Free Essay

China Fdi

In:

Submitted By tesion302
Words 7851
Pages 32
Perspectives on China's Outward Foreign Direct Investment

Randall Morck University of Alberta School of Business and NBER Tel: (780) 492-5683 randall.morck@ualberta.ca

Bernard Yeung Stern School of Business New York University Tel: (212) 998-0425 byeung@stern.nyu.edu

Minyuan Zhao Ross School of Business University of Michigan Tel: (734) 647-6978 myzhao@umich.edu

June 2007

* The authors are grateful for the helpful comments from William Allen, Tom Pugel, Myles Shaver, Jordan Siegel, and Changqi Wu.

Perspectives on China's Outward Foreign Direct Investment
Randall Morck Bernard Yeung Minyuan Zhao

Abstract Recent economic data reveal that, at the infant stage, China’s outward foreign direct investment (FDI) is biased towards tax haven countries and South East Asian countries and are mostly conducted by State controlled enterprises with government sanctioned monopoly status. Further examination of China’s savings rate, corporate ownership structures, and bank dominated capital allocation suggests that, although a surge in China’s outward FDI might be economically sensible, the most active players have incentives to conduct excessive outward FDI while capital constraints limit players that most likely have value-creating FDI opportunities. We then discuss plausible firm-level justifications for China’s outward FDI flow, its importance, and promising avenues for further research.

I. Introduction Barely thirty years ago, most would consider China a poor agricultural economy. In 2008 China is hosting the Olympics to signal its emergence as a major economic power. This phenomenal development appropriately draws international business scholars’ attention. One especially curious characteristic of China’s development path is a recent surge in its outward foreign direct investment (FDI). Successful and not-so-successful foreign acquisitions by companies like Haier, Lenovo, TCL and CNOOC (China National Offshore Oil Corporation) grab headlines. Much discussion is of the phenomenon itself. With over a trillion dollars in foreign reserves and increasing economic clout, China can send flagship companies abroad to acquire technologies, brands, resources, and better access to international markets. In some industries at least, rising capacity and intensifying domestic price competition are cutting profit margins, and Chinese managers see FDI as a way to upgrade technology and augment earnings. While these are all legitimate strategies under broad ranges of circumstances, we believe it is important to identify specific drivers of the current surge in Chinese outward FDI, and to evaluate its broader implications with economic theories. In this paper, we first sketch the empirical characteristics of China’s outward FDI: its size, target locations, and most important players. Then, we offer alternative perspectives on the subject matter. At the economy level, China’s very high saving rate, the behavior of its dominant statecontrolled banks, and the enduring voice of the state in corporate governance might distort capital allocation in ways that generate outward FDI. Plausible distortions arise from both of the identity and likely motives of the key players. Next, we explain why China’s outward FDI will probably grow substantially as different players gain prominence. Given this, we adopt a firm-level perspective, and consider three non-exclusive theoretical explanations of China’s outward FDI surge. Implications for corporate management and public policy are discussed in the conclusion.

-1-

II. A Brief Description This section draws on various data sources to characterize China’s outward FDI – its size, target locations, and players. China’s outward FDI is tiny Figure 1 tracks the surge in outward FDI from China. Starting from near zero in the seventies and early eighties, Chinese outward FDI exceeds $16 billion in 2006.

Figure 1. China’s Outward Foreign Direct Investment (1979-2006)
18

15

12

US$ Billion

9

6

3

0 1979 1982 1985 1988 1991 1994 1997 2000 2003 2006

Data sources: Ministry of Commerce and China Statistics Bureau

Despite this impressive growth rate, the absolute magnitude remains small. The IMF places China’s 2005 purchasing power parity (PPP) adjusted GDP at $8.8 trillion, a bit over 70% of U.S. GDP ($12.2 trillion). However, Table 1 shows China’s outward FDI that year to be only $12.3 billion – a mere 5% of the comparable U.S. figure – barely outpacing Singapore and falling well behind the Netherlands. Moreover, China’s outward FDI stock accounts for only 0.6% of the world total at the end of 2005 – a disproportionately small sum. Clearly, Chinese outward FDI has substantial scope to grow.

-2-

Table 1. Comparison of Outward FDI across Countries (US$ Billions) Global total outward FDI flow China outward FDI Total As % of global total Developed Countries Japan France Canada Netherlands Italy UK Spain USA Developing Countries Chile Brazil Mexico South Korea Malaysia Singapore Russia Annual FDI Flow 2003 2004 2005 612.2 730.3 — 2.9 0.5% — — — — — — — — — — — — — — — 5.5 0.8% — — — — — — — — 1.4 1.4 3.4 1.4 5.5 5.1 12.3 1.7% 31.0 47.8 47.5 14.6 19.3 65.4 54.3 229.3 — 9.5 2.2 4.8 2.1 10.7 9.6 Cumulative FDI 2003 2004 2005 8,196.9 9,732.2 — 33.2 0.4% — — — — — — — — — — — — — — — 44.8 0.5% 335.5 — 307.8 — 238.9 1,128.6 207.5 2,069.0 — 54.6 13.8 34.5 29.7 90.9 51.8 57.2 0.6% 370.5 — 369.8 — 280.5 1,378.1 332.6 2,018.2 — 64.4 15.9 39.3 13.8 100.9 81.9

Data source: World Investment Report (2004) and World Investment Report (2005) of UNCTAD, and China Ministry of Commerce

Target locations High-profile Chinese outward FDI includes Lenovo’s acquisition of IBM’s personal computer unit and Minmetals’ bid for Noranda in Canada. That these acquisition targets are located in the world’s most developed countries attracts much public attention, generating an illusion that China already contains world-class companies joining the ranks of the multinational giants based in developed countries. In reality, Chinese outward FDI targets firms in all continents, with Figure 2 showing a distinct focus on South and East Asia and, to a lesser extent, Africa. In 2006, the 76 newly planned outward FDI projects in these two regions account for over 60% of the 125 total reported. In contrast, only about a third is in developed countries.

-3-

Figure 2. Number of Planned FDI Projects by Destination (2006)
South & East Asia Africa Western Europe North America Eastern Europe & FSU Latin America Japan, HK, S. Korea, Singapore Middle East North Korea Australia & New Zealand 0 2 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 3 3 6 8 9 10 17 26 41

Data Source: FIAS/MIGA Firm Survey, World Bank

The stock of China’s outward FDI is even more geographically concentrated. According to the annual statistics from the Ministry of Commerce, as of the end of 2005, Asia, Latin America and Africa account for 71%, 20% and 3% of the FDI stock, respectively, and the shares for North American and Europe are each below 3%. Table 2 separates China’s outward FDI volume by host country. The top locations are Hong Kong and Caribbean tax havens. These consistently account for about 70% of the flow. These countries provide confidentiality to foreign investors, and so are commonly used by multinational firms to store wealth beyond the purview of tax authorities (Harris, 1993). FDI into these countries by Chinese firms might also be designed to hide wealth from tax authorities, other authorities, or even public shareholders. Moreover, Chinese subsidiaries in these countries might serve as holding companies for investments elsewhere; or even back into China. For example, a Chinese firm’s FDI into Hong Kong can rebound to China if its Hong Kong subsidiary acquires ―foreign owned enterprise‖ (FOE) status in the mainland. FOEs pay lower taxes than domestic firms through the end of 2006. Unfortunately, we are not able to trace the funds pouring from China into tax havens to their final destinations. Yet another possibility is that Chinese controlled

-4-

subsidiaries in these countries veil spontaneous privatization, analogous to that documented by Lipton and Sachs (1990) in Eastern Europe. That is, the insiders of some Chinese firms might be moving wealth into tax havens to place it under their personal control. These numbers cast doubt on the extent to which economic fundamentals genuinely drive China’s outward FDI.
Table 2: Top Destinations of China’s Outward FDI Flows 2003 Amount (US$100M) 11.5 8.1 2.1 1.5 — 0.7 0.3 0.3 — 24.4 2004 Amount (US$100M) 26.3 12.9 3.9 0.4 1.3 1.2 0.8 0.6 1.5 48.7 2005 Amount (US$100M) 34.2 51.6 12.3 5.9 1.9 2.3 2.0 — 1.0 77.0

Country/Region Hong Kong Cayman Islands British Virgin Island South Korea Australian USA Russia Indonesia Sudan Total

% of Total 40.4% 28.3% 7.4% 5.4% — 2.3% 1.1% 0.9% — 85.8%

% of Total 47.8% 23.4% 7.0% 0.7% 2.3% 2.2% 1.4% 1.1% 2.7% 88.6%

% of Total 27.9% 42.1% 10.0% 4.8% 1.6% 1.9% 1.6% — 0.8% 90.7%

Data source: China FDI Statistics Report, Ministry of Commerce and China Statistics Bureau

The players Table 3 ranks the thirty largest companies in China by their outward FDI in 2004 and 2005. Almost all are either listed or controlling major listed subsidiaries. Two observations follow. First, the biggest sources of Chinese outward FDI are highly profitable listed SOEs. Lenovo is the only FDI heavyweight not explicitly state controlled. Private-sector firms may well conduct some outward FDI; but the scale is too small to register. Second, virtually every one of these significant players has an officially-sanctioned monopoly in some major industry, such as

telecommunications or natural resources. In 2005, the top ten SOEs account for over 75% of the total profit of China’s 169 national SOEs1, and 32% of the profit earned by the entire industrial
1

National SOEs refer to SOEs controlled by the central government. In China, there are SOEs controlled by various level of governments, e.g., provincial and municipal.

-5-

sector. Eight of the top ten qualify for inclusion in Table 3. Namely, the largest FDI players overlap substantially with the most profitable SOEs in China.
Table 3: 30 Largest Companies Ranked by Outward FDI No 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 Year 2004 China Mobile China National Petroleum Corp. China National Offshore Oil Corp. China Resources (Holding) Co. Ltd. COSCO CITIC SINOPEC China Telecom Guangdong and Hongkong Investment Holding China Merchant Group China NetCom China Construction Corp. Lenovo Holding China Aviation Group China Power Investment Group China Minmetals SinoChem China National Cereal, Oil and Foodstuff China Shipping Sino Transportation Group Shanghai Auto Group China Huaneng Group Beijing Orient Electrics Group China World Best Group TCL Group Guangdong Hangyun Group Shanghai Bao Steel Beijing Jade Bird Group China Nonferrous Metal Mining Group China Road and Bridge Corp. Year 2005 China National Petroleum Corp. China National Offshore Oil Corp. China Mobile China Resources (Holding) Co. Ltd. COSCO SINOPEC CITIC China Merchant Group China National Cereal, Oil and Foodstuff China Construction Corp. China Aviation China Telecom SinoChem Chine NetCom China Shipping Guangdong and Hongkong Investment Shanghai Auto Group Shum Yip Holding Company Lenovo Holding China Power Investment Group China Minmetals Sino Transportation Group TCL Beijing Orient Electrics Group China Huaneng Group China Poly Shanghai Bao Steel China Shou Gang Group China Nonferrous Metal Mining Group China North Industrial Group

Data source: China FDI Statistics Report, Ministry of Commerce and China Statistics Bureau

-6-

Table 4: The Ten Most Profitable State Owned Enterprises in 2005 Rank Company name Net income (¥100M) 1,756.1 782.1 551.8 357.9 338.6 221.0 220.5 200.4 150.2 143.9 4,722.5 6,276.5 14,802.54 Growth over last year (%) 46.1 21.9 27.6 55.2 3.8 85.0 0.5 64.2 51.3 44.9 40.05 27.9 22.6

1 China National Petroleum Corp. 2 China Mobile 3 SINOPEC 4 China National Offshore Oil Corp. 5 China Telecom 6 Shen Hua Group Corp. 7 BaoSteel 8 COSCO 9 Aluminum Corp. of China Ltd. 10 State Grid Corporation of China Total of the top 10 All 169 National SOEs All 271,835 SOEs and non-state enterprises above designated size *
*

The designated size is defined by the National Bureau of Statistics as enterprises with annual revenue over 5 million Yuan from principal businesses. Data source: State-owned Assets Supervision and Administration Commission of the State Council, and China Statistic Yearbook

In sum, the data indicate that China’s outward FDI remains small relative to the economy’s size, and focuses on nearby developing countries and, quite recently, Africa. From 2003 to 2005, Chinese FDI that flowed further abroad poured into tax havens. Whether this is to avoid taxes or mask corruption is unclear. High-profile FDI bids for foreign natural resources firms, like that of Minmetals for Inco and CNOOC’s bid for Unocal, are likely responses to State prodding. 2 To date, the main players are still large profitable SOEs with lucrative state-enforced monopolies.

III. Perspectives at the Economy Level This section examines three features of China’s macro environment that are likely connected with its outward FDI surge: a high savings rate, weak corporate governance, and distorted capital

2

On May 16, 2007, the Development and Reform Commission of China announced government support for outward FDI projects that can alleviate China’s resource bottleneck, facilitate industrial upgrade, improve innovation capabilities, and increase the competence of Chinese firms on the global market.

-7-

allocation. Although outward FDI can let firms gain important economies of scale and scope, these three features could conspire to induce excessive outward FDI by the wrong players that works against China’s long-term economic prosperity. High savings Savings pay for investment, and China’s savings rate is persistently and remarkably high. Figure 3 shows China’s total savings as a percent of GDP, and also breaks the total into savings by households, enterprises, and governments. While household savings have declined slightly as a fraction of GDP, enterprise savings are growing rapidly and now constitute the most important category.
Figure 3. China's Savings Rate in Recent Years (in percent of GDP)
50

40

30

Household Enterprise

%

20

Government Total

10

0 1990 1993 1996 1999 2002

Data source: IMF World Economic Outlook, September 2005

Table 5 compares China’s savings rates to those of other countries. Clearly, China’s household, enterprise, and government savings exceed those of other countries by substantial margins.3

3

Note that the total savings rates in Tables 4 and 5 are not fully compatible because they are from two difference sources.

-8-

Table 5: Savings Rates as Percent of GDP Country Total domestic savings Household savings Enterprise savings Government savings China 41.7 16.0 20.0 5.7 USA 14.3 4.8 10.3 -0.9 France 20.7 10.8 9.5 0.3 Japan 25.5 8.2 19.4 -2.2 Korea 31.0 4.5 14.8 11.7 Mexico 20.8 8.0 10.6 2.2 India 28.3 22.0 4.8 1.5

Data source: Kuijs (2006, Table 4).

Chinese domestic savings flow mainly into state-controlled banks as deposits. The reasons for Chinese households’ high savings are well known: Chinese save for education, housing, purchases of consumer durables, and security (e.g., pension and medical expenses). Its household savings rate, though high, is lower than India’s. The declining trend in China’s household savings rates in recent years likely reflects several factors: (i) greater accumulated savings, (ii) an aging population, and (iii) a gradual improvement in the consumer credit market, which mitigates the need for household savings. Corporate savings is retained earnings – the portion of earnings not paid out to equity investors. Table 5 reveals that China’s enterprise savings rate is among the highest in the world, and comparable to Japan’s. Bank involvement in Japanese corporate governance is thought to induce excessive earnings retentions by firms there (Morck and Nakamura, 2000). If enterprises do not plow their retained earnings into economically sound expansions, a high enterprise savings rate reflects an economically undesirable aversion to disburse earnings to shareholders (Jensen, 1986). Standard corporate finance theory suggests that companies ought to pay out to shareholders all earnings exceeding the firm’s profitable investment needs. Information asymmetry makes ―profitable‖ investments hard for shareholders to verify, and Jensen (1986) argues that a common corporate governance problem involves management excessively retaining earnings and pouring them into low-return projects to build corporate empires. La Porta, et al. (2000) show that sound

-9-

legal protection for investors is associated with higher dividends, but where legal systems are less at the service of investors, insiders tend to excessively retain earnings for empire-building. FDI builds particularly impressive corporate empires, spanning continents. Weak corporate governance underlying Chinese companies’ high rates of earnings retention and fueling their FDI must be considered a serious hypothesis. It turns out that Chinese SOEs, responsible for most FDI, are particularly dividend-averse. According to statistics from Shanghai and Shenzhen stock exchanges, over half of the listed SOEs pay no dividends, despite high earnings. For example, the most profitable SOE in Table 3, China National Petroleum Corp., realized 2005 net profits of ¥133.36 billion, but distributed only one percent of that, a mere ¥1.49 billion, to shareholders. The Chinese Securities Regulatory Commission (CSRC) also appears concerned that listed SOEs pay suboptimal dividends, for a series of new regulations in 2004 and 2005 explicitly forces higher dividend payouts. Companies with positive profits but no dividends for three consecutive years must provide ―explanations‖ to their public shareholders; or risk lawsuits. Further, companies with dividend payouts below 20% of after-tax profits are ineligible for debt refinancing. Because of these changes, many Chinese companies have announced dividends precisely equal to the 20% minimum.

Corporate ownership structures Potential reasons for these low dividends become apparent if we look into the ownership structure of listed companies. Figure 4 provides a snapshot of the ownership structures of the 1,381 listed companies at the end of 2005. Of all the shares outstanding, fully 65.9% are non-tradable shares. Of these, over half are owned by governments and government organs, with the remainder owned by other legal entities – mostly large state-controlled enterprises or state-managed investment funds. Non-tradable shares are also inalienable – they cannot be freely bought or sold. Their

- 10 -

existence has ensured continued state-control of the economy by giving the state majority voting power in the shareholder meetings of major listed firms.4

Figure 4. Ownership Structure of China’s listed companies (2005)

Shares with trade restrictions 10.61% State shares 27.97%

A shares 29.99%

Tradable 38.33%

B shares 3.02%

Corporate shares 21.39%

Other nontradable shares 1.70%

Other tradable shares 5.32%

*

The major classes of tradable shares are ―A‖ shares for domestic investors, ―B‖ shares that are locally traded but originally reserved for foreign portfolio investors, and cross-listings in Hong Kong or abroad. Data source: China Securities Regulatory Commission (CSRC)

This figure may understate the total state-related equity control, as state investment funds also hold tradable shares, and cross-shareholding by SOEs are prevalent. This typical ownership structure has several implications.5 First, small public shareholders have little or no influence on corporate decisions since the state wields sufficient voting power to appoint the board of the typical listed firm. Second, listed firms do not typically pay dividends on non-tradable shares directly owned by the state, even if they pay dividends on other classes of tradable and non-

4

A recent reform beginning in 2005 aims at eliminating trading right difference between tradable and nontradable shares, i.e., making all shares tradable. However, even after the reform, the state shareholders can only sell their holdings upon the approval of the state-owned assets authorities.

5

Parts of this discussion draw on Morck, Yeung and Zhao (2005).

- 11 -

tradable shares. 6 Naturally, vested interests within the state organs see a high dividend as undesirable because they have 100% of the control if the earnings are retained but little to gain once they are distributed. A sequence of legal and regulatory reforms has done little to alter this fundamental power imbalance. State-appointed independent directors often see the world much as do state-appointed CEOs. Moreover, every listed firm’s board has a parallel authority structure, the firm’s Party Committee, headed by its Party Secretary. Reforms to the board leave this hidden – or not-sohidden – real power structure untouched. The Party Secretary may or may not chair the board, and Party Committee members may or may not serve as directors. Where the two structures do not overlap, real power flows through the Party channels, leaving the board and formal corporate top executives with scant real authority. In the large SOEs, the Party Secretary appoints the top executives and directors, often simply relaying orders from the Communist Party of China’s Organizational Department, and exercises a leading role in the company. The ultimate function of the Party Committee and Party Secretary may change as corporate governance reforms occur, but this remains unresolved. For example, whether listed companies’ managers might someday report to shareholders, rather than the Party, is debated. At present, the Party Committee monitors and evaluates corporate executives, determining their prospects for career advancement. The CEOs of the largest 53 national SOEs are appointed directly by the Communist Party of China’s Organizational Department. The other senior management positions are mostly appointed by the State-Owned Assets Supervision and Administration Commission (SASAC), which is directed by the State Council. Similar patterns hold for the local SOEs.7

6

For example, the 169 national SOEs have never paid dividends to the state. A new proposal is under consideration to require dividend payment on state shares, beginning in 2007.

7

Caijing, Volume 174, December 11, 2006

- 12 -

The full extent of State and Party influence over corporate management is rendered obvious with examples of top executive turnover. PetroChina, a subsidiary of China National Petroleum Corporation, trades on both the New York Stock Exchange (NYSE) and the Hong Kong Stock Exchange (HKSE). In April 2003, Mr. Li Yizhong, then Chairmen of the Board of CNPC, was appointed to the SASAC and replaced by Mr. Chen Tonghai, a former State Planning Commission official. In October 2003, Mr. Wei Liucheng, then CEO, Chairman of the Board, and Party Secretary of China National Offshore Oil Corp. (CNOOC) was appointed Governor of Hainan Province. In November 2004, the top managers of the three largest telecommunication companies in China – China Mobile, China Telecom and China Unicom – exchanged positions almost overnight without prior notice to public shareholders. In short, executive positions in listed firms are filled by State and Party bureaucrats and are seen as steps in the career of a successful civil servant. The current corporate governance structure is unlikely to reward managers who honestly admit that investment opportunities are limited and advocate disbursing excess earnings to shareholders. Unpaid dividends are, of course, corporate savings!8 For Party officials who have real control but little personal stake in their company’s long-term economic performance, underwriting unprofitable, but politically important, projects is likely sound strategy for career advancement in both Party and State bureaucracies.9 High retained earnings can finance featherbedding, and thus provide social stability by keeping unemployment low. They can also finance overt symbols of power and grandeur, such as ―national champion‖ SOEs taking over companies in foreign countries.
8

If earnings beyond profitable investment needs were disbursed to shareholders, they would show up either as consumption and household investment goods (e.g., houses, cars), or as additional household savings (bank deposits or portfolio investments).

9

These are often called ―image projects‖ (形象工程) or “political achievement project‖ (政绩工程).

- 13 -

Capital market distortion Distortion in China’s capital markets compound distortions in managerial incentives. China’s capital markets are dominated by banks, especially the ―Big Four‖ state-controlled banks – the Bank of China (BOC), Industrial and Commercial Bank of China (ICBC), China Construction Bank (CCB), and Agricultural Bank of China (ABC) –together responsible for about threequarters of all commercial loans and just over half of total banking assets as of the end of 2005.10 Household savings and idle corporate funds both turn up as bank deposits, and these are recycled as bank loans. Most of the loans go to the state sector, often due to the preferential policies set by the local government and the banks’ lack of competency in evaluating risks (Tsai, 2002). According to the Financial Statistics Yearbook (2005) published by the People’s Bank of China, SOEs account for 73% of the short-term bank loans between 2001 and 2004. This means that even SOEs that merely hoard earnings as bank deposits, without actually initiating foreign acquisitions, still help fund the FDI of other SOEs. The OECD’s 2005 Economic Survey of China shows the private sector to be the true engines of economic growth, accounting for 59.2% of value added in the economy. 11 These growing companies face ongoing capital constraints, and must finance their growth largely with informal financing (Allen et al., 2005). Ayyagari et al. (2007, Table 7) shows that firms that do obtain bank loans subsequently post elevated sales, but not productivity growth, while firms that rely on alternative channels of financing post slower sales growth, but stronger productivity growth.

10

Stephen Thomas and Chen Ji: Banking on Reform, in China Business Review, a publication of US-China Business Council, May-June 2006.

11

See the table in Chapter 2, Economic Survey of China, Paris: OECD, September 16, 2005. The survey defines private enterprises as those controlled by individuals or legal persons, in contrast to the ―statecontrolled‖ and ―collectively controlled‖.

- 14 -

Dollar and Wei (2007) also show that, even after years of reform, state-owned firms still have significantly lower returns to capital, on average, than domestic private or foreign-owned firms. This is consistent with China’s banking system channeling savings to firms with limited capabilities and profitable investment opportunities. Some of these funds may end up in China’s highly visible outward FDI, but this may well be the visible tip of a much larger capital misallocation iceberg. In summary, China’s recent outward FDI surge is likely a manifestation of its inability to reinvest efficiently its high corporate and individual savings. This distorted capital flow is propelled by the governance structure of large SOEs and by inefficiencies in its banking sector. Grandiose and patriotism-inspiring initiatives, like takeovers of foreign companies, legitimize the continuation of the political status quo. Over the longer term, deflecting capital away from more efficient private sector ventures may compromise both continued economic growth and political stability. It is worth pointing out that the risks of outward FDI are not going unnoticed in China. The rationale and efficiency of companies going abroad have been frequently discussed in Chinese newspapers, academic journals, and some high-profile economic forums.12 Many have called for caution and patience, emphasizing that FDI would be a long learning process for Chinese companies. Managers also try not to repeat the experience of their Japanese counterparts in the 1980s, and frequently seek the help of external advisors with their due diligence investigations. Overall, we do not argue that all outward FDI from China is unjustified. We just caution that the current parameters of governance and bank lending do suggest a high likelihood of wasteful investments. Meanwhile, private companies with otherwise great overseas opportunities may be kept away from the door.
12

For example, the Ministry of Commerce and the UNCTAD jointly organize the annual ―International Forum on Chinese Companies Going Global‖ in Beijing in 2006 and 2007.

- 15 -

IV. Perspectives at the Firm Level Regardless of the above economy-level considerations, FDI may be economically rational from an individual firms’ perspective. To explore this, we therefore turn to the theory of the firm and discuss microeconomic justifications of China’s outward FDI.

Internalization: political wiles as an asset Much FDI by multinational firms is thought to add value by raising the returns to corporate investment in research and development (R&D), brand creation, and other ventures with large fixed costs and high risks of market transactions (e.g., Buckley and Casson 1976). (For empirical evidence, see Morck and Yeung, 1991, 1992.) For example, an auto company can invest more in R&D if any productivity enhancing innovations can be applied to large-scale operations around the world, rather than in a smaller scale operation confined to its home country. The company may want to conduct internalization FDI because, by keeping productivity enhancements internal to the company, it can gain higher returns while reducing the risk of intellectual property rights misappropriation. At first blush, this perspective seems off in China’s case. It implies that firms with large past investments in enhanced productivity should lead China’s FDI surge. This is not observed; instead, large relatively inefficient SOEs lead the charge, and more efficient private enterprises remain largely domestic. The internalization theory also suggests that China’s FDI surge should be disproportionately into countries with larger domestic markets that can better contribute to economies of scale and scope in the use of such productivity enhancements. This too is not observed, for the targets of China’s outward FDI are mainly in Southeast Asia and Africa, not Europe, Japan, or North America. Nonetheless, some Chinese FDI does accord with this intuition. For example, China’s vast but highly regionalized domestic markets may school Chinese businesses in catering to large and

- 16 -

complex customer bases. If so, this expertise might qualify as a large fixed cost investment, like the automaker’s R&D, whose return is magnified by expanding into more regions. One possible case of this might be Chinese telecommunication companies’ recent attempt to expand in Southeast Asia. Given this interpretation, these Chinese firms’ FDI nicely fits the standard internalization model, assuming that this expertise really exists, and that it is valuable outside China. A modified internalization perspective might have more general traction in explaining the trend in China’s recent FDI. Many of the Asian and African countries targeted by Chinese FDI have chronically weak institutions. Huang et al. (2004) show that most ASEAN economies have high level of direct state intervention, insecure property rights protection, and opaque corporate governance. These institutional deficiencies impede capital market development (La Porta et al., 1997; 1998), and raise costs of capital for local firms (Morck et al., 2005). For western and Japanese multinationals with financial resources (Desai et al., 2004), corrupt or otherwise dysfunctional institutions in these countries create difficulty for their local operations, and trigger investor pressure to withdraw from such locations. Perkins (2005) shows that past experience in certain institutional environments significantly predicts survival when a firm invests in another such environment. Compared to firms from highly developed countries, Chinese firms are more experienced with such institutional features, and are likely far more capable of dealing with burdensome regulations and navigating around the opaque political constraints. Such capabilities become an intangible asset that might make FDI into like environments far more profitable for Chinese companies than for other foreign firms. Our internalization theory thus posits that Chinese SOEs have developed sophisticated measures that help them operate despite endemic government interference and related problems. By expanding into economies with similar institutional environments, they can achieve large returns

- 17 -

on these past investments. In 2005, PetroKazakhstan, a Canadian owned concern with operations primarily in Kazahstan, found itself unable to enforce its previous agreements with a Kazakh government bent on expropriation. The state-owned CNPC again stepped in and bought out PetroKazakhstan for $4.2 billion. PetroKazakhstan’s investors exited with some capital intact and CNPC was able to enforce contracts and property rights where a private sector Canadian firm could not.

Who is the boss, and why? Another perspective may further reconcile standard explanations of FDI with Chinese firms’ multinational expansion. In the automaker example above, we imagined a U.S. automaker with unique productivity-enhancing technology taking over foreign automakers and applying its new technology to their operations as well as its own. This lets the innovative U.S. automaker not only apply its innovation on a global scale, but keep knowledge of the innovation internal. In recent years, China has become a global manufacturing hub. In most cases, foreign firms with unique technological expertise or valuable brand names direct FDI into China, building or acquiring control of manufacturing facilities there. But in a few high-profile cases, Chinese manufacturing firms sought to acquire the firms in rich countries that provide them with up-todate technology. In this category perhaps fall Lenovo’s acquisition of IBM’s PC manufacturing unit and Haier’s bid for Maytag. These cases stand opposite to our carmaker model, as if a lowtech Chinese automaker bought the innovative U.S. firm and its technology, and then undertook to apply the technology on a global scale. In a typical FDI venture, the firm that developed the intangible asset – the technological or advertising heavy firm – is the acquirer, and retains control to protect its property rights over that asset. Grossman and Hart (1980) argue that control should reside with the party whose noncontractible effort is more important in creating value for firm. In the traditional FDI setting with

- 18 -

the acquirer from a developed country, this party is the firm that initially produced the critical intangible asset. A new technology must be updated continuously, or risks eclipse by advances elsewhere. A brand name made valuable by a reputation for high quality must be safeguarded by continual rigorous quality control. Failure to keep pace with the expanding technology frontier or to safeguard the value of a brand name courts disaster, and the Chinese manufacturing firm typically lacks the ability to contract and monitor the foreign firms’ performance in these dimensions. The foreign firm, in contrast, can monitor and control the Chinese production operation, at least to a considerable extent. Thus, in a typical inward FDI investment into China, a foreign firm with a technological edge or a brand name acquires physical assets in China that help it produce for Chinese or global markets. However, this logic need not apply in all cases. IBM saw PCs becoming commoditized, with rapidly evaporating profit margin. While technology advances continue to affect key components, actual PC assembly becomes routine, which made technology maintenance and upgrading more contractible and less critical. The terms of competition tilted towards production cost and quality control. In this setting, actions by the managers of the Chinese assembly plants became important enough to justify Lenovo taking control of IBM’s PC unit. Conceivably, similar logic induced TCL’s takeover of Thomson’s TV and DVD businesses in Europe and elsewhere. More generally, in maturing industries, intensifying price competition in increasingly standardized products renders manufacturing quality more important than cutting edge R&D, and rigorous cost control more important than brand name recognition. In such circumstances, a reversal of roles becomes rational: the production unit takes over the R&D or brand-building unit because its non-contractible effort becomes more important in creating value.

- 19 -

Private benefits of control Above, we suggest that China’s outward FDI surge per se is not necessarily economically wasteful, but its many and profound institutional infirmities, especially the corporate governance and banking system deficits highlighted above, are reasons for concern. The civil servants manning the Party Committees that govern China’s SOEs, listed or not, and the Party appointees governing China’s state-run banks are economically rational people with well-defined goals, which they can be expected to pursue. These goals may not accord with the long-term financial viability of the firms or banks they govern; and to understand China’s outward FDI better, a deeper understanding of those goals might be useful. Private benefits of control are benefits enjoyed by a dominant controlling owner above and beyond dividends and other cash flow rights, which also accrue to public shareholders. Much evidence shows that controlling shareholders in many countries preserve their control with, e.g., super-voting shares, even though these structures are empirically linked to depressed valuations. Insiders also lock in their control with staggered boards, pyramiding, and various other entrenchment devices that empirically prove value-destroying. These actions suggest that corporate insiders, including controlling shareholders, derive private benefits large enough to compensate the controlling shareholder for the depressed value of her shares. While there are multiple ways to combine the Chinese and foreign firms’ capabilities, executives who value private benefits of control high sufficiently may choose acquisitions over other possibilities, such as long-term contracts or technology licenses, and are willing to pay for this with a depressed share valuation. These private benefits may be pecuniary, such as wealth accumulated through self-dealing or insider trading. The FDI flowing from Chinese SEOs into Caribbean tax havens, where it essentially disappears from sight, might ultimately become a pecuniary private benefit of control

- 20 -

for the SEOs’ insiders. But the private benefits of control also include non-pecuniary gains, such as status, power, and respect. Conceivably, China’s outward FDI is a manifestation of executives pursuing such intangible benefits. Indeed, there are plausible reasons for expecting such insiders to value control highly indeed. First, some top executives – especially the Party Committee members governing SOEs – may have difficulty escaping the mindset of a command economy, in which direct control is the only way to coordinate economic activity. Even now, many Chinese executives are uncomfortable with contractual arrangements and market forces. In part, this may be an understandable response to judicial inefficiency and market failures in China, where free market institutions remain a work-in-progress. Assuming similar problems in world markets, Chinese executives might overvalue direct control over e.g. natural resources. This mindset may persist until a new generation of Chinese executives, with more confidence in markets, takes over. Weak corporate governance likely further reinforces the importance of ―control‖ to many Chinese executives. Experience proves, in China at least, that investing in firms one does not control puts one at the mercy of their controlling shareholders. Weak corporate governance creates a junglelike ethic of ―control or be controlled‖ – investors who do not wield control find themselves at the mercy of whoever does, and cannot expect to be treated tenderly. Not trusting institutions outside China either, they may perceive outward FDI as necessary to control their dealings abroad. In countries with well developed institutions, contracts and legal rights may be cheaper, and hence more efficient ways to organize their dealings, but Chinese executives may have to learn this from experience. Finally, enhancing national pride is quite likely a hugely important private benefit of control. Although many Chinese call for caution in overseas expansion, citing the examples of earlier failures, phrases like ―The Age of Chinese Acquisitions‖ still frequent media headlines. The

- 21 -

corporate executives, Party Committee members, and bankers seen thus restoring China’s honor as a true economic power arguably gain respect and status unattainable by any other means.

V. Conclusion Despite the media buzz, China’s outward FDI is still relatively small. Its flow and stock are tiny relative to its GDP, even compared to those of other developing countries. Moreover, China’s outward FDI is mostly acquisitions in neighboring Asian countries and resource-rich parts of Africa. As China develops rapidly, the scope and scale of Chinese outward FDI merits on-going analysis by international business scholars, for it is a manifestation of the economic, organizational and managerial transformation in the country, and of its relation with the rest of the world. This paper develops perspectives we hope can facilitate a better understanding of the deeper causes and consequences of China’s outward FDI. From economy-wide perspectives, we show that China’s outward FDI is unsurprising, given the economy’s remarkably high savings rate, but there are reasons for caution. Currently, the leading players are large SOEs with lucrative state-enforced monopolies in natural resources or infrastructure sectors. Due to their peculiar ownership and incentive structures, large SOEs tend to hoard retained earnings, rather than distribute dividends to shareholders. China’s bankdominated capital allocation also likely channels savings disproportionately to these SOEs. Hence, the insiders, especially their Party Secretaries and Party Committee members, may use these retained earnings to fund investments that advance their careers as bureaucrats, like ―flagship‖ projects overseas, rather than investments with high economic returns. In spite of the causes for concern, standard economic rationales for FDI take on unexpected new forms in China, and may justify some, perhaps even much, of China’s outward FDI. Three rationales are of note. First, the internalization theory of FDI, appropriately reinterpreted,

- 22 -

suggests that Chinese companies, with vast experience in navigating complex bureaucracies, might do well in countries with similar institutional environments. Second, in certain maturing industries, outward FDI from China, even into advanced economies, might make economic sense. This ownership reversal, which we develop from the perspective of Grossman and Hart (1986), argues that the party possessing manufacturing capabilities becomes the ―boss‖ as the locus of competition shifts from innovation to production cost and quality control. Third, China’s outward FDI may be justified economically to SOE insiders who overvalue control due to their distrust of markets and sense of national pride. This third rationale can continue as long as those who control China’s business enterprises continue to accept below-market share valuations in exchange for these perceived benefits of control. All the above perspectives are consistent with the stylized facts we observe, and are potentially at work behind China’s outward FDI surge. Thus, depending on the actual mechanism, Chinese outward FDI may have very mixed performance as the future unfolds. Moreover, we focus on pre-entry motivations, and disregard the very real challenges of post-entry integration. Due to substantial differences in culture and managerial practices, even a priori well-justified FDI investments may be mired in unexpected difficulties. For example, the Chinese steelmaker Shougang Group has been plagued by strikes and labor conflicts in South America. Shanghai Automotive Industrial Corporation (SAIC) has similar experiences in South Korea after acquiring SsangYong Motor in 2004. Further study of China’s outward FDI is likely to be rewarding. In the years to come, we expect significant growth in China’s outward FDI, not only in volume, but also in variety across industries and organizational forms. More importantly, we expect that the globalization experience will transform many Chinese companies, especially those entering developed countries and competing in higher-end product markets. How will Chinese firms establish a global identity, design flexible operations across countries, and improve corporate governance at

- 23 -

both the headquarters and global network levels? How will corporate governance improve in Chinese firms as they compete in global markets, and as Chinese domestic institutions develop? What sort of modern management system is compatible with the path that China has followed? These issues have profound consequences for China’s long-term economic and institutional development, and for our deeper understanding of international business. Studying these phenomena in their infancy also provides scope for longitudinal research. The dynamic evolution of firms and institutions not only offers a rich empirical setting for various research questions, but also lets researchers avoid ex-post observation biases. For example, a common problem in studying globalization is that only surviving firms are observable ex post. Since there will always be good learners and success stories, the estimated efficiency of any country’s outward FDI may be misleadingly high, for the accounting misses failed projects that are essentially ―tuition paid‖ – lessons about how to succeed. Careful work beginning now will give us a much more comprehensive picture. Finally, international business research is cross-disciplinary in nature, and China’s outward FDI promises a cross-disciplinary research cornucopia. As our earlier discussion indicates, the structural transition in China mandates that any sensible economic analysis of firm strategies will have to take institutional, political and social aspects into consideration. Given the visible hands of the Chinese State and the Party in the economy, any micro-level analysis will not be complete without a macro level background. Exciting new insights are likely to be gleaned from this rich context.

- 24 -

References Allen, Franklin, Jun Qian and Meijun Qian (2005) ―Law, Finance, and Economic Growth in China,‖ Journal of Financial Economics, 77: 57-116. Ayyagari, Meghana, Asli Demirguc-Kunt and Vojislav Maksimovic (2007) ―Formal vs. Informal Finance: Evidence from China,‖ Worldbank Micro Financing Conference Paper, March, 2007. Buckley, Peter J. and Mark Casson, C. (1976, 2002). The Future of the Multinational Enterprise. (1st edition, 1976, London: Macmillan, 2nd edition, 2002, Palgrave). Desai, Mihir A., C. Fritz Foley and James R. Hines Jr. (2004) ―A Multinational Perspective on Capital Structure Choice and Internal Capital Markets,‖ Journal of Finance, 59(6): 2451-2488. Dollar, David and Shang-Jin Wei (2007) ―Das (Wasted) Kapital: Firm Ownership and Investment Efficiency in China,‖ NBER Working Paper No. 13103 Economic Survey of China, Paris: OECD, September 16, 2005. Grossman, Sanford J. and Oliver D. Hart (1986) ―The Costs and Benefits of Ownership: A Theory of Vertical and Lateral Integration,‖ Journal of Political Economy, 94(4): 691-719. Harris, David G. (1993) ―The Impact of U.S. Tax Law Revision on Multinational Corporations' Capital Location and Income-Shifting Decisions,‖ Journal of Accounting Research, 31: 111-140. Huang, Yaseng, Randall Morck and Bernard Yeung (2004) ―ASEAN Countries, External Threat, FTAA, and Internal Institutional Weaknesses,‖ Business and Politics, 6(1). Jensen, Michael C. (1986) ―The Agency Costs of Free Cash Flow: Corporate Finance and Takeovers,‖ American Economic Review, 76(2): 323-29. Kuijs, Louis (2006) ―How Will China's Saving-Investment Balance Evolve?‖ World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 3958.

- 25 -

La Porta, Rafael, Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes, Andrei Shleifer and Robert Vishny (2000) ―Agency Problems and Dividend Policies around the World,‖ Journal of Finance, 55(1): 1-33. La Porta, Rafael, Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes, Andrei Shleifer and Robert Vishny (1998) ―Law and Finance,‖ Journal of Political Economy, 106(6): 1113-55. La Porta, Rafael, Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes, Andrei Shleifer and Robert Vishny (1997) ―Legal Determinants of External Finance,‖ Journal of Finance, 52(3): 1131-50. Morck, Randall and Masao Nakamura (2000) ―Japanese Corporate Governance and Macroeconomic Problems,‖ Harvard Institute of Economic Research Paper No. 1893. Morck, Randall and Bernard Yeung (1992) ―Internalization: An Event Study Test,‖ Journal of International Economics, Vol. 33, (August), p. 41-56. Morck, Randall and Bernard Yeung (1991) ―Why Investors Value Multinationality,‖ Journal of Business, 64(2): 165-87. Morck, Randall, Bernard Yeung and Minyuan Zhao (2005) ―China’s Lucky Corporate Governance,‖ Peking University Business Forum, September. Perkins, Susan (2005) ―Does Prior Experience Really Pay? Foreign Direct Investments, Institutional Environments and Firm Performance,‖ Doctoral Dissertation, New York University. Thomas, Stephen and Chen Ji (2006) ―Banking on Reform,‖ China Business Review, (a publication of US-China Business Council) May-June. Tsai, Kellee S. (2002) Back-Alley Banking: Private Entrepreneurs in China. Cornell University Press: New York.

- 26 -

Similar Documents

Free Essay

Fdi China

...BEC_2047753W anonymous marking enabled WORD COUNT CHARACTER COUNT 2657 16583 TIME SUBMITTED PAPER ID 04-APR-2013 07:28AM 23032084 BEC_2047753W ORIGINALITY REPORT 30 % SIMILARITY INDEX 21 % INTERNET SOURCES 7% PUBLICATIONS 25 % STUDENT PAPERS PRIMARY SOURCES 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 www.unctad-docs.org Internet Source Submitted to University of Glasgow Student Paper Submitted to Royal Holloway and Bedford New College Student Paper ftp.iza.org Internet Source Submitted to University of Leeds Student Paper Submitted to The University of Manchester Student Paper Submitted to University of Liverpool Student Paper Submitted to University of Northumbria at Newcastle Student Paper Submitted to University of Westminster Student Paper english.peopledaily.com.cn Internet Source Submitted to Manchester Metropolitan University Student Paper www.novelguide.com Internet Source Submitted to London School of Economics and Political Science Student Paper Submitted to University of Huddersfield Student Paper Submitted to University of Bath Student Paper Submitted to University of Bristol Student Paper 5% 4% 2% 2% 2% 2% 1% 1% 1% 1% 1% 1% 1% 1% 1% 1% 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 www.merger.org.cn Internet Source www.firstexind.com Internet Source www.cdo.ugent.be Internet Source Submitted to University of East London Student Paper www.uni-due...

Words: 270 - Pages: 2

Premium Essay

Fdi in America and China

...Executive summary. The greenfield FDI is a form of direct investment where a parent company starts a new business in a foreign country by setting up new operational facilities. In addition to building new facilities, most parent companies also create new long-term jobs in the foreign country by hiring new employees. In order to decide which country is better for ‘greenfield’ foreign direct investment via sole ownership, the advantages and disadvantages of the countries should be considered. For example, China is a developing country, and during the past 30 years, China’s rapid economic development shows that China has a strong power in developing economic. In recent decades, China stays on one of the leading positions in direct investment and therefore a lot of investments to this country are considered to be profitable for any company or investor. The reasons are simple: the growth of the economy and a large number of different projects. Foreign direct investment in China, due to stable growth potential of the economy and a huge production resources, aimed at both the external and the internal market.The innovative ability is a great attraction for investment managers around the world. In contrast, a lot of foreign investors had chosen China for investment and this resulted in a very big competition. Nevertheless, USA is a successfully developed country. And its economy is the top one in the world. As the most important country in the first world countries, the USA...

Words: 5010 - Pages: 21

Premium Essay

Vw Fdi China

...Volkswagen’s Entry Strategy in China’s Car Market 21/1/2013 Content Page Table of Contents Abstract 1 Introduction 1 Literature review 2 Volkswagen rational for China – Dunning’s Eclectic Paradigm. 4 Conclusion 6 References 7 Abstract China is one of the most attractive destinations for Foreign Direct Investments in the world. It is first destination for Inward FDI among developing countries (WTO, 2012). China has developed second world’s largest car market after U.S.A. and has been the largest car producer in the world since 2008. German company Volkswagen (hereafter VW) is the world’s second largest motor vehicle manufacturer after Toyota Motor (CNN, 2012) and the biggest manufacturer in Europe. VW is one of the earliest investors and the biggest foreign car maker in China with 15% of market shares. This report, by applying relevant theories, such as Dunning’s eclectic paradigm or Hymer’s internationalization theory, will explain why VW Company decided to invest in China through joint venture rather than acquisition or Greenfield investment. Introduction Chinese car industry, as well as many other branches, is very young, although dynamic and fast growing. In 1978 Chinese government introduced policy of open doors which allowed foreign companies to invest and operate in China. Since then car sector has developed rapidly from an infant to a mature industry. Moreover, Chinese government provides various incentives in order to attract foreign firms...

Words: 2781 - Pages: 12

Premium Essay

Determinants of Fdi in China

...DETERMINANTS OF FDI IN CHINA DETERMINANTS OF FDI IN CHINA Shaukat Ali and Wei Guo1 ABSTRACT Why and how firms take advantage of foreign opportunities, especially via foreign direct investment (FDI) has been much documented. China, as a major emerging market, has attracted significant flows of FDI, to become the second largest receipt. This paper briefly examines the literature on FDI and focuses on likely determinants of FDI in China. It then analyses responses from 22 firms operating in China on what they see as the important motivations for them to undertake FDI. Results show that market size is a major factor for FDI especially for US firms. For local, export-orientated, Asian firms, low labor costs are the main factor. The paper concludes with managerial implications for businesses wish to exploit opportunities in China. INTRODUCTION The past few years has seen a tremendous growth of foreign direct investment (FDI) that has exceeded both world output and world trade. China is by far the largest recipient, and in 2004 surpassed the USA as host destination. It has consequently attracted an increasing attention from multinational businesses. Since China adopted the reform and opening-up policy in the late 1970s, foreign investment has played an increasingly important role in its economic growth. According to the World Investment Report for 2004 by the United Nations Conference on Trade and Development, China absorbed a total of US$53.5 billion worth of ...

Words: 7747 - Pages: 31

Premium Essay

The Effects of Foreign Direct Investment (Fdi) on the Economic Growth of China

...of foreign direct investment (FDI) on the economic growth of China. Such growth was achieved through China taking in tremendous amounts in FDI, increasing its productivity, especially in the export manufacturing sector of the economy. This paper provides mounting evidence that China’s growth has been largely fuelled by FDI through capital formation, export promotion, technological and skill transfer, increased tax revenues. Similarly, the creation of a larger middle class, encouragement of economic reforms and increased infrastructure spending has fueled the inflow of FDI into China further increasing the growth of China’s economic growth. FDI plays an extraordinary and growing role in global business. Tuan, C., & Ng, L.F-Y. (2007) pointed that FDI has fuelled economic growth in China by attracting capital investments and creation of employment; increasing manufacturing exports; bringing skilled labor and international brand names and transferring knowledge and technology to local economy. FDI has improved developments in infrastructure and expanded domestic market through job creation. The fixed capital investment in economic growth has been considered one of the basic principles in economic. FDI is of special interest for its supposed positive effects on growth (Qi, 2007). In 1980, the ratio of FDI inflow to China’s Gross Domestic Investment was negligible. It had increased to 7% by 1992, and up again to 36% by 2004 (Rising FDI into China: The Facts Behind the Numbers...

Words: 1521 - Pages: 7

Premium Essay

Evolusi Perusahaan Mnc Di Hongkong Dan Singapura

...entrepôt(gudang) for trade in South East Asia and China, indigenous (adat) Chinese firms(perusahaan) based in Hong Kong emerged(munculnya) as MNCs in the early 1950s, thus reflecting(mencerminkan) a longer history by comparison to MNCs from Taiwan and South Korea whose emergence(muncul) can be traced(ditelusuri) to the early 1960s. Hong Kong has grown to become a significant home country(negara asal) of FDI(foreign direct investment) with an outward FDI stock of ,$154.9 billion in 1998, or some 3.8 per cent of the global stock of outward FDI. Indeed, it had become the world’s tenth-largest source of FDI in that year based on the size of outward FDI stock after the United States (with a share of 24.1 per cent of the global stock of outward FDI), United Kingdom (12.1 per cent), Germany (9.5 per cent), Japan (7.2 per cent), the Netherlands (6.4 per cent), France (5.9 per cent), Switzerland (4.3 per cent), Italy (4.1 per cent) and Canada (3.8 per cent). In fact, Hong Kong is almost as important as Canada whose outward FDI stock was $156.6 billion in that year. Thus, Hong Kong had become a significant source of FDI in the world economy, particularly more so in relation to the stock of outward FDI from developing countries where Hong Kong is the single largest home country with a share of almost 40 per cent. Not only is Hong Kong comparable to Switzerland as a home country of FDI in terms of the size of outward FDI stock, the study of the emergence and evolution of...

Words: 1995 - Pages: 8

Premium Essay

Doing Business in China

...Essay 1 Although the potential market in China is very attractive to FDI, it still have many risks that stopping the FDI decide to invest in China. In order to further attract inward FDI and optimize its structure to meet China’s goals of economic development, there are few measures that the China government should take, including providing more knowledge about the market, providing more networking and connections and enhance the investment environment of China. Taking these measures can effectively attract more inward FDI to invest in China. First of all, many FDI has lack of knowledge about the market which make them afraid of investing in China. Therefore I suggest that the China government can provide more information about the market such as the history of investment of the target market, the development of the target market and the structure of the target market. This can help FDI gaining more knowledge about the target market and thus can lower the risk of failure investment. Moreover, being insensitive to Chinese culture, social norms is also one of the major factor that lead to failure investment for FDI. I suggest that the China government can hold some forums or talks introducing the culture of China and the difference between western and Chinese culture. Secondly, lacking of networking and connections in China will also stop the FDI invest in China. Since most of the FDI has lack of the knowledge about the market, they need to find networking or connections...

Words: 538 - Pages: 3

Premium Essay

What Is That?

...International Trade Discuss the main determinants of FDI in China compared to Hong Kong. Is a country (or natural person investors Legal person Cross border capital investment) or other factors of production, in order to obtain or control the corresponding enterprise management right Core In order to obtain profits, or for the purpose of scarce production factors Investment activities . Main determinants of FDI in China Obviously, cheaper labour costs were the major determinant for foreign investment in China. Then, in the early 1990s, the Chinese government started to place more emphasis on technology-intensive investment. Nearly 400 of the Fortune 500 firms have invested in over 2,000 projects in China in various industries such as: computers, electronics, telecommunications equipment, pharmaceuticals, petrochemicals, power-generating equipment etc. A recent bright spot for direct investment in China has been represented by the R&D activities, with over 100 R&D centres established by transnational corporations such Microsoft, Motorola, GM, GE, Samsung, Ericson, Nokia, Panasonic, Mitsubishi, Siemens, to name only a few. According to UNCTAD sources, Motorola, for example, has established R&D centres in the area of electronics, based on US$200 million in investment and 650 research personnel. Also, Microsoft invested US$80 million in a Chinese research institute and has announced the investment of a further US$50 million to create a Microsoft Asian...

Words: 499 - Pages: 2

Premium Essay

China Case

...China – entry into WTO * Reduction of trade barriers, and limits to import. * Reduction of goverment subsidies and other form of support. * Equal treatment for foreign and domestic firms. * Trade barriers between provinces removed. * Market size up, opportunity to export. * Opportunity to offshoring and outsourcing. Steel – before 2000 * Many low quality steel mills; subsidies * Overemployment * Only 8 mills reached min efficiency to win profits. * World’s biggest production of steel and iron. * Productivity – 10% of other countries productivity. * China demand for high-end steel: undersupplied, but supply off low-end stell: oversupply. After 2000: Reduce subsidies – small steel mills exit * Acquisitions mergers * Ricardian model: China specializes in low-end steel. * Krugman: small firms should exit * large firms grow * medium firms: characterize supply PC: Before 2000 * China produces low-end products * High growth of the market, focus on education * Price wars in the late 90’s * Competitive with HP, Dell etc. * Profit seekers. After 2000: * Market experience * Competitive with western firms Monopolistic competition. AC falls. Offshoring to China: Hardware and low skilled labor – wage difference TV: Before 2000: Oversupply, saturated market. * Unused capacity * Financial support from the government * Foreign tv producers target high-end...

Words: 474 - Pages: 2

Premium Essay

International Business- Assignment 4

...To: Reader From: Nicole Ki Date: June 26, 2014 Re: International Business- Assignment 4 Questions 1. Discuss the implications of globalization on the food industry in China. 2. What makes China so attractive to U.S. food companies? Discuss why it is important to gain 3. Reflect on the standardization versus adaptation debate as it relates to marketing fast food and processed food in China. Using the ‘4Ps’ of marketing, discuss how companies should approach the market. Which elements in the marketing mix can be standardized? Which elements must be adapted to suit local preferences? See http://www.mindtools.com/pages/article/newSTR_94.htm 4. How is Western culture influencing China’s culture? Discuss how companies like Frito Lay and McDonald’s are contributing to this change. What are the implications of this trend? Answers 1. There are four different implications of globalization in the food industry in China. The first implication would be the slow demise of a common understanding of an American way of eating. To be certain, families and other institutions will always have their own food traditions and preferences, and certain food items (e.g., hot dogs or hamburgers) may continue to enjoy long-standing popularity within our culture. But the idea that there will be a "commonly understood" cuisine served at critical ritual occasions such as weddings, parties or summer picnics is quickly becoming a thing of the past. One need merely consider the diversity...

Words: 1202 - Pages: 5

Premium Essay

Recentering Globalization

...Reviews Koichi Iwabuchi, Recentering Globalization: Popular Culture and Japanese Transnationalism. Durham and London: Duke University Press, 2002. 275 pp., including references and index. ISBN 0-8223-2891-7. In this book, Koichi Iwabuchi, a Cultural Studies scholar based in Japan, explores intellectual discourses, marketing strategies and audience consumption of Japanese popular culture in a transnational Asian context. In other words, he examines Japan's encounter with a 'modern' Asia by focusing on the diffusion of its commercialized popular culture. This has been made possible by the globalization of media, which itself encouraged an incipient expansion of a hitherto largely domestic-oriented Japanese media production system to other Asian markets. There have been two results from this expansion of mediated popular culture. In the first place, it brings into question the assumed hegemony of American mass culture (from Disney to McDonald's) and shows how, in East and Southeast Asia at least, Japanese contemporary culture is extremely significant – especially in the global cities of Seoul, Shanghai, Taipei, Hong Kong, Singapore and so on. Second, and more troubling so far as Iwabuchi is concerned, Japan's 'return to Asia' from the 1990s, when it began reasserting its Asian identity, contains echoes of World War II colonialism since Japanese tend to regard themselves as 'above' other Asian countries because of their superior technology and production capacity...

Words: 5521 - Pages: 23

Premium Essay

Citrus Industry Australia and China

...is about moving investment and economic activity from its current concentration in China’s south and its coastline, inland to the flourishing mega-cities of the inner western region. TARGETS 'Going out' refers to China’s strategy of growing offshore investment. With food security and safety for a billion people a priority for policymakers, external investment in agriculture and food interests is a high priority for investment targets. Healthcare and education - a bonus for Australian universities - is also a priority, these investments are likely to help China’s pivot from a manufacturing to a service economy. TARGETS 'Going green' is a delayed attempt to address the consequences of growth-at-all-costs. In contrast to Australia, China is making colossal investments in 'cleantech' like renewable energy. Its cleantech outlay currently stands at about US$65 billion a year. Spending on renewable energy alone has been growing at a rate of 77 per cent a year since 2008. TARGETS OTHER TARGETS There are many challenges that arise when...

Words: 974 - Pages: 4

Premium Essay

Foreign Investment in Chinese Banking Sector: Hr Challenges

...significant foreign interest and investment. • However, while most of the developing nations adopted trends set by the global banking giants, China made its own norms and forced those banking giants to comply with it. • Instead of the traditional mergers and acquisitions practiced in most foreign direct investments, China offered strategic partnerships to a maximum permissible limit of 20%, while total foreign ownership in any bank was capped at 25%. • The global banks developed customized lending policies, banks cards, and asset management products to cater to the huge retail banking market. • The partnership between the foreign partner and the Chinese bank not only needed to be a strategic fit and complementary in nature, but it also had to be in line with Chinese culture and value system and had to gradually modify the system to make it more beneficial for both parties. • Biggest challenge for the strategic alliances came from the alignment of the critical human resource management (HRM) functions such as HR planning, staffing, appraisal, training and development, employee retention, etc., with Chinese culture. Key Issues Differences in Business Cultures • The differences in culture, labor markets, and employments systems between China and other countries created challenges for multinational companies operating in China. • Chinese management style was based on relationship building and development of trust. There was strong overlap between personal and business...

Words: 595 - Pages: 3

Premium Essay

Expatriate Management In Human Resource Management

...The purpose of this paper is to provide a comprehensive analysis on a case study related to a Swedish-based company’s Human Resource Manager, entrusted to craft up strategies to minimize failure rate of expatriation. This case study is specific towards the company’s direction to expand to China by setting up operations in the country. This analysis outlines challenges and strategies in the human resource management, focusing on expatriate management cycle, process of candidates’ recruitment, training and learning development, managing expatriates family in the host country and acclimatising in the host country’s culture. This analysis is critical as it affects the company’s nature of business, its revenue and profits, and its business models...

Words: 742 - Pages: 3

Premium Essay

Hsbc

...around the world. Thomas Sutherland, the founder of HSBC, realized a demand for local banking facilities in Hongkong and on the China coast. Hence, the Hongkong and Shanghai Banking Corporation was founded in 1865 and the first bank opened in Hong Kong in March 1865 and at the same year, the first branch opened in Shanghai. Nowadays, the business of HSBC is distributed in more than 100 countries and regions and HSBC has over 100 million customers all over the world. Chinese market is quite important and special for HSBC and Shanghai was chose by HSBC and opened the first branch in 1865. Although the founder was a Scot, HSBC still headquartered in Hong Kong until 1980s. In early stage, HSBC hoped to become the local bank of China and gave services to the clients all over the world but now, HSBC preferred to be a global bank to cater to Chinese. Therefore, the China strategy is crucial for HSBC. The China strategy of HSBC can be divided into three stages, which was before Oct, 1949, before China’s accession to the WTO and after China’s accession to the WTO. In the middle of the 19th century, more and more British merchants came to China to do business but Qing government lacked banks or financing institution. Mr. Sutherland recognized the demand and founded HSBC to give services to the Brutish merchants and Chinese merchants. HSBC considered that China was a potential market and few competitors had already entered Chinese market. Furthermore, Qing government signed several treaties...

Words: 1302 - Pages: 6