitors, for example, are modeled as dichotomous structures that switch randomly to the role of being prey-to-predator (or vice versa) along the time-scale based on ad hoc decisions invoked by the participant competitors This alternating or flip-flopping dispositions of dichotomy between prey- and predator-states in an observed time-frame considered as the ex post regime is expected to offer an asymptotic projection of relevant technoeconomics by forecasting the performance in the ex ante region of the timescale. Proposed strategy is justified with real-world mobile platform data available in a competitive market structure.

2.1

Co-evolution of Competing Species

The co-evolution paradigm attributed to technoeconomic context described in [11] and [16] is based on the following principle: Considering the dynamics of two competing species say, two corporations A and B, it can be expressed by 33 Perambur Neelakanta Raef Yassin

A Co-Evolution Model of Competitive Mobile Platforms: Technoeconomic Perspective

Journal of Theoretical and Applied Electronic Commerce Research ISSN 0718–1876 Electronic Version VOL 6 / ISSUE 2 / AUGUST 2011 / 31-49 © 2011 Universidad de Talca - Chile

This paper is available online at www.jtaer.com DOI: 10.4067/S0718-18762011000200005

a coupled system of (two) logistic relations. They specify the onset of activation (or expanding) phase being followed by a state of inhibition (or contracting) phase in the evolution (growth/decay) prospects of both corporate businesses. This can be explained as follows: In a non-competitive situation, any expansion (positive evolution or growth) trend of a corporate business is decided by the existing (current) levels of consumers supporting the underlying business activity and the prevailing growth rate; however, resource limitations may bring the system to a contracting phase implicated by supply-demand considerations. Hence, the growth will level off eventually. The same description applies, if a stand-alone business begins with a decaying (devolutionary) trend due to poor corporate decisions, it may settle down at an asymptotic minimum level; or, with timely prudent decisions may allow the business to take a positive growth-trend. That is, in the event of a competitive ambient between two businesses A and B, the evolving (or devolving) trends will be dictated by the intervening smart and crucial decisions taken by both parties vis-à-vis phases of competitive market situations driven by the competitors. Then, the theory of equality would apply in presuming that each decision made by a competing enterprise is as good, intelligent and rational as that of other competing units. As such, any evolutionary prospects of a corporation and the decisions made are often confronted with the odds of competitor’s ploys consistent with decisions and evolutionary aspects of that competitor. Thus, in a competitive business environment, the associated evolutionary considerations may follow a dichotomous prey-predator paradigm with an alternating role (state) of being a prey or a predator (or vice versa) assumed by each of the two competing corporations, A and B. Predator-state OL profile

B
Prey-state

G(t)

A
OL

OL

profile

T1

Time (t)

T2

Figure 1: Growth function G(t) displaying the random flip-flop (dichotomous) states of two corporate species A and B The dichotomy of states is modeled as the biological predator/prey (or vice versa) competition. The profiles of predator-state and prey-state are bounded between an upper level (Gmax) and a lower level (Gmin) respectively. The dynamics of evolutions (or devolutions) in the business profiles of A and B may overlap and this refractory region is indicated as OL. T1 and T2 are event-specific instants (epochs) at which the state transition takes place. The dynamics of temporal evolutions (or devolutions) specified by a function G(t) as regard to the competing business profiles of A and B can be illustrated as in Figure 1. Essentially, the occurrence of dichotomy (flip-flop) of states makes the corporate species A and B to assume the role of a predator or prey (or vice versa). Such flip-flops are event-specific and are randomly disposed. That is, based on the business strategies of the corporations and customer reaction, for example, the state reversal would occur at two epochs T1 and T2 as shown in Figure 1. Suppose A has made some smart decisions aggressive enough to be designated as a predator at a certain instant of time, pushing its business activity into a positive trait of evolution. Then, as a consequence, the competitor B becomes a prey and may suffer thereof market-losses indicated by a devolutionary trend in its business. However, at a later phase/instant of this downward market-trend, competitor B as mentioned earlier may exercise some business changes through prudent decisions that counter the market-losses; hence, its devolutionary trend may shift its slope to positive side and becomes evolutionary. That is, the competitor B emerges out of its role of being a prey and proceeds to be a predator. As a result, now the market of A may start showing a downward trend and therefore, will start assuming a status of being a prey. This flip-flopping dichotomy along the time-scale would continue until an equilibrium of both (A and B) finding sustained markets is reached; or one (or both!) corporations may go out of business. The flip-flop model of Figure 1 is indicated to describe the competitive growth dynamics of digital subscriber lines (DSL) in the context New Zealand’s Telecom [11]-[16]. The concept of dichotomy in state-reversal of prey-to-predator (or vice versa) as characterized by Neelakanta and Sardenberg in [11] is summarized below: • • The state reversal (flip-flop) occurs randomly: With the corporate structures indicated above, this translates to unexpected epochs of service strategies implemented by A or B via their decision ploys The duration of being in a particular state by A or B is also nondeterministic

34 Perambur Neelakanta Raef Yassin

A Co-Evolution Model of Competitive Mobile Platforms: Technoeconomic Perspective

Journal of Theoretical and Applied Electronic Commerce Research ISSN 0718–1876 Electronic Version VOL 6 / ISSUE 2 / AUGUST 2011 / 31-49 © 2011 Universidad de Talca - Chile •

This paper is available online at www.jtaer.com DOI: 10.4067/S0718-18762011000200005

However, the deployment of decision-policy and changes in the service structure can be expected from A or B when the market of individual corporation shows a downward trend with revenue losses or when the market trend shows a positive direction with increases in revenue In the dichotomy of states of A and B observed, there could be overlapping refractory time-frames marked as OL in Figure 1.



Careful handling of technoeconomics in competing businesses and industries such as in Mobile OS context would require diligent planning and prudent approaches. Further, in the context of competitive and deregulated environment, meaningful forecasts on technological needs as well as financial necessities are crucial so as to sustain the well being of the industry through retention of a satisfied customer base with a willingness-to-pay (WP) attitude as well as for realizing a comfortable return-on-investment (RoI) [8]. Consistent analytical considerations and computational pursuits of the model on the dynamics of competitive technoeconomic evolution are developed here on the basis of a practical set of (real-world) data observed in mobile platform market. Since the model indicated is specific to the data set already observed, it conforms to the ex post regime of time; and using this growth model, a forecast strategy can be exercised to project the business economics into the ex ante time-frame.

3 Dynamics of Technoeconomic Growth Function
Again considering the technoeconomic evolution as a function of time, relevant growth model of the dynamics G(t) versus t, can be specified in terms of G(t) expressed as a nonlinear logistic function of time. Such nonlinear prescriptions are adopted in classical models mostly using empirical considerations as described by Neelakanta and Baeza in [8]. However, representation via rigorous analytical considerations of an evolutionary phenomenon infested with random inputs should also duly account for the interaction of associated stochastic parameters. Conceiving such a model was originally developed by Neelakanta and De Groff as presented in [10]. It refers to the context of neural information growth and the corresponding growth function G(t) is expressed in [10] via the so-called BernoulliLangevin function, LQ(t), (which will be detailed later). Further, the concept of using G(t) ≡ LQ(t) to describe the growth dynamics in technoeconomics context has been posted by Neelakanta and Baeza as an exercise in [8]. As a sequel, Neelakanta and Sardenberg have exemplified in [13] a model depicting customer reaction to Internet pricing. Subsequently, description of the growth/decay processes using G(t) ≡ LQ(t) has been judiciously adopted in [11] and [16] in the context of technoeconomic business structures by analogously equating the underlying evolutionary dynamics to those encountered in biological systems. The model of [11] and [16] describes the competitive growth dynamics of digital subscriber lines (DSL) in the service structure of New Zealand’s Telecom mentioned earlier. Currently, the analytical format of G(t) ≡ LQ(t) is again adopted to model the competitive business economics of Mobile OS systems following the procedure reported in [11] and [16]. The approach pursued thereof is as follows: In a competitive technoeconomic structure, the growth/decay dynamics would normally involve variables pertinent to a set of endogenous parameters similar to biotic parameters in the bio-ecosystem; and, a set of exogenous variables akin to abiotic influences as defined by Neelakanta and Sardenberg in [13] and elaborated in [16]. Broadly, such variables can be specified as follows: (i) Endogenous variable set that impedes the growth: {uIN(t)}i i = 1, 2, …, I; (ii) exogenous variable set that impedes the growth: {uIX(t)}j j = 1, 2, …, J; (iii) endogenous variable set that promotes the growth: {vPN(t)}k k = 1, 2, …, K; and (iv) exogenous variable set that promotes the growth: {vPX(t)} = 1, 2, …, L. The underlying growth regulation is decided by a pair of controllers, one exercising antagonistic (impeding) influence via negative information-flux or entropy and the other providing promoting actions (via positive information or negentropic flow); and, the interacting control dynamics on the net data-flow would eventually cause a logistic growth profile for G(t). That is, the interacting subsets being themselves invariably nonlinear functions of independent variables involved, a change observed in any of the functions (for a given incremental change in the independent variable) would largely depend on the already prevailing value of that function [7]-[10]. Further, the variables in question could be largely stochastical and partly deterministic. As such, a stochastical (nonlinear) differential equation can be specified for the dynamics under discussion; and, the resulting solution for G(t), as indicated before, would correspond to the Bernoulli-Langevin function, LQ(t) as specified by Neelakanta and De Groff in [7] and [10]. Explicitly LQ(t) is given by (1 + 1/2Q)coth[(1 + 1/2Q)t] − (1/2Q)coth[(1/2Q)t]. Further, when Q = ½, LQ =1/2(t) = tanh(t), which defines the upper-bound on the disorder; and, as Q → ∞, LQ → ∞(t) = [coth(t) − (1/t)], which corresponds to the lower-bound of the disorder statistic. Also in the limiting case as Q → 0, LQ → 0(t) = sgn(t) depicting the scenario wherein the participant subsystems do not interact with each other. Further, the function LQ(t) describes the logistic growth in the context of stochastical variables being present with the stochastic feature of disorder set by Q. That is, the associated statistical disorder is dictated by Q; and Q is limited to the range (1/2 < Q < ∞). In terms of the theory of interaction statistics [7] and [10], (1/2 < Q < ∞) explicitly decides the extent of nonlinear interaction. Such interactions span the regime of disorder being totally isotropic when Q → ½; and when the randomness corresponds to being totally anisotropic, Q→ ∞. Lastly, when Q→ 0, it implies a total non-interaction (that is, mutually non-relying) state of the parameters/variables that globally decide the underlying activity. Lastly, the Bernoulli-Langevin function has a slope that ranges from 1 to 1/3 at the origin corresponding to the range of Q between 1/2 to ∞. 35 Perambur Neelakanta Raef Yassin

A Co-Evolution Model of Competitive Mobile Platforms: Technoeconomic Perspective

Journal of Theoretical and Applied Electronic Commerce Research ISSN 0718–1876 Electronic Version VOL 6 / ISSUE 2 / AUGUST 2011 / 31-49 © 2011 Universidad de Talca - Chile

This paper is available online at www.jtaer.com DOI: 10.4067/S0718-18762011000200005

In formulating the nonlinear growth of G(t), it is also necessary to consider certain exogenously-infused variables that may influence implicitly the growth or decay in addition to the functional sets: {uIN(G, t), uIX(G, t)} and {vPN(G, t), vPX(G, t)} mentioned earlier. Again, such influences could either be favoring or retarding the growth (or decay) along the time-frame of observation and are depicted as PX(t) and RX(t) respectively. Hence, derived in [13], [16] is a nonlinear differential equation that describes the (exogenous and endogenous) data-balance relations in the concerned system; and, by applying the chain-rule of total differentiation on the variables, relevant dynamics of G(t) is deduced as follows:

⎧ ∂G ∂vPN ⎫ ⎧ ∂G ∂vPX ⎫ ⎧ ∂G ∂u IN ⎫ ⎧ ∂G ∂u IX ⎫ × × × × ⎨ ⎬+⎨ ⎬ ⎨ ⎬+⎨ ⎬ ∂t ⎭ ⎩ ∂vPX ∂t ⎭ ⎩ ∂uIN ∂t ⎭ ⎩ ∂u IX ∂t ⎭ dG(t) ⎩ ∂vPN = − ⎡ ⎧ ∂FX ⎫⎤ ⎡ ⎧ ∂FX ⎫⎤ dt ⎢1 − ⎨ ∂G ⎬⎥ ⎢1 − ⎨ ∂G ⎬⎥ ⎭⎦ ⎭⎦ ⎣ ⎩ ⎣ ⎩

(1)

⎡ ⎧ ∂F ⎫⎤ ⎡ ⎧ ∂P ∂R ⎫⎤ where, ⎢1 − ⎨ X ⎬⎥ ≡ ⎢1 − ⎨ X − X ⎬⎥ and, the entity (PX – RX) is jointly set equal to FX considering the heuristics ∂G ⎭⎦ ⎣ ⎩ ∂G ⎭⎦ ⎣ ⎩ ∂G that the net result of superposed nonlinear functions is itself nonlinear [7], [10]. The algorithm of Equation (1) adopted in [13] and [16] is applied exclusively in the present study to describe the dynamics of mobile platform economics. Again, as described in [16], the associated nonlinear functions of Equation (1) are expressed via Bernoulli-Langevin function as indicated below:

FX (G) = Lq (G); G(u IX ) = Lq (u IX ); G(u IN ) = Lq (u IN ); G(vPX ) = Lq (vPX ) and G uIX uIN vPX G(vPN ) = Lq (vPN ) where L (•) denotes the Bernoulli-Langevin function with qs being the order parameter (≡ qs vPN Q) for the governing function indexed by the subscript s and this subscript s stands for G, vPN, vPX, uIN or uIX as appropriate. With necessary simplifications, Equation (1) can be rewritten as follows:
That is,
∂v ∂u dG(t) ∂v ∂u = ⎡ Aq ⎤ PN + ⎡ Bq ⎤ PX − ⎡Cq ⎤ IN − ⎡ Dq ⎤ IX ⎣ ⎦ ∂t ⎣ ⎦ ∂t ⎣ ⎦ ∂t ⎣ ⎦ ∂t dt

(2)

where,
IX

Aqs = L'qv

PN

(vPN ) / [1 − L'qG (G)];

Bqs = L'qv

PX

(vPX ) / [ 1 − L'qG (G)];

Cqs = L'qu (uIN ) / [ 1 − L'qG (G)];
IN

Dqs = L'qu (u IX ) / [ 1 − L'qG (G)]. The prime on the functions indicates differentiation with respect to the argument. As per Equation (2), the net growth of information flux (G) promoted (or demoted) is implicitly dictated by the dynamics (that is, the rate of change) of the quantities: vPN, vPX, uIN and uIX; and, each of these rates is weighted appropriately by a nonlinear coefficient of the set {Aqs, Bqs, Cqs, Dqs}. Further, it can be observed that all these coefficients as seen, are in a general form, L'q ρ (θ)/[1 − L'qκ ( φ )] where ρ and κ denote the index s as appropriate and the set {θ, φ } represents the variables involved as arguments. Hence, for any arbitrary value of qs ≡ Q between the states of disorder extremum, the coefficients Aqs, Bqs, Cqs and Dqs are decided by Lqs (x: θ, φ) and its derivative with respect to the argument. It is indicated in [13] and [16] that L′qs(x: α, β) would incline to follow approximately, 1 z(qs ; x: θ, φ , ...) law where z is a simple, arbitrary first-order function of its independent variables, namely, (qs; x: α, β, ...). The functional trend of 1 z(qs ; x: θ, φ , ...) shows that the dependence of the function L′qs(x: θ, φ) on (qs; x: θ, φ) is significantly influenced for low values of the associated independent variables (qs; x: θ, φ). Further, it would asymptotically tend to zero for large values of the arguments, (x: θ, φ). Also, for a random set of (qs; x: θ, φ), the nonlinear aspect Lqs(x: θ, φ) versus stochastic variations in the regulatory variables would be significant and therefore, will be jagged for the low-range of qs between (1/2 and ∞). However, at larger levels of such influences, the perceived variations would tend to cease depicting more or less an invariant state of Lqs(.) asymptotically reaching the terminal statistics of steady-state. The limiting trends as above indicate that the coefficients in question may significantly influence the underlying processes only for low values of the associated independent variables (qs; x: θ and φ); and, these coefficient functions would asymptotically tend to zero for large values of their arguments. Physically, this implies that the variability in the nonlinear aspect of the rate of change in regulatory variables would be significant for levels of endogenous and/or exogenous influences present during the early stages of temporal discourse of G(t). However, at a later stage, that is, towards terminal dynamics of G(t), such variations would tend to cease showing more or less an invariant state of flow of the participant fluxes involved. Hence, as dictated by the statistics of endogenous and exogenous variables, jagged variations can be observed in real-world technoeconomic growth during the initial phases of G(t). This initial phase observed in the market can be regarded as the so-called ex post regime of system economics. However in practice, it is also of interest to know the growth profile that lies ahead. This amounts to forecasting, which is necessary so as to be prepared with resources in order to meet future demands in the market. 36 Perambur Neelakanta Raef Yassin

A Co-Evolution Model of Competitive Mobile Platforms: Technoeconomic Perspective

Journal of Theoretical and Applied Electronic Commerce Research ISSN 0718–1876 Electronic Version VOL 6 / ISSUE 2 / AUGUST 2011 / 31-49 © 2011 Universidad de Talca - Chile

This paper is available online at www.jtaer.com DOI: 10.4067/S0718-18762011000200005

This period of interest lying ahead denotes an ex ante regime and it mostly implies the terminal statistics of the growth function under consideration [8]. In summary, based on the details of [13] and [16], the governing stochastical differential equations of Equations (1) and (2) of the underlying evolutionary process (growth process) yield convergent solutions that can be expressed in normalized scale in terms of the function LQ(t). The associated stochastic feature is set by the temporal disorder, Q. Likewise, a time-dependent decay process can be described by the function [1 − LQ(t)] in normalized scale. Hence, the phenomenon of competitive evolution (growth) or devolution (decay) between A and B as indicated in [11] and [16] can be specified by the following dichotomous functional relations: GA or B(t)|Growth = {αiLQA(t) × Yti(t) + βi[1 − LQB(t)] × Yti + τi(t)}, GA or B(t)|Decay = {γj[1 − LQA(t)] × Ytj + τj(t) + δjLQB(t) × Ytj (t)}, (t ≥ 0) (t ≥ 0) (3)

Where i and j are discrete instants where dichotomous transitions (flip-flopping) of prey/predator states occur and (τi and τi) denote shifts in time-scale with respect to ti and tj at which the transitions take place. Further, the set {αi, βi, γj, δj} depicts the extents (levels) of evolution (growth) or devolution (decay) at the transitions. Thus, Equation (3) is a quantitative portrayal of Fig. 1. Further, considering the technoeconomics of competitive industry, the elements in the coefficient-set {αi, βi, γj, δj} are implicitly decided by the endogenous and exogenous parameters, namely {uIN, uIX}, {vPN, vPX} and FX; and, Equation (3) depicting the dynamics of growth (or decay) of A and B denotes a doublystochastic process. That is, in the absence of dichotomous flipping, suppose the evolution and devolution states are denoted respectively by a nonlinear set corresponding to the growth-function, f(t) → LQ(t) and the decay-function, g(t) → [1 − LQ(t)]. Then, with the superposition of random dichotomous (flip-flop) transitions denoted by switching functions (signum functions), Yt(t) and Yt + τ(t) on A and B, the dynamics of A and B is specified either as: GA(t) = f(t) × Yt(t) and GB(t) = g(t) × Yt + τ(t); or as, GA(t) = f(t) × Yt + τ(t) and GB(t) = g(t) × Yt(t). Equation (3) formalizes this switching or state transition features.

4 Model Verification with Real-world Mobile Platform Data
With reference to real-world data concerning traffic share in US by Mobile OS platforms (of iPhone, Android and Symbian), the efficacy of the proposed model is verified in this study. Relevant data used in the computations refers to AdMob details on smartphone market as reported in [3]-[4], [14]-[15] and [17]. The data indicated therein illustrates relative competition between the Mobile OS devices in sharing the traffic with a flip-flop trend. A summary of the traffic/market trends of these devices are as follows: • • Competitively iPhone and Android share the market-climbing concurrent to a rapid increase in mobile webbrowsing traffic. iPhone versus Android conform to two-horse smart-phone OS race, which implies a flip-flopping dichotomy in their market structure in traffic sharing. With the launch of iPhone 3G in 2008, for example, the iPhone market share quickly arose with a peak at the release of the iPhone 3GS. Correspondingly, the launch of new Android devices (as well as Palm’s webOS-based Pre), took some of the wind out of the iPhone’s sails at least temporarily. Relatively, the traffic shares of RIM and Windows Mobile have remained low due to rapid market- growths experienced by Android and iPhone.



Typical real-world data on actual profiles of Mobile OS traffic-share in US as available in [3]-[4], [14]-[15] and [17] are presented in Figure 2. It depicts actual profiles of the traffic-shares (in %) borne by Symbian, iPhone and Android over, a time-period of 16 months, from October 2008 through February 2010. This traffic-share is considered in the present study as an implicit economic index of growth (or decay) of underlying businesses. Further, shown in Figure 3, is a normalized version of Figure 2 where the traffic-share on y-axis is calibrated to depict the relative traffic-share of relevant Mobile OS devices; and, the x-axis extends from 0 to 1 covering the 16 months involved. The reason for considering the normalized profiles (Figure 3) is to track the dynamics of the growth/decay function consistent with Equation (3) where the model is based on the sigmoid LQ(t), which converges in its asymptotic limit to 1; that is, as t → ∞, LQ(t) → 1. Normalized data may, however, apparently restrict the model to describe the evolution/devolution for relative comparison only. On the other hand, once such relative comparison is elucidated by the present method, the actual growth/decay performance (in absolute scale) can be decided by denormalizing the results inasmuch as the normalization is done linearly using a constant weight. From the dynamics of ups and downs in the traffic-share in Figures 2 and 3, one can also identify distinct points of inflexion (shown with a circle) wherever the slope of the growth-curve markedly changes. These points are identified here as epochs and are indicated in Figs. 2 and 3 as the epoch-set {a, b, c, …, g}. 37 Perambur Neelakanta Raef Yassin

A Co-Evolution Model of Competitive Mobile Platforms: Technoeconomic Perspective

Journal of Theoretical and Applied Electronic Commerce Research ISSN 0718–1876 Electronic Version VOL 6 / ISSUE 2 / AUGUST 2011 / 31-49 © 2011 Universidad de Talca - Chile

This paper is available online at www.jtaer.com DOI: 10.4067/S0718-18762011000200005

Months OCT 08 DEC 08 FEB 09 APR 09 JUN 09 AUG 09 OCT 09 DEC 09 FEB 10

80 Actual traffic-share (%) (Economic growth-factor) 40 iPhone

Symbian

0 a b

Android

c d e Epochs (Marked as ) f g

Figure 2: Mobile OS traffic-shares in the USA

38 Perambur Neelakanta Raef Yassin

A Co-Evolution Model of Competitive Mobile Platforms: Technoeconomic Perspective

Journal of Theoretical and Applied Electronic Commerce Research ISSN 0718–1876 Electronic Version VOL 6 / ISSUE 2 / AUGUST 2011 / 31-49 © 2011 Universidad de Talca - Chile Normalized time (t/tM) (Sixteen months: October 08 – February 10) 0 OCT 08 DEC 08 1.0 Normalized traffic-share (Economic growth-factor) 0.5 FEB 09 APR 09 0.5 JUN 09 AUG 09 OCT 09

This paper is available online at www.jtaer.com DOI: 10.4067/S0718-18762011000200005

1.0 FEB 10 DEC 09

iPhone

Symbian

Android

0 a b

c d e Epochs (Marked as ) f g

Figure 3: Normalized profiles of mobile OS traffic-shares in the USA Table 1: Competing mobile OS platforms: A chronological summary of marketed Items across the period October 2008 to February 2010 Mobile OS company Epoch: Introduction in the market of the Device/Application Beta version OS 3.0 3GS Android 2.0 OS Update Droid Google Nexes One Date Epoch designation: As in Figs. 3 and 4 C de f fg g

iPhone iPhone Android Motorola Android

March 2009 June 2009 October 2009 November 2009 January 2010

In Figure 2, the profiles indicate actual traffic-shares in percentage by Symbian, iPhone and Android from October 2008 to February 2010 [3]-[4], [14]-[15], [17]. Figure 3 is the normalized version of Figure 2. The total period of tm equal to 16 months (from October 2008 to February 2010) is normalized on the x-axis with a time-scale, t from 0 to 1. Salient epochs are indicated by circles. With reference to the profiles of traffic-shares indicated in Figures 2 and 3, relevant logic behind the flip-flops (depicting growth/decay dichotomy) can be explained in terms of business ploys and/or new devices/applications introduced by the competing species. For this purpose, presented in Table 1 is a 39 Perambur Neelakanta Raef Yassin

A Co-Evolution Model of Competitive Mobile Platforms: Technoeconomic Perspective

Journal of Theoretical and Applied Electronic Commerce Research ISSN 0718–1876 Electronic Version VOL 6 / ISSUE 2 / AUGUST 2011 / 31-49 © 2011 Universidad de Talca - Chile

This paper is available online at www.jtaer.com DOI: 10.4067/S0718-18762011000200005

summary vis-à-vis the observations in Figures 2 and 3. The model developed in this paper and presented via Equation (3) can be validated against the details of Figures 2 and 3 consistent with the business epochs described in Table 1. Relevant considerations can be identified in terms of the following temporal history: • In the growth/decay profile dictated by Equation (3), the dichotomy in switching a state is signaled by the growth(or decay) function showing a saturation (flat temporal trend), namely, dG(t)/dt → 0 where G(t) depicts explicitly, GA or GB(t)|Growth/Decay of Equation (3) for two competitors A and B The epoch(s) designated as above via dG(t)/dt → 0 may remain sustained approximately over a (short) time-duration shown as overlapping regimes (OL) in Figure 1 at which either or both competitors would introduce new promotion ploys or withdraw any existing incentives Suppose the initial slope of G(t) at the commencement of growth or decay is written as, mo = [dG(t)/dt]t → starttime. It is (randomly) decided by the endogenous and exogenous technoeconomic inputs. Further, the corresponding regulation of evolution (or devolution) may face an intense (or significantly observable), jagged variations in the dynamic activity, mostly during the nascent stages of commencement of the processes involved. As such, the entities, namely, QA and QB of the Bernoulli-Langevin function in Equation (3) that control the initial slope of G(t) are considered as non-deterministic random variables in the simulations, but within the specified range of (1/2 to ∞) Suppose at t = 0, the competition between A and B commences such that GA(t) is evolving (growing) and GB(t) is devolving (decaying). This dynamics places A in predator status and B in prey status; and, the corresponding models due to Equation (3) are specified by: GA(t)|Growth = {αiLQA(t)} and G B(t)|Decay = {βi[1 − LQB(t)]}, (t ≥ 0) respectively. At a certain instant (t + τ) of epoch in the stretch of OLR regime suppose a state-transition is invoked. This makes A and B to flip their roles with GA |Decay = {γj[1 − LQA(t)]} and GB(t)|Growth = {δjLQB(t)}, (t + τ ≥ 0). Such dichotomous dynamics would progress ahead with the flip-flops of evolutionary/devolutionary states of A and B along the time-scale of interest







In the studies presented in [11] and [16], it is indicated that at each reversal of state indicated above, “the evolving (devolving) species will try to assume and follow the gradient-trend of its opponent in the episode prior to the change of the state”. This statement can be illustrated as shown in Figures 4(a) and 4(b).

(a) QBI B QBII

Relative technoeconomic parameter

A QAI QAII t

Timeframe I

Timeframe II

Figure 4 (a): Illustration of evolving (devolving) species: Zero-sum payoff condition

40 Perambur Neelakanta Raef Yassin

A Co-Evolution Model of Competitive Mobile Platforms: Technoeconomic Perspective

Journal of Theoretical and Applied Electronic Commerce Research ISSN 0718–1876 Electronic Version VOL 6 / ISSUE 2 / AUGUST 2011 / 31-49 © 2011 Universidad de Talca - Chile

This paper is available online at www.jtaer.com DOI: 10.4067/S0718-18762011000200005

(b) QBI B QBII Relative technoeconomic parameter

QAII QAI A Timeframe I Timeframe II

t

Figure 4(b): Illustration of evolving (devolving) species: Non-zero sum payoff condition In Figure 4, the evolving (devolving) species that try to assume and follow the gradient-trend of its opponent in the episode prior to the change of the state is illustrated. Figure 4(a) refers to the case of zero-sum payoff condition, for example QBII tracking QAI and Figure 4 (b) refers to condition, for example non-zero sum payoff condition with, for example the dominance of A over B. (Details as in the text). Further, in Figure 4, suppose in an arbitrary time-frame I, A (predator) is evolving and its QA-value is designated as QAI; correspondingly, B (prey) is devolving with its QBvalue designated as QBI. These Q-values decide the initial slope (mo) of the growth/decay curves [7], [10]. That is, the gradient-trends of A and B can be implicitly specified by the Langevin function logistics expressed in terms of QA and QB values respectively; and, the parameter Q is related to mo as follows [7], [10]: mo = (1/3)(1 + 1/Q). Considering the dichotomy of state-transitions from prey-to-predator or vice versa across the temporal dynamics, the progress of evolution of a participant species currently assuming, say the role of a predator in the context of competitive prey-to-predator bio-ecology [16], [18] would track the progress of evolution (in the prior of time-frame) of the competing species currently playing the role of a prey. This track history is decided by two conditions of gametheoretic payoff. Payoff is what results from each combination of strategies/decisions (alternatives) adopted or courses of action taken by the participants in the market) [8]: Condition 1: A zero-sum payoff status implies that the sum of payoffs for any choice of alternatives of decisions by the competitors is zero. For example, in the case of two participants A and B, if one gains profit, the other meets a loss of equal extent for each outcome; and, condition 2: The status of non-zero sum payoff implies an assured dominance of one competitor against the other. It depends on the proportion of efforts of a dominating species so as to get advantageous edge on its disposition (such as monotonically growing revenue) by invoking appropriate alternatives. Relevant payoff dominance would imply that a higher-paying alternative is said to dominate the lower one. Hence, based on the observed initial slopes of G(t) pertinent to A or B choice of QA and QB is made (in the range 1/2 to ∞) consistent with game-theoretic considerations indicated above and described in [16]. Relevant theorem based on competitive bio-ecology principles is also enunciated and proved in [16]. In summary, as per Condition 1, the ex ante profile of growth (or decay) trend of an incumbent species posterior to a state-transition would track the ex post profile of growth (or decay) trend of the competitor species prior to the statetransition (and vice versa). Hence, the outcome of this game is that asymptotically, the progress of dichotomy of states will continue until each state assuming a stability of its own. With reference to Condition 2, the ex ante profile of growth (or decay) trend of an incumbent species posterior to a state-transition will be autonomous and independent of the ex post profile of growth (or decay) trend of the competitor species, prior to the state-transition (and vice versa); and, the said autonomous track is decided by the underlying dominance criterion.

5 Computations, Results and Discussions
Pursuant to the considerations discussed above, Equation (3) is simulated and validated with reference to growth/decay details presented in Figure 3. First, using the data of Figure 3, initial slopes (mo) of growth/decay curves in each time-frame are ascertained and listed as in Table 2(a). Next, the corresponding Q-values of BernoulliLangevin functions are determined pertinent to Equation (3) for each of the Mobile OS system (Symbian, iPhone or Android) under consideration. The indices/suffices, AN, iP and Sy used in Table 2(a) explicitly denote the respective services of Android, iPhone and Symbian). Further, as regard to the associated nonlinear temporal growth/decay profiles having mo and Q-values as listed in Table 2(a), corresponding explanatory remarks are presented in Table 2(b). 41 Perambur Neelakanta Raef Yassin

A Co-Evolution Model of Competitive Mobile Platforms: Technoeconomic Perspective

Journal of Theoretical and Applied Electronic Commerce Research ISSN 0718–1876 Electronic Version VOL 6 / ISSUE 2 / AUGUST 2011 / 31-49 © 2011 Universidad de Talca - Chile

This paper is available online at www.jtaer.com DOI: 10.4067/S0718-18762011000200005

Table 2(a): Determination of QSy, QiP and QAN values in terms of the initial slope (mo) of growth/decay curves [7], [10] of each time-frame indicated in Figure 3 (Note: QSy = [1/(3mo −1)Sy], QiP = [1/(3mo −1)iP] and QAN = [1/(3mo −1)AN]) Symbian Timeframes (See Fig. 3) Initial slope (mo)Sy 1.0 (Decay) QSy and GSy(t) iPhone Initial slope (mo)iP 1.0 (Growth) QiP and GiP(t) Android Initial slope (mo)AN →0 QAN and GAN(t) Remarks

ab

0.50 1 − LSy(t)

0.50 LiP (t)

Not specified (Steady or minor growth or decay

I

bc

0.5 (Growth)

2.0 LSy (t)

→0

Not specified (Steady or minor decay)

→0

Not specified (Steady or minor growth or decay

II

cd

0.5 (Decay)

2.0 1 – LSy (t)

1.05 (Growth)

0.47 LiP (t)

→0

Not specified (Steady or minor growth or decay

III

Not specified de →0 (Steady or minor growth) 0.55 (Decay) 1.54 1 – LiP (t)

→ 0.5 (Growth)

1.0 LAN(t)

IV

ef

0.33 (Dominant decay)

→∞ 1 – LSy (t)

0.39 (Growth)

6.45 LiP (t)

0.55 (Growth)

1.54 LAN(t)

V

fg

→0

Not specified (Steady or minor growth)

Across ef-fg… 0.58 1.36 Growth: LiP (t)

0.67 (Growth)

0.98 LAN(t)

VI

42 Perambur Neelakanta Raef Yassin

A Co-Evolution Model of Competitive Mobile Platforms: Technoeconomic Perspective

Journal of Theoretical and Applied Electronic Commerce Research ISSN 0718–1876 Electronic Version VOL 6 / ISSUE 2 / AUGUST 2011 / 31-49 © 2011 Universidad de Talca - Chile

This paper is available online at www.jtaer.com DOI: 10.4067/S0718-18762011000200005

Table 2(b): Explanations on the remarks (I through VI) of Table 2(a) vis-à-vis Bernoulli-Langevin nonlinear growth/decay profiles of traffic shared by iPhone, Symbian and Android systems
Remarks Symbian I (ab) iPhone Android Symbian II (bc) iPhone Android Symbian Explanatory details Devolution (decay) tendency toward upper-bound (QSy = 0.5) of the sigmoid implying a closing-in toward an isotropically unsettled random interaction of technoeconomic entities Evolution (growth) tendency toward upper-bound (QiP = 0.5) of the sigmoid implying a closing-in toward an isotropically unsettled random interaction of technoeconomic entities Insignificant evolution (growth) tendency (with QAN → negative value) towards an almost steadystate condition. So the Bernoulli-Langevin function is not applicable Evolution (growth) tendency toward lower-bound of the sigmoid (QSy = 2) implying a closing-in toward a settled (anisotropically random) interaction of technoeconomic entities Minor evolution (growth/decay) tendency (with QiP → negative value) towards an almost steadystate condition. So the Bernoulli-Langevin function is not applicable Minor evolution (growth) tendency (with QAN → negative value) towards an almost steady-state condition. So the Bernoulli-Langevin function is not applicable Devolution (decay) tendency toward lower-bound (QSy = 2.0) of the sigmoid implying a closing-in toward an anisotropically settled random interaction of technoeconomic entities Evolution (growth) tendency toward upper-bound of the sigmoid (QiP = 0.47) implying a closing-in toward a unsettled (isotropically random) interaction of technoeconomic entities Minor evolution (growth) tendency (with QAN → negative value) towards an almost steady-state condition. So the Bernoulli-Langevin function is not applicable Not significant evolution (growth/decay) tendency (with QSy → negative value) towards an almost steady-state condition. So the Bernoulli-Langevin function is not applicable Devolution (decay) tendency toward lower-bound of the sigmoid (QiP = 1.54) implying a closing-in toward a settled (isotropically random) interaction of technoeconomic entities Evolution (growth) tendency toward upper-bound with QAN → 1.0 implying a closing-in toward a settled (anisotropically random) interaction of technoeconomic entities Devolution (decay) tendency degenerates toward signum function (QSy → ∞) implying a closing-in toward totally anisotropic random interaction of technoeconomic entities meaning that variability in economic parameters pose insignificant influence on the decay process --- So, Symbian is loosing the game and a stage is now set for the dominance of the competitors (iPhone and Android) Evolution (growth) tendency toward lower-bound of the sigmoid (QiP = 6.45) implying a closing-in extensively toward a settled (anisotropically random) interaction of technoeconomic entities --- With growth (winning) trend, iPhone is getting the dominance over the competitor, Symbian Evolution (growth) tendency toward lower-bound of the sigmoid (QAN = 1.54) implying a closing-in toward a settled (anisotropically random) interaction of technoeconomic entities --- Android is also getting the dominance over the competitor, Symbian Minor evolution (almost no-growth) tendency (with QSY → negative value) towards a steady-state condition. So the Bernoulli-Langevin function is not applicable Evolution (growth) tendency toward lower-bound of the sigmoid (QiP = 1.36) implying a closing-in toward a settled (anisotropically random) interaction of technoeconomic entities --- iPhone is creeping into the dominance over the competitor, Symbian and competes almost one-to-one with Android

iPhone III (cd) Android

Symbian

iPhone IV (de) Android

Symbian

V (ef)

iPhone

Android

Symbian

iPhone VI (fg)

Android

Evolution (growth) tendency toward lower-bound of the sigmoid (QAN = 0.98) implying a closing-in toward an unsettled (isotropically random) interaction of technoeconomic entities --- Android is also creeping into the dominance over the competitor, Symbian and competes one-to-one with iPhone

43 Perambur Neelakanta Raef Yassin

A Co-Evolution Model of Competitive Mobile Platforms: Technoeconomic Perspective

Journal of Theoretical and Applied Electronic Commerce Research ISSN 0718–1876 Electronic Version VOL 6 / ISSUE 2 / AUGUST 2011 / 31-49 © 2011 Universidad de Talca - Chile

This paper is available online at www.jtaer.com DOI: 10.4067/S0718-18762011000200005

Now, using the details as in Tables 2(a) and 2(b), simulation of underlying Bernoulli-Langevin function for each timeframe under consideration can be done with the corresponding Q-value. The simulations performed in each timeframe refer to an ensemble of evaluations on G(t) with the set {Q ± ΔQR} where {ΔQR} denotes an ensemble set of random values in the range of say, ± 10 % of Q so as to provide the statistical error-bar on simulated curves. (For +4 the specific cases of Q → 0 and Q →∞ respectively, 10−4 and 10 are used in the simulations).

0.6

Ensemble simulations.

iPhone 0.4 Relative trafficshare 0.2 Symbian

0 a b c d e Temporal epochs f

g

Figure 5: Symbian versus iPhone: Progress of traffic-shares from October 2008 to February 2010

0.6

Ensemble simulations.

Android 0.4 Relative trafficshare 0.2 Symbian

0 a b c d e Temporal epochs f

g

Figure 6: Symbian versus Android: Progress of traffic-shares from October 2008 to February 2010 Figure 5 is the Illustration of growth pursuit by a participant (predator) in a given time-frame versus decay suffered by the competitor (prey) in the previous time-frame. Likewise, Figure 6 depicts the Illustration of growth pursuit by a participant (predator) in a given time-frame versus decay suffered by the competitor (prey) in the previous time-frame. In essence, Figures 5 and 6 depict respectively, the simulated curves superimposed on data curves of (Symbian versus iPhone) and (Symbian versus Android) as observed during each time-frames, ab, bc, …, fg. In terms of the model developed in this work, the results depicted in Figures 5 and 6 are explained in Tables 3 and 4. 44 Perambur Neelakanta Raef Yassin

A Co-Evolution Model of Competitive Mobile Platforms: Technoeconomic Perspective

Journal of Theoretical and Applied Electronic Commerce Research ISSN 0718–1876 Electronic Version VOL 6 / ISSUE 2 / AUGUST 2011 / 31-49 © 2011 Universidad de Talca - Chile

This paper is available online at www.jtaer.com DOI: 10.4067/S0718-18762011000200005

Table 3: Symbian versus iPhone: Prey/predator status of Figure 5 – Details Timeframe ab iPhone Growth Predator 0.50 Mobile OS Symbian Growth or decay Decay Status Prey Q-value 0.50 Commencement of the game-theoretic competition. Q = 0.5 implies the economic variability would strongly influence the growth/decay making G(t) dynamics jagged Symbian with Q = 2.0 shows less variability in getting affected by economic factors, but has a growing trend relative to iPhone The profile of growth trend of iPhone (posterior to the state-transition at c) appears to gracefully track the profile of growth trend of the competitor (Symbian) prior to the state-transition. Hence, the suite of Condition 1, seem to fit in implying a zero sum payoff situation. Symbian tries to maintain a steady profile with no event-specific moves The growth regime of iPhone (predator) in the time-frame, ef tracks more or less the competitor’s (prey’s) decay profile all the way from the previous time-frame, cd. Further, across ef-fg, Symbian loses is dependence on any variability (with Q → ∞) in the technoeconomic inputs. As such, its decay tendency continues. Here, Condition 2 tendency appears to prevail. That is, with Symbian continuously loosing grip on the game, the growth-trend of the competing iPhone (posterior to its eth epochal state-transition) becomes more autonomous; that is, an autonomous track sets in due to the underlying dominance criterion, which in this case takes the iPhone to be the eventual winner as a dominant Mobile OS system. Thus, the Condition 2, implying a non-zero sum payoff situation creeps in. Comment

bc

Symbian iPhone

Growth Steady minor growth Decay Growth or

Predator Prey

2.00 Not specified in LQ(t) context 2.00 0.47

cd

Symbian iPhone

Prey Predator

de

Symbian iPhone

Steady minor growth Decay Growth

or

Predator Prey Predator

Unspecified de: 1.54 6.45 Across 1.36

ef-fg

iPhone

ef-fg:

Symbian

Decay

Prey

ef: → ∞ fg: Unspecified

45 Perambur Neelakanta Raef Yassin

A Co-Evolution Model of Competitive Mobile Platforms: Technoeconomic Perspective

Journal of Theoretical and Applied Electronic Commerce Research ISSN 0718–1876 Electronic Version VOL 6 / ISSUE 2 / AUGUST 2011 / 31-49 © 2011 Universidad de Talca - Chile

This paper is available online at www.jtaer.com DOI: 10.4067/S0718-18762011000200005

Table 4: Symbian versus Android: Prey/predator status of Figure 6 – Details Timeframe ab Mobile OS Symbian Android Growth or decay Decay Steady or minor growth Status Prey Predator (?) Q-value 0.50 Unspecified ab: Commencement of the game with Android posing no extensive competitive trend and Symbian significant decay trend. Condition 1, namely, the zero-sum payoff situation can be expressed with respect to competing enterprises in the initial timeframes. Towards the end (ef-fg) Condition 2 tendency prevails. That is, the growth-trend of competing Android becomes more autonomous and independent of the profile of decay trend of the incumbent Symbian. The autonomous track sets in due to the underlying worsening state of the Symbian and dominance of the Android. Hence, at the end of the observed period, Android becomes the eventual winner. Comment

cd de

Android Symbian Android Symbian

Minor growth Decay Growth Steady or minor decay Growth Decay

Predator Prey Predator Prey

Unspecified 2.00 1.00 de: → ∞ ef: Not specified 0.98-1.54 Not specified

ef-fg

Android Symbian

Predator Prey

5.1

Sample Calculation and Sensitivity Considerations

With reference to the compiled results, indicated below is an example calculation and sensitivity aspects of the observed performance. Considering Symbian versus iPhone competition, relevant prey/predator status shown in Figure 5 is explained in Table 3. It refers to, for example: (i) in time-frame bc Symbian shows a growth trend with an incumbent role of being a predator; and, (ii) in the next time-frame cd, the competitor namely, iPhone assumes a growth trend playing a predator role. This growth trend of iPhone, which happens posterior to a state-transition (in cd) appears to track the profile of the growth trend of the competitor prior to the state-transition (in bc). Hence, the suite of Condition 1, seem to fit in implying a zero sum payoff situation. This can be justified using numerical details on the growth/decay functions. From the traffic-share data (in normalized form) fitted to the time-frames bc and cd, it can be inferred from Table (2a) that: bc time-frame: Computed initial slope (magnitude) of Symbian’s growth profile (moSY) ≈ 0.5 The corresponding Q-value = 1/(3moSY – 1) ≈ 2.0 G(t)|ab = LSy(t) as indicated in Table 2(a) cd time-frame: Computed initial slope (magnitude) of iPhone’s growth profile (moiP) ≈ 1.05 The corresponding Q-value = 1/(3moiP – 1) ≈ 0.47 G(t)|cd = LiP(t) as indicated in Table 2(a) Thus, the growth trend in cd of iPhone tracks the growth trend of the competitor (Symbian) in the prior time-frame, bc. The tracking as above is in conformance with the suite of Condition 1 namely, zero sum payoff situation. The efficacy of tracking trend can be specified in terms of the sensitivity set by the Q-values. In both cases as above, the Qvalues (2.0 and 0.47) are near to the upper-bound of the statistical variability or disorder set by the function G(t) ≡ LQ(t) on the growth features introduced by the exogenous and endogenous factors of the underlying technoeconomics. This is true inasmuch as the time-frames in question (bc and cd) conform to the initial business stages where such high variability or isotropic randomness can be anticipated. However, the sensitivity of growth/decay to such variations will be felt to a lesser extent at later time-frames wherein the businesses stabilize for better or worse. This can be illustrated with the following exemplification: Again, consider the traffic-share data (in normalized form) fitted to the time-frames ef through fg relevant to Symbian versus iPhone competition. From Table 2(a): ef time-frame: Computed slope (magnitude) of Symbian’s G(t) profile (moSY) ≈ 0.39 The corresponding Q-value = 1/(3moSY – 1): → ∞ 46 Perambur Neelakanta Raef Yassin

A Co-Evolution Model of Competitive Mobile Platforms: Technoeconomic Perspective

Journal of Theoretical and Applied Electronic Commerce Research ISSN 0718–1876 Electronic Version VOL 6 / ISSUE 2 / AUGUST 2011 / 31-49 © 2011 Universidad de Talca - Chile G(t)|ef = 1 – LSY(t) as indicated in Table 2(a) Computed slope (magnitude) of iPhone’s G(t) profile (moiP) ≈ 0.33 The corresponding Q-value = 1/(3moiP – 1): 6.45 G(t)|ef = LiP(t) as indicated in Table 2(a)

This paper is available online at www.jtaer.com DOI: 10.4067/S0718-18762011000200005

fg time-frame: Computed slope (magnitude) of Symbian’s G(t) profile (moSY) → 0 The corresponding Q-value = 1/(3moSY – 1): Unspecified in using LQ(t) function G(t)|ef → Steady-state as indicated in Table 2(a) Computed slope (magnitude) of iPhone’s G(t) profile (moiP) ≈ 0.58 The corresponding Q-value = 1/(3moiP – 1): 1.36 G(t)|ef = LiP(t) as indicated in Table 2(a) At these later time-frames (ef-fg), the businesses stabilize for better or worse. That is, the sensitivity of growth/decay to technoeconomic variability is less felt. With iPhone, the Q-value (= 6.45) is much offset from the limiting value of Q = 0.5; and hence, the statistical variability on the growth features introduced by the exogenous and endogenous factors of the underlying technoeconomics becomes steadier rendering the associated disorder closer to being more anisotropic or invariant. As such, iPhone becomes negatively sensitive to decay in its growing trends. On the contrary, the competitor (Symbian) faces extensive constancy in its dynamics G(t) ≡ LQ(t) introduced by the bound Q → ∞ (seen in ef) on any possible variability in the technoeconomic inputs that would reverse its decaying trend in its performance. Thus, the growth-trend of competing iPhone (posterior to its eth epochal state-transitions through ef-fg time-frames) becomes more autonomous and independent of the profile of decay trend of the competitor Symbian; that is, an autonomous track sets in due to the underlying dominance criterion, which in this case takes the iPhone to be the eventual winner as a dominant Mobile OS system. Hence, the Condition 2 implying a non-zero sum payoff situation creeps in. Similar reasoning can be attributed to rest of the time-frames as well as to the other participant Mobile OS systems analyzed.

6 Inferential Remarks and Discussions
Commensurate with the objective of the present study, this paper offers a model to depict the co-evolution of large enterprises such as Mobile OS industry as competitive business structures. The model considers at least two competing corporations with an embodiment of several stochastically interacting subsystems constituting a complex system. Further, considering the underlying dynamics of competition, a novel paradigm of prey-predator model is specified with a dichotomy of (prey-predator) flip-flops along the time-scale. That is, in each state (of predator and prey), the evolution or devolution of the corporate economics is shown to follow a nonlinear growth or decay, G(t), which can be expressed in a stochastical differential equation format. Corresponding solution of G(t) is presented in terms of Bernoulli-Langevin function. Lastly, simulated results on this functional description of G(t) are compared against real-world Mobile OS data. The computed results lead to the following observations and inferential conclusions toward validation of the model. • • Temporal evolutions/devolutions across each time-frame set: {ab, bc, cd, de, ef, fg}: As presented in Tables 3 and 4 Considering the incumbent game-players, Android and iPhone show a growth trend. This growth is competitive with respect to each other as could be evinced in the time-frames of ef and fg. Should iPhone versus Android in the post-(February 2010) be an issue of research interest, it is indicated here as an openquestion In the segments of time-frames considered in this study, relevant simulated data closely follow the actual data within the statistical stretch of computations exercised indicating the efficacy of the model and validating the method of approach The computational outcome is exemplified with an illustrative sample calculation and corresponding sensitivity details on the results are furnished To the best of the authors’ knowledge no parallel efforts in describing the prey-predator dichotomy dynamics of technoeconomics in terms of Bernoulli-Langevin nonlinear perspectives are available in the literature



• •

47 Perambur Neelakanta Raef Yassin

A Co-Evolution Model of Competitive Mobile Platforms: Technoeconomic Perspective

Journal of Theoretical and Applied Electronic Commerce Research ISSN 0718–1876 Electronic Version VOL 6 / ISSUE 2 / AUGUST 2011 / 31-49 © 2011 Universidad de Talca - Chile •

This paper is available online at www.jtaer.com DOI: 10.4067/S0718-18762011000200005

The present study offers a model in the analytical form of Equation (3) that describes the growth/decay trends of the businesses in the past (that is, in ex post regime). A logical question that arises is how this model could be useful. Once a model such as Equation (3) is available describing the past episode of evolution/devolution, it can be used forecast the details in the futuristic (ex ante) time-frame via appropriate asymptotic computations that preserve the associated stochastics as well as the stability features of the terminal phases in the technoeconomics scenario under discussion. Relevant forecast computations can be done, first by exercising a learning phase, for example in an artificial neural network (ANN) using actual data gathered from the market and modeled via Equation (3). Once the ANN is so trained, suppose a set of upcoming data on the growth/decay performance is available, it can now be supplied to the ANN as the input set so that the computed output conforms to predicting of forecast details. Inasmuch as the ANN training model is based on Equation (3) with the associated stochastical considerations of the growth/decay trends, it can be anticipated in the prediction phase that the growth/decay features will be preserved in the ex ante regime following the suite of the ex post epochs. Relevant efforts on ANN-based forecasting via coevolution model are in progress As indicated before, the use of normalized data in the analysis may apparently restrict the model to describe the evolution/devolution for relative comparison only. However, the normalization performed uses a linear constant weight. Hence the proportionality of performance like traffic share would not change either in the model predictions or in the forecast regimes. Once the relative comparison is elucidated using the normalized data set then, the actual growth/decay performance (in absolute scale) can be decided by denormalization done with the constant linear weight adopted as the normalizer. This proportionality consideration is true for both ex post and ex ante results.



7 Closure
In closure, this paper offers a neoteric approach to view the evolution of competitive species in the framework of prey-predator mind-set projected as a dichotomous dynamics of flip-flopping (prey/predator) roles. Hence the temporal dynamics of competition/co-evolution of known competitors in the mobile-platform market, like Android, Symbian and iPhone is depicted by a novel model posing a dichotomy of prey-predator flip-flops in the market; and, an asymptotic projection of underlying algorithm into the ex ante region would correspond to forecast assessments of mobile platforms. That is, the modeled algorithm like Equation (3) can be adopted as a growth/decay profile that feeds an ensemble of input data set to train an ANN in an ex post time-frame; and, the trained ANN can be used to deliver projected/forecast data in the ex ante regime.

References
[1] [2] [3] [4] [5] [6] [7] [8] [9] [10] [11] [12] [13] H. Boley and E. Chang, Digital ecosystem: Principles and semantics, presented at the Inaugural IEEE International Conference in Digital Ecosystems and Technologies, February 21-23, 2007. H. Dong, F. K. Hussain, and E. Chong, Ontology-based digital ecosystem conceptual representation, in Proceedings of the Third International Conference on Automatic and Autonomous Systems, 2007. C. Foresman. (2009, April) iPhone OS devices continue to dominate Mobile traffic. [Online]. Available: http://arstechnica.com/apple/news/2009/04/iphone-os-devices-continue-to-dominate-mobile-traffic.ars. C. Foresman. (2009, November) iPhone and Android in two-horse smartphone OS race, Source AdMob/via ArtsTechnica, iPhone OS still dominates Mobile web: Android on the way up. [Online]. Available: http://arstechnica.com/apple/news/2010/03/iphone-os-still-dominates-mobile-web-android-on-the-way-up.ars. R. Lòpez-Ruiz and D. Fournier-Prunaret (2006, May) Three Logistic Models for the Ecological and Economic Interactions: Sybiosis, Predator-prey and Competition, Computer Research Repository. [Online]. Available: http://www.informatik.uni-trier.de/~ley/db/journals/corr/corr0605.html#abs-nlin-0605029. H. Mehlum, K. Moene and R. Torvik, Predator or prey? Parasitic enterprises in economic development, European Economic Review, vol. 47, no. 2, pp. 275-294, 2003. P. S. Neelakanta (Ed.), Information-theoretic Aspects of Neural Networks, Boca Raton, CRC Press, 1999. P. S. Neelakanta and D. Baeza, Chapter 8, in Next-generation Telecommunications and Internet Engineering, New York: Linus Publications, 2009, pp. 441-446. P. S. Neelakanta and W. Deecharoenkul, A complex system characterization of modern telecommunication services, Complex Systems, vol. 12, no. 1, pp. 31-69, 2000. P. S. Neelakanta and D. De Groff, Neural Network Modeling: Statistical Mechanics and Cybernetic Perspectives, Boca Raton, Florida: CRC Press, 1994. P. S. Neelakanta and R. C. T. Sardenberg, Digital Ecology: A medley of computer-centric digital informatics and environmentalism, vol. 8, no. 4-5, pp. 376-390, 2010. P. S. Neelakanta and R. C. Tourinho, Modeling an IT-centric complex system via digital ecology concepts, in rd Proceedings 3 IEEE International Conference on Digital Ecosystems and Technologies, Istanbul, Turkey, pp. 441-446, June 2009. P. S. Neelakanta and R. C. T. Sardenberg (2011, January) Consumer benefit versus price elasticity of demand: a nonlinear complex system model of pricing internet services on QoS-centric architecture Netnomics: 48 Perambur Neelakanta Raef Yassin

A Co-Evolution Model of Competitive Mobile Platforms: Technoeconomic Perspective

Journal of Theoretical and Applied Electronic Commerce Research ISSN 0718–1876 Electronic Version VOL 6 / ISSUE 2 / AUGUST 2011 / 31-49 © 2011 Universidad de Talca - Chile

This paper is available online at www.jtaer.com DOI: 10.4067/S0718-18762011000200005

[14] [15] [16] [17]

[18]

Economic Research and Electronic Networking. [Online]. vol. 12, no. 1, pp. 31-60. Avaible: http://www.springerlink.com/content/k42732451r106460/. A. Prabhudesai. (2010, April) India second to USA in mobile Internet traffic – smartphones usage surge. [Online]. Available: http://trak.in/tags/business/2010/04/08/india-mobile-internet-traffic-smartphones/. B. Reed, How Android conquered the mobile world, Network World, November 8, 2010, pp. 12-20. R. C. T. Sardenberg, Technoeconomic aspects of next-generation telecommunications including the Internet service, PhD dissertation, Florida Atlantic University, Boca Raton, Florida, USA, 2010. V. Savov. (2010, March) Stats: iPhone OS is still king of the mobile web space, but Android is nipping at its heal. [Online]. Available: http://www.engadget.com/2010/03/29/stats-iphone-os-is-still-king-of-the-mobile-webspace-but-andr/. F. van der Ploeg, Predator-prey and neo-classical models of cyclic growth, Zeitschrift für Nationalokonomie, vol. 43, no. 3, pp. 235-256, 1983.

49 Perambur Neelakanta Raef Yassin

A Co-Evolution Model of Competitive Mobile Platforms: Technoeconomic Perspective

Similar Documents

Premium Essay

Best Buy - Competitive Strategy Evolution

...Competitive Strategy Best Buy Best Buy Group D9 THEME: How Best Buy has maintained and enhanced its Competitive Advantage over the years by constantly seeking a favorable competitive position in the Consumer Electronics retailing industry 1 Table of Contents Contents Objective of the report Executive Summary Part I – Early beginnings & Hyper-growth Part II – Initiating Change at Best Buy -- Recognizing the need for change -- First attempt at change (formulating the Standard Operating Platform) -- Head-Heart-Hands approach to change management (Overcoming Cognitive Inertia) -- Institutionalizing the Change Management Process (Overcoming Action Inertia) -- Impact of the SOP on the Best Buy's operations Part III - Revisiting the Drawing Board -- Building new skill sets -- Formulating Customer Centricity (deploying a new game strategy) -- Implementing Customer Centricity (reconfiguring the value chain) -- Reaping the gains from Customer Centricity Part IV – Staving off Competition: Click & Mortar model -- Industry going through a phase of Intermediating Change -- Where does Best Buy go from here? -- Experimenting may payoff but need to commit References used Page no 2 3 4-5 5-9 5 6 6-7 7-8 8-9 9-12 9-10 10-11 11 12 13-14 13 13 13-14 15 1 Objective of Report Best Buy Co., Inc has been a leading player in the Electronics & Appliances retailing industry for several years now. It has withstood several cycles of churn in the Industry; seen many of its competitors...

Words: 4544 - Pages: 19

Premium Essay

Case Study

...MOBILE INDUSTRY HISTORY Indian Mobile Industry Stats [Infographic] by ARUN PRABHUDESAI Recently, I have been coming across some interesting infographics and presentations on Indian Mobile Industry. We published one such infographic earlier this week – And here is the second one which the readers will find quite interesting as well. Eyedea Lab, a Web and Graphics Design Studio at Kolkata recently published an informational Infographic which gives you a nice overview of Indian Mobile Industry. Did you know that first mobile phone call in India was made by Late Mr. Jyoti Basu to Mr. Sukh Ramon 30th July 1995. so it can be officially said that Indian Mobile Industry has just finished its 16th year – and is still a teenager so to say! Indian Mobile Industry Infographic [Click on the image to zoom] Yeah, the call rates back then were Rs. 32 per minute and incoming & outgoing both used to be charged ! MARKET TRENDS Five Trends That Will Shape the Mobile Industry in 2011 * Evaluation of Patent Trends, Technology Evolution, and Product Innovation Indicates Potential Winners and Losers in the Technology Battles Facing Mobile Industry    UBM TechInsights has made key predictions about the future of the mobile industry based on its in-depth research on patent trends, technology evolution, and product innovation. These five trends will be of strategic importance to most players in the mobile communication industry in 2011, including smartphone and tablet computing OEMs...

Words: 4304 - Pages: 18

Premium Essay

Htc Info

...HTC Posted on June 16, 2012 by John Dudovskiy HTC Corporation (formerly known as High Tech Computer Corp.) is a Taiwan-based smartphone manufacturing company engaged in design, development, manufacturing and sales of mobile computers, personal digital assistant phones, touch phones and smart phones and offers its products in Europe, Asia pacific, North and Latin America, Africa and Middle East (Bloomberg, 2010). The company has gained a reputation in terms of innovation related to the features of their products as well as their design   The Evolution of HTC HTC was founded in 1997 by three business people and technology enthusiasts Cher Wang, HT Cho and Peter Chou. The founders took the roles of Chairwoman, Director of Board and Chairman of HTC Foundation, and President and CEO respectively. At the initial period of business HTC was mainly involved in partnerships with companies like Compaq, Dell and HP designing and building PDAs (personal digital assistants) for them. The most innovative and acclaimed products of these brands HTC was closely involved in include Compaq iPAQ, Treo 650, O2 XDA, and Orange SPV (Hi, we’re HTC, 2010) The company was introduced to the public as an independent brand starting from June 2006, and manufactured its first own brand product HTC Touch, which is claimed to be by the company a first finger-friendly touch-screen smartphone in June 2007. Today HTC boasts with its popular products as Touch Diamond, Hero, HD2, HD Legend, and Desire, and...

Words: 7173 - Pages: 29

Premium Essay

It Project Paper

...THE EMERGENCE OF TECHNOLOGY AND ITS ADVANTAGE TO BEST BUY COMPANY INC. Course project on; Managerial applications of information technology -IS535 Devry University, Keller graduate school of management. June 2013 Table of Contents Abstract Company Background Discussion of Business problem High Level Solution Approach Business and Technical Approach Benefits of Solving the Problem Conclusion and Recommendations References THE EMERGENCE OF TECHNOLOGY AND ITS ADVANTAGE TO BEST BUY COMPANY INC Abstract Many companies have been struggling recently due to the shift and the constant increase of online marketing and sales. The internet has created an entire new market. This has posed serious problems to Best Buy company Inc., as it profit and revenue seems to be on the down turn .In 2013 fiscal second quarter, Domestic comparable stores sales saw a 1.6 percent...

Words: 2940 - Pages: 12

Premium Essay

Pest & Swot

...RESEARCH IN MOTION LIMITED - BLACKBERRY Research in motion limited was founded in the year 1984 by Mr. Michael Lazaridis,the company's President and Co-Chief Executive Officer, and Mr. Douglas Fregin(RIM-2009). The company then grew in to one of the leading designer and manufacturer of wireless solutions, the company product portfolios include the blackberry wireless solution and other software and hardware solutions. The major markets of the company include North America, Europe and Asia Pacific (RIM-2008). RIM generates most of its revenues through the blackberry wireless device with various features which provides a user friendly interface. Although the company has been growing since its inception. In early 1990s the company was focused on developing wireless data technology but by far the significant year for the company was 1999 when it introduces the blackberry solutions and in following years it has launched many advanced models of blackberry solutions in partnership with various service providers which includes Yahoo, AOL, MTN, Qtel etc. The company has recorded a revenue of US$14.935 million in the financial year 2010 which is an increase of 35% compared to FY 2009 with USA alone accounting for 57% of the revenue. The devices accounted for 81% of the revenue followed by service (14.4%),software (1.7%) and other (2.8%). Although the company is doing very well financially, it is not immune the pressure of external forces and following section highlights some of the external...

Words: 1708 - Pages: 7

Premium Essay

Tim Strategy

...Telecom Italia Strategic Plan Update MARCO PATUANO Safe Harbour These presentations contain statements that constitute forward-looking statements within the meaning of the Private Securities Litigation Reform Act of 1995. These statements appear in a number of places in this presentation and include statements regarding the intent, belief or current expectations of the customer base, estimates regarding future growth in the different business lines and the global business, market share, financial results and other aspects of the activities and situation relating to the Company and the Group. Such forward looking statements are not guarantees of future performance and involve risks and uncertainties, and actual results may differ materially from those projected or implied in the forward looking statements as a result of various factors. Forward-looking information is based on certain key assumptions which we believe to be reasonable as of the date hereof, but forward looking information by its nature involves risks and uncertainties, which are outside our control, and could significantly affect expected results. Analysts are cautioned not to place undue reliance on those forward looking statements, which speak only as of the date of this presentation. Telecom Italia S.p.A. undertakes no obligation to release publicly the results of any revisions to these forward looking statements which may be made to reflect events and circumstances after the date of this presentation...

Words: 3455 - Pages: 14

Free Essay

Marketing

... BY ABIN MATHEW MBA B B112 TABLE OF CONTENTS INTRODUCTION ……………………………………………………………………………………………….. 3 HISTORY ………………………………………………………………………………………………… 3 VISION ………………………………………………………………………………………………… MISION …………………………………………………………………………………………………. OPERATIONAL STRATEGY………………………………………………………………………………………5 CONCLUSION ………………………………………………………………………………………………….8 INTRODUCTION Research In Motion (RIM) is a leading designer, manufacturer and marketer of wireless solutions. The company provides platforms and solutions allowing access to time-sensitive information, including email, phone, SMS, internet and intranet-based applications. Its technology also enables a broad array of third-party developers and manufacturers to enhance their products and services with wireless connectivity to data. RIM’s portfolio of products, services and embedded technologies include the BlackBerry wireless solution, and other software and hardware.The company operates offices in North America, Europe and Asia Pacific. The company is organized and managed as a single reportable business segment, which includes the research, design, manufacture and sales of wireless communications products, services and software.The segment includes primary operations related...

Words: 2565 - Pages: 11

Premium Essay

Mobile Communications

...Analysis of Mobile Communications Devices Industry INTRODUCTION This report is focused on the segment of the Electronics industry that creates devices for mobile communications, and referred to as the Mobile Communications Devices industry in this report. The mobile communications devices industry is set for a hyper growth spurt. By 2020, Morgan Stanley predicts that the number of mobile devices (smartphones, tablets, car electronics, etc.) could easily top 10 billion units. Mobile data traffic nearly tripled in 2010 due to usage of smart connected devices and significant progress in mobile network technology, and is driving revenue growth. Yet, Cisco expects it to increase another 26-fold by 2015, at a compound annual growth rate of 92 percent. Total annual sales for all mobile-related devices and services are set to top $1 trillion. As shown in Exhibit 1, there are an estimated 5.6 billion mobile communications connections in the world, as of March 2011. The average mobile network connection speed of 215 kilobytes per second in 2010 is expected to increase 10-fold to exceed 2.2 megabits per second in 2015. The number of people using their mobile devices as the only way to access the internet is expected to increase 56-fold from 14 million last year to 788 million by the end of 2015. The pace of product innovation remains high. Network speeds are increasing dramatically because of improving technology. Device and service sales are expected to continue to grow...

Words: 6859 - Pages: 28

Premium Essay

Sharing Economy

...Sharing corps: Should company build competitive advantage by embracing the sharing economy? SHARING CORPS SHOULD COMPANIES build a new competitive advantage BY embracing the SHARING ECONOMY? ECOVALA - December 2013 1 Sharing corps: Should company build competitive advantage by embracing the sharing economy? Ecovala © 2013 This report was produced by the Ecovala in December 2013. If no other source is specified, the contents of this report are under a Creative Commons Attribution – Non-Commercial - Share Alike 3.0 Unported License. You can find the full text of the license in this website. Ecovala Ecovala provides innovative solutions to private and public organisations to accelerate their transition towards sustainability. The organisation offers a wide range of services around sustainability and system innovation: from companies’ environmental assessment to sustainable strategic design, from new green services definition to effective implementation of CSR management. Based in Finland, the organisation is active throughout Europe, relying on an extensive network of like-minded organisations and sustainability experts. www.ecovala.eu Author Erwan Mouazan is director and founder of Ecovala. He develops and implements innovative sustainability solutions both at private and public level. Erwan owns a Master's degree in economics, with a specialization in international management. In the last 9 years, he has worked at international level in environmental...

Words: 10348 - Pages: 42

Free Essay

Rim/Blackberry

...an innovator in wireless email solutions in the late 90’s they were able to establish assets such as licenses and patents related to data security, wireless transmission of data, and what they are known best for; their push email service. By securing these licences and patents it has given Blackberry an edge in the market with the features it offers, and allowed them to establish a target market which was business people and professionals, before moving into the general market. The major stakeholders of the company are two of the founding members, who currently serve as Co-CEOs of the firm. RIM performs well financially on a consistent basis, with revenue figures reaching $4.2 billion in 2011, although this is down 15% from the previous quarter. In the USA RIM owns 40% of the smart phone market, however their blackberry products are weaker internationally than their rivals Nokia. to IDC |   | Top five mobile phone manufacturers, by 2010 global sales according to Strategy Analytics | Rank | Vendor | Unit shipments | Market share | Annual sales growth |   | Rank | Vendor | Unit shipments | Market share | | 1 | Nokia | 453.0 million | 32.6% |...

Words: 5273 - Pages: 22

Premium Essay

Organizational Behavior

...Reinventing Retail Banking Series Evolving Models of Retail Banking Distribution Capitalizing on changes in channel usage Produced by the Deloitte Center for Banking Solutions Reinventing Retail Banking Generation Y Reinventing Retail Banking Series Consumer Trust Reinventing Retail Banking Series Catalysts for Change The Implications of Gen Y Consumers for Banks Building Consumer Trust in Retail Payments Laying a Solid Foundation Produced by the Deloitte Center for Banking Solutions Produced by the Deloitte Center for Banking Solutions The traditional retail bank is at an inflection point. The needs and expectations of customers are changing as quickly as the competitive landscape. Customers are demanding seamless, multi-channel sales and service experiences and not consistently receiving them. Simultaneously, other financial institutions and non-traditional players are looking for opportunities to invade this space or to redefine it through disruptive innovation. The result is forcing banks to examine a more balanced, integrated approach to the customer experience and growth. In this series, entitled Reinventing Retail Banking, the Deloitte Center for Banking Solutions looks at how banks must move beyond simply meeting their profit and growth goals to delivering more completely on the customer experience. Specifically, these articles will focus on: understanding customers needs; identifying emerging and profitable customer segments and strategies...

Words: 12004 - Pages: 49

Free Essay

Armanda

...the University of Windsor. BlackBerry Limited (BlackBerry), incorporated on February 24, 2003, is a provider of mobile communications. The Company is engaged primarily in the provision of the BlackBerry wireless solution, consisting of smartphones, service and software. The Company's four areas of business are Devices business, Enterprise Services, BlackBerry Technology Solutions (BTS) business and Messaging. The Company's Devices business is focused on delivering smartphone products. BlackBerry's Enterprise Services business offers enterprise products and services. The Company's BTS business consists of five units: QNX Software Systems Limited (QNX), Certicom, Paratek, the BlackBerry Internet of Things (IoT) Platform, and Intellectual Property and Patent Licensing (IPPL). The Company's Messaging business is engaged in providing BlackBerry Messenger (BBM). The Company's smartphones are powered by the BlackBerry 10 operating system (OS). BlackBerry smartphones are available from various carriers and indirect channels, through a range of distribution partners, and are designed to operate on a range of carrier networks, including High Speed Packet Access (HSPA), HSPA+, Universal Mobile Telecommunications System (UMTS), Global System for Mobile Communications (GSM), general packet radio service (GPRS), Enhanced Data rates for GSM Evolution (EDGE), code division multiple access (CDMA), Evolution-Data Optimized (Ev-DO) and Integrated Digital Enhanced Network (iDEN). Devices business. The Company...

Words: 3666 - Pages: 15

Premium Essay

Competitive Analysis

...Cycle……………………………………………4 3.0 Literature review of Information Technology………………………………4 4.0 Conclusion for Industry Life Cycle…………………………………………5 5.0 Industry Level Analysis (Dell)………………………………………………6 6.0 Business Strategy……………………………………………………………7 7.0 Enterprise Solutions and service…………………………………………….8 8.0 PEST Analysis of Dell Company…………………………………………...11 9.0 Porters Five Forces of Dell………………………………………………….13 10.0 Stage of Industry Lifecycle of Dell…………………………………………16 11.0 Recommendation to improve performance of Dell…………………………17 12.0 Conclusion…………………………………………………………………..18 Bibliography………………………………………………………………………....19 Appendix…………………………………………………………………………….21 Overview of Industry Life Cycle Industry Life Cycle (ILC) is the stages of evolution through which an industry progresses as it moves from conception to stabilization and stagnation. Different analyses posit different stages of an industry life cycle (usually four to five), but all emphasize that an industry has a beginning, with technological innovation; a period of rapid growth; maturity and consolidation; and finally decline and possibly death. Industry dynamic impacts firm strategy and survival, and it is important to managers understanding that whether firm should compete or cooperate at different stages of the industry life cycle (Wilson & Hynes, 2009). One of the main tenets of how firms and industries evolve is that, as some businesses mature, the basis of competition shifts from product innovation to process...

Words: 3165 - Pages: 13

Premium Essay

Blue Whip Case

...Research report Service provider strategies for mobile advertising: case studies Alexandra Rehak October 2008 Research from Analysys Mason Fixed Networks and Services Analysys Mason Fixed Networks and Services online market intelligence service MENA telecoms market: strategies and opportunities 2008–2013 Mobile broadband: another substitution threat for fixed operators? Business data services in Europe: market drivers and forecasts 2008–2013 Multi-play services in Western Europe: market sizings and forecasts 2008–2013 Central and Eastern European fixed telecoms: market sizings and forecasts 2008–2014 Pay TV in Western Europe: market sizings and forecasts 2005–2013 Legacy matters: ensuring a soft landing for TDM services Regulatory headaches in the transition to nextgeneration networks Next-generation network architecture: what and when? Success factors for hosted and managed VoIP in Europe Western European fixed telecoms: market sizings and forecasts 2004–13 Wireless broadband forecasts for 2008–2015: HSPA, HSPA+, EV-DO, LTE and WiMAX Mobile social networking: strategies and case studies Strategies for mobile broadband pricing and packaging Mobile proximity payments: scenarios for market development iPhone shows the way for mobile TV Critical ingredients of mobile TV: femtocells and sideloading Mobile media and entertainment in Western Europe: value chains and business models The business case for picocells and femtocells in the enterprise market Femtocells in the consumer...

Words: 1892 - Pages: 8

Premium Essay

Internet

...The Future of the Internet A Compendium of European Projects on ICT Research Supported by the EU 7th Framework Programme for RTD European Commission I nform ati on S oc i et y and M ed ia Europe Direct is a service to help you find answers to your questions about the European Union New freephone number * 00 800 6 7 8 9 10 11 Certain mobile telephone operators do not allow access to 00800 numbers or these calls may be billed. In certain cases, these calls may be chargeable from telephone boxes or hotels. «The views expressed are those of the authors and not necessarily those of the European Commission or any of its officials» A great deal of additional information on the European Union is available on the Internet. It can be accessed through the Europa server (http://www.europa.eu). Cataloguing data can be found at the end of this publication. ISBN 978-92-79-08008-1 © European Communities, 2008 Reproduction is authorised provided the source is acknowledged. Printed in Belgium PRINTED ON CHLORE FREE PAPER The Future of the Internet A Compendium of European Projects on ICT Research Supported by the EU 7th Framework Programme for RTD European Commission I nform ati on S oc i et y and M ed ia ••• 2 Preface 5 priorities identified by the Internet Governance Forum: openness, security, access, diversity and critical Internet resources. The use of the Internet in public policies will considerably grow in areas such as education, culture, health and e-government...

Words: 66329 - Pages: 266