Free Essay

Essays

In:

Submitted By janithamaharaj
Words 9686
Pages 39
Vol. 4, 2010-22 | August 5, 2010 | http://dx.doi.org/10.5018/economics-ejournal.ja.2010-22

Housing Wealth Isn’t Wealth
Willem H. Buiter
Citigroup, London Abstract A fall in house prices due to a change in fundamental value redistributes wealth from those long housing (for whom the fundamental value of the house they own exceeds the present discounted value of their planned future consumption of housing services) to those short housing. In a closed economy representative agent model (the special case when the birth rate is zero, of the Yaari-Blanchard OLG model used in the paper), there is no pure wealth effect on consumption from a change in house prices if this represents a change in their fundamental value. When the birth rate is positive, higher fundamental house prices driven by the housing demand of future generations will boost current consumption. There is a pure wealth effect on consumption from a change in house prices even in the representative agent model, if this reflects a change in the speculative bubble component of house prices. Two other channels through which a fall in house prices can affect aggregate consumption are (1) redistribution effects if the marginal propensity to spend out of wealth differs between those long housing (the old, say) and those short housing (the young, say) and (2) collateral or credit effects due to the collateralisability of housing wealth and the non-collateralisability of human wealth. A decline in house prices reduces the scope for mortgage equity withdrawal. For given sequences of future after-tax labour income and interest rates, a fall in house prices will then depress consumption in the short run while boosting it in the long run. JEL E2, E3, E5, E6, G1 Keywords Wealth effect; house prices; speculative bubbles Correspondence Willem H. Buiter, CBE, FBA, Chief Economist, Citigroup, Citigroup Centre, Canada Square, Canary Wharf, London E14 5LB, UK; E-mail: willembuiter@btinternet.com, Web Page: http://www.nber.org/~wbuiter/

Citation Willem H. Buiter (2010). Housing Wealth Isn’t Wealth. Economics: The Open-Access, Open-Assessment E-Journal, Vol. 4, 2010-22. doi:10.5018/economics-ejournal.ja.2010-22. http://dx.doi.org/10.5018/economics-ejournal.ja.2010-22 © Author(s) 2010. Licensed under a Creative Commons License - Attribution-NonCommercial 2.0 Germany

1

Introduction

The bold statement “Housing wealth isn’t wealth” was put to me over a decade ago by Mervyn King, now Governor of the Bank of England, then Chief Economist of the Bank of England. Like most bold statements, the assertion is not quite correct; the correct statement is that, in a representative agent model, a decline in house prices does create a negative wealth effect on aggregate consumption demand. On average, consumers are neither worse off nor better off. The argument is elementary and applies to coconuts as well as to houses. When does a fall in the price of coconuts make you worse off? Answer: when you are a net exporter of coconuts, that is, when your endowment of coconuts exceeds your consumption of coconuts. A net importer of coconuts is better off when the price of coconuts falls. Someone who is just self-sufficient in coconuts is neither worse off nor better off. As regards wealth effects, houses are like durable coconuts, or indeed like any consumer durable. The fundamental value of a house is the present discounted value of its current and future rentals, actual or (in the case of owner-occupiers) imputed. Anyone who is ‘long’ housing, that is, anyone for whom the value of their home exceeds the present discounted value of the housing services they plan to consume over their remaining lifetime will be made worse off by a decline in house prices. Anyone ‘short’ housing will be better off. So the young and all those planning to trade up in the housing market are made better off by a decline in house prices. The old and all those planning to trade down in the housing market will be worse off. Another way to put this is that landlords are worse off as a result of a decline in house prices, while current and future tenants are better off. On average, the inhabitants of a country own the houses they live in; on average, every tenant is his/her own landlord and vice versa. So in a representative agent model, there is no net housing wealth effect. You need a model with heterogeneous agents in which a change in house prices causes redistribution between agents with different marginal propensities to spend in order to get an aggregate consumption effect from a change in house prices. Most econometric or calibrated numerical models I am familiar with treat housing wealth just like the value of stocks and shares as a determinant of household consumption. Their designers appear to forget that households consume

www.economics-ejournal.org

1

housing services (for which they pay or impute rent) but not stock or bond services. A prominent example is the FRB/US model (see Brayton and Tinsley, eds. (1996), Brayton, Levin, Tryon, and Williams (1997), and Brayton, Mauskopf, Reifschneider, Tinsley and Williams (1997)). It is used frequently by participants in the debate on the implication of developments in the US housing market for US consumer demand. A recent example is Frederic S. Mishkin’s (2008) paper “Housing and the Monetary Transmission Mechanism”. The FRB/US model apriori constrains the wealth effects of housing wealth and other financial wealth to be the same. The long-run marginal propensity to consume out of non-human wealth (including housing wealth) is 0.038, that is, 3.8 percent. In several simulations, Mishkin increases the value of the long-run marginal propensity to consume out of housing wealth to 0.076, that is, 7.6 percent, while keeping the long-run marginal propensity to consume out of non-housing financial wealth at 0.038. The argument for an effect of a change in house prices on consumption other than the pure wealth effect, is that housing wealth is collateralisable. Householdsconsumers can borrow against the equity in their homes and use this to finance consumption. If they are credit-constrained, a boost to housing wealth would relax the credit constraint and temporarily boost consumption spending. Of course, the increased debt will have to be serviced, and eventually consumption will have to be below the level it would have been at in the absence of the mortgage equity withdrawal (MEW). So even if the impact effect or short-run effect on consumption of a change in house prices can be represented adequately through a higher marginal propensity to consume out of collateralisable housing wealth than out of non-collateralisable (human) wealth, in the long run, the lower net financial assets of the household will reduce consumption compared to what it would have been if the change in wealth had been due to a change in non-collateralisable wealth. Ben Bernanke (2007), Donald Kohn (2006), Fredric Mishkin (2008), Randall Kroszner (2005, 2008) and Charles Plosser (2007) all have made statements to the effect that the credit effect, collateral effect or MEW effect of a change in house prices is on top of, that is, in addition to, the ‘normal’ wealth effect.1 The _________________________
1 Bernanke (2007): “If the financial accelerator hypothesis is correct, changes in home values may affect household borrowing and spending by somewhat more than suggested by the conventional

www.economics-ejournal.org

2

message of this paper is that the in the simplest benchmark model (the representative agent model) there is no aggregate wealth effect from a change in house prices (it is purely redistributive), and even if there were a redistributional effect from changes in house prices, this would not impact aggregate consumption because winners and losers have the same marginal propensities to consume. Richer OLG models suggest the possibility of either positive or negative net effects on aggregate consumption from a change in house prices when the young are both short housing and liquidity- or collateral-constrained. By overestimating _________________________ wealth effect because changes in homeowners' net worth also affect their external finance premiums and thus their costs of credit.” Kohn (2006): “Between the beginning of 2001 and the end of 2005, the constant-quality price index for new homes rose 30 percent and the purchase-only price index of existing homes published by the Office of Federal Housing Enterprise Oversight (OFHEO) increased 50 percent. These increases boosted the net worth of the household sector, which further fueled (sic) the growth of consumer spending directly through the traditional "wealth effect" and possibly through the increased availability of relatively inexpensive credit secured by the capital gains on homes.” Kroszner (2005): “As some of the “froth” comes off of the housing market – thereby reducing the positive “wealth effect” of the strength in the housing sector -- and people fully adjust to higher energy prices, I see the growth in real consumer spending inching down to roughly 3 percent next year.” Kroszner (2008), “ falling home prices can have local and national consequences because of the erosion of both property tax revenue and the support for consumer spending that is provided by household wealth.” Mishkin (2008, p.363): “By raising or lowering short-term interest rates, monetary policy affects the housing market, and in turn the overall economy, directly and indirectly through at least six channels: through the direct effects of interest rates on (1) the user cost of capital, (2) expectations of future house-price movements, and (3) housing supply; and indirectly through (4) standard wealth effects from house prices, (5) balance sheet, credit-channel effects on consumer spending, and (6) balance sheet, credit channel effects on housing demand.” Mishkin (2008a, p. 378): “Although FRB/US does not include all the transmission mechanisms outlined above, it does incorporate direct interest rate effects on housing activity through the user cost of capital and through wealth (and possibly credit-channel) effects from house prices, where the effects of housing and financial wealth are constrained to be identical.” Plossser (2007): “ changes in both home prices and stock prices influence household wealth and therefore impact consumer spending and aggregate demand.” Plosser (2007):“To the extent that reductions in housing wealth do occur because of a decline in house prices, the negative wealth effect may largely be offset for many households by higher stock market valuations. “

www.economics-ejournal.org

3

the effect on consumer demand of a change in house prices, the monetary authority may be led to move its rates too aggressively. The failure to treat a change in fundamental house prices as a distributional and credit constraint/collateral issue for consumers and, through Tobin’s q, as a residential investment issue rather than as the source of a net aggregate wealth effect continues to plague even the most recent literature. An example is an NBER working paper by Casey Mulligan and Luke Threinen, “Market Responses to the Panic of 2008”, that appeared in October 2008.2 In their paper, Mulligan and Threinen “... model the panic of 2008 as part of the wealth and substitution effects deriving from a housing price crash that began in 2006. The dissipation of the wealth effect stimulates a reorganization of the banking industry and increases in employment, GDP, and unemployment.” (Mulligan and Threinen (2008)). Casey and Mulligan also don’t take the ‘escape route’ stressed in the present paper, that there is a pure wealth effect from a change in house prices that reflects a speculative bubble instead of a change in economic fundamentals (the present discounted value of future rentals): “The expected capital losses in the long run are not necessarily reflective of a “bubble,” but may rather have served to ration housing.” (Mulligan and Threinen (2008)). The insight that housing wealth isn’t wealth has the status of a folk theorem in macro consumer demand theory and empirics (see e.g. Buchanan and Fiotakis (2004), Edelstein and Lum (2004), Case, Quigley, and Shiller (2005) and Carroll, Otsuka, and Slacalek (2006)). A rigorous statement and formal model of the proposition is not, as far as I know, available. The representative agent special case of the model presented in this paper can be found in the Appendix to Buiter (2008a). The paper does not develop a complete general equilibrium model, although it would be trivial to add a simple version of the missing components, especially if I am permitted the luxury of a small open economy with perfect international mobility of financial capital. To establish the conditions under which there is no pure wealth effect on consumption from a change in the fundamental value of a unit of housing capital, or the proposition that a housing bubble does have a pure wealth effect, all that is required is the aggregate consumption function and a _________________________
2 An earlier version of the present paper (Buiter (2008b) had appeared in the NBER Working Paper series in July 2008.

www.economics-ejournal.org

4

subset of the economy-wide equilibrium conditions – in particular the housing autarky assumption that the housing stock is owned only by domestic consumers. The determination of the equilibrium real wage, the real interest rate, the production of non-housing consumption goods and the relative price of housing services and other consumption goods is irrelevant from the point of view of establishing the three main propositions of the paper.

2
2.1

The Model
Individual Household Behaviour

For sake of brevity, I consider an integrated household-consumer-home ownerconstruction firm owner and worker, rather than the separate household and business entities. The structure of preferences is irrelevant to the result, as long utility is increasing in consumption of housing services and consumption of nonhousing goods and services. What matters for the strong proposition that a change in house prices does not change aggregate consumption is (1) the assumption of housing autarky for the economy under consideration and (2) the absence of distributional effects from house price changes. Specifically, the absence of lifecycle-related effects of house price changes on the demand for housing services is central. Housing autarky means that there are no foreign owners of domestic housing. As regards age-related variations in the demand for housing services, in the YaariBlanchard OLG model used in what follows (for expositional simplicity), every surviving household has the same remaining life expectancy, regardless of the age of the household (see Yaari (1965), Blanchard (1985) and Buiter (1988)). In addition, the current housing stock and all future contributions to the flow of rental income from housing are fully owned by those currently alive. This is in contrast to human capital, where the future wages earned (net of taxes on labour income paid) by the unborn are not owned by any private agent currently alive today. This is a consequence of the implicit assumption of the absence of hereditary slavery. When combined with the assumption of no (operative) intergenerational gift and bequest motive, a positive birth rate generates absence of debt neutrality in the Yaari-Blanchard OLG model as in the Allais-Samuelson OLG model.

www.economics-ejournal.org

5

A positive birth rate also introduces the only economically significant form of household heterogeneity into possessed by the Yaari-Blanchard model: that between those currently alive and the unborn (future generations). The unborn don’t own any of the non-human assets currently in existence, including the housing stock. Forward-looking asset markets will, however, anticipate the consumption demand, including the demand for housing services of future generations. As regards those generations currently alive (the current generation plus the survivors from all past generations) there is no heterogeneity due to age, accumulated financial wealth or human capital. The usual life-cycle property that those with a shorter remaining life-span will have a larger marginal propensity to consume out of a windfall, is absent because life expectancy is the same, regardless of age: the marginal propensity to consume out of comprehensive wealth (financial assets and human capital) is independent of age. Once born, each household has a constant, age-independent instantaneous probability of dying, μ ≥ 0 . The birth rate, β ≥ 0 , is constant. With β = 0 the model reduces to the representative agent model, regardless of whether μ is positive or zero. At time t a surviving household born at time v ≤ t earns an exogenous wage income w(t, v) ≥ 0 (for simplicity, each household’s labour supply is assumed inelastic and scaled to unity), pays lump-sum taxes τ (t , v) , consumes an amount of non-housing goods and services z (t , v) ≥ 0 , and an amount of housing services ρ (t , v) ≥ 0 . The rest of its income is either saved in the form of real financial assets earning the instantaneous risk-free real interest rate r (t ) plus a competitive annuity rate (to be discussed) or spent on acquiring housing equity at a price p k (t ) for an ownership claim to one unit of installed physical housing capital. Here k (t , v) is the number of housing shares owned by generation v at time t. A unit of real housing capital earns real rental income or dividend x(t ) . Real financial wealth held by the household, excluding the value of the stock of housing it owns, is denoted f(t,v). Non-housing goods and services are the numéraire. The price of a unit of housing services in terms of non-housing goods and services is p(t ) . There are efficient competitive annuities markets. Surviving households earn an annuity premium rate r l on their non-human wealth (including housing wealth). When a household dies, all its non-human wealth (which can be negative)

www.economics-ejournal.org

6

accrues to the life-insurance company that has sold them the annuity. There is free l entry into the annuities market; therefore r = μ . A utility-maximising competitive representative household born at time v ≤ t and having survived until time t , maximizes the time-additive objective function in (1) subject to the instantaneous budget identity (2) and the solvency constraint (3). The expectation operator conditional on information at time t is Et , θ is the subjective rate of pure time preference and σ is the reciprocal of the intertemporal substitution elasticity.

U (t , v) = Et ∫ e −θ ( s −t )u ( ρ ( s, v), z ( s, v) ) ds, θ > 0 t ∞

u(ρ , z) =

1−σ 1 ( ρη z1−η ) ; 0 < η < 1; σ > 0, σ ≠ 1 1−σ = ln ( ρ η z1−η ) ; σ = 1

(1)

df (t , v) dk (t , v) + p k (t ) = ( r (t ) + μ ) f (t , v) + ( x(t ) + μ p k (t ) ) k (t , v) dt dt + w(t , v) − τ (t , v) − z (t , v) − p(t ) ρ (t , v)
( r ( u ) + μ ) du lim e ∫t ( f ( s, v ) + p k ( s ) k ( s, v ) ) ≥ 0
− s →∞ s (2)

(3)

We assume that the (expected) rates of return on housing equity and on other financial assets are the same, so

& x pk r= k + k p p

(4)

It follows that the instantaneous budget identity can be rewritten as:

www.economics-ejournal.org

7

d ( f (t , v) + p k (t )k (t, v) ) = ( r (t ) + μ ) ( f (t , v) + p k (t )k (t, v) ) dt + w(t , v) − τ (t , v) − z (t , v) − p (t ) ρ (t , v)

(5)

The only uncertainty in the model is uncertain life expectancy, if the probability of death μ is positive. The objective functional U(t,v) in (1) can therefore be rewritten as

U (t , v) = ∫ e− (θ + μ )( s −t )u ( ρ ( s, v), z ( s, v) ) ds t ∞

(6)

Let the present discounted value of current and future after-tax labour income or human capital of a household of generation v at time t ≥ v be denoted h(t,v):
− ( r ( u ) + μ ) du h(t , v ) = ∫ e ∫t ( w( s, v) − τ ( s, v) ) ds t ∞ s (7)

The solvency constraint (3), the instantaneous budget identity (2) and (7) permit us to write the intertemporal budget constraint of the household as follows:
− ( r ( u ) + μ ) du f (t , v ) + p k (t )k (t , v) + h(t , v ) ≥ ∫ e ∫t [ z ( s, v) + p( s) ρ ( s, v)] ds t ∞ s (8)

The first-order conditions for housing and non-housing consumption imply that, for all s ≥ t :

ρ ( s) ⎛ η ⎞ −1 =⎜ ⎟ p( s ) z ( s) ⎝ 1 − η ⎠ z ( s, v) = z (t , v)e

(9)
⎛ σ −1 ⎞ ⎟ ⎝ σ ⎠

∫t ⎜ ⎝

s ⎛ r ( u ) −θ

σ

⎞ ⎟ du ⎠

⎛ p( s) ⎞ ⎜ ⎟ ⎝ p (t ) ⎠

η⎜

(10)

www.economics-ejournal.org

8

⎛ ⎞ η λ (t , v) = (1 − η ) ⎜ ⎜ (1 − η ) p(t ) ⎟ ⎟ ⎝ ⎠ & λ = − ( r + μ )λ

η (1−σ )

z (t , v) −σ

(11)

(12)

Here λ (t , v) is the co-state variable of real private non-human wealth at time t for a household born at time v (measured in units of utility), whose equation of motion is given in (2) or (5), that is, the present value shadow price for a household of generation v of private financial wealth and housing wealth. From equations (8) to (12), we can obtain the following individual decision rules for consumption or consumption functions. Total consumption of both housing services and non-housing goods and services is denoted c = p ρ + z :

z (t , v) = (1 − η )c(t )

(13) (14)

ρ (t , v) =

η p(t )

c(t )

c(t , v) = ξ (t ) ⎡ f (t , v) + p k (t )k (t , v) + h(t , v) ⎤ ⎣ ⎦

(15)

where ξ (t ) , the marginal propensity to consume out of comprehensive wealth, is independent of generation-specific parameters and variables.
⎛ σ −1 ⎞ η⎜ ⎡ ∞ − s ⎡⎛ σ −1 ⎞ r (u ) + μ + θ ⎤ du ⎤ ⎟ ⎝ σ ⎠ ∫t ⎢⎜ σ ⎟ σ ⎥ ⎛ p(s) ⎞ ⎢ e ⎣⎝ ⎠ ⎥ ⎦ ds ξ (t ) = ∫ ⎜ ⎟ ⎢ ⎥ ⎝ p (t ) ⎠ t ⎢ ⎥ ⎣ ⎦ −1

(16)

Equations (5), (7), (8) (holding with equality) and (15) imply:

& ⎞ dc(t , v) ⎛ ξ (t ) = ⎜ r (t ) + μ + − ξ (t ) ⎟ c(t , v) dt ξ (t ) ⎝ ⎠ www.economics-ejournal.org (17)

9

For the logarithmic instantaneous felicity function σ = 1 , this simplifies to

ξ (t ) = ξ = θ + μ and the familiar consumption Euler equation

(18)

dc(t , v) = ( r (t ) − θ ) c(t , v) dt

(19)

2.2

Aggregation

For any individual household flow or stock variable y(t , v) we define the population aggregate Y (t ) as follows: for β > 0 ,

Y (t ) =

−∞

∫ y(t, v)S (t , v)dv

t

(20)

where S (t , v) is the number of households born at time v that are still alive at time t. Let O(t ) > 0 be the size of the population (the size of the labour force or the number of households) at time t.

S (t , v) = β O(v)e− μ (t −v ) and (21)

O(v) = O(0)e( β − μ ) v
Without loss of generality let O(0) = 1 . So

(22)

S (t , v) = β e− μt + β v and if β > 0

(23)

www.economics-ejournal.org

10

Y (t ) = β e

− μt

−∞

∫ y(t, v)e

t

βv

dv

(24)

We cover the case of a zero birth rate as follows:

When β = 0, y (t , v) = y (t ) and Y (t ) = e − μt y (t )

(25)

I also assume that each consumer is born just with his endowment of human wealth – there are no intergenerational gifts and bequests – and therefore:

f (t , t ) + p k (t )k (t , t ) = 0

(26)

Also, for simplicity, assume that everyone alive earns the same wage and pays the same taxes, so

w(t , v) = w(t ) τ (t , v) = τ (t )

(27)

It follows that each surviving member of every generation has the same human wealth:

h(t , v) = h(t )

(28)

The aggregate consumption function is given by:

C (t ) = ξ (t ) ⎡ F (t ) + p k (t ) K (t ) + H (t ) ⎤ ⎣ ⎦

(29) (30) (31)

Z (t ) = (1 − η )C (t )
R (t ) =

η p(t )

C (t )

www.economics-ejournal.org

11

With

d ( F (t ) + p k (t ) K (t ) ) = r (t ) ( F (t ) + p k (t ) K (t ) ) + W (t ) − T (t ) − C (t ) (32) dt

& H (t ) = [r (t ) + β ]H (t ) − W (t ) + T (t )
If follows that the aggregate consumption ‘Euler equation’ is given by:

(33)

& ξ⎞ & ⎛ C = ⎜ r + β − ξ + ⎟ C − βξ ( F + p k K ) ξ⎠ ⎝

(34)

With the logarithmic utility function, σ = 1 , the aggregate consumption Euler equation (35) simplifies to:

& C = ( r + β − μ − θ ) C − β (θ + μ ) ( F + p k K )

(36)

We also have the aggregate intertemporal budget constraint of the private sector. This can, using (8), be written as:

F (t ) + p (t ) K (t ) + ∫ k ∞

t

− r ( u ) du r ( u ) du e ∫t C ( s )ds (37) (W (s) − T ( s) ) ds = ∫ e ∫t −

s



s

t

Note that, from (33), the human capital of those currently alive is given by:
( r ( u ) + β ) du H (t ) = ∫ e ∫t (W ( s) − T ( s) ) ds
− ∞ s (38)

t

The presence of the birth rate as an augmentation factor for the discount rate applied to future aggregate after-tax labour income in (38) is due to the assumption, built into the model, that the human wealth of future generations is

www.economics-ejournal.org

12

not owned by anyone currently alive. This assumption about property rights (effectively the absence of hereditary slavery and hereditary indentured labour), together with the assumption that there are no operative intergenerational gift and bequest motives, makes for the absence of debt neutrality that is a property of all OLG models that make the same two key assumptions.

2.3

The Accumulation of Housing Capital

There is a continuum of competitive home construction firms on the unit circle that maximize profits by accumulating housing capital and letting it out. Each firm maximises the following objective function: r ( u ) du V (t ) = ∫ e ∫t ( p( s)α ( s) K ( s) − A( s) ) ds − t∞ ∞ s (39)

α > 0; K ≥ 0 subject to the constraint that the resource cost of housing capital formation is quadratic in the investment rate,

A(t ) = I (t ) +

γ ( I (t ) − (δ + n) K (t ) )
2 K (t )

2

(40)

and the capital stock adjustment identity

& K = I −δ K

(41)

Here γ ≥ 0 measures the severity of the housing capital adjustment costs, δ ≥ 0 is the constant proportional deprecation rate of the stock of housing capital and n is the natural real growth rate of the economy (the growth rate of the labour force in efficiency units). When γ → ∞ we have the case of unaugmentable capital. When γ → ∞ and δ = 0 we have the case of housing as ‘land’ in the sense of the unaugmentable and indestructible contribution of nature. When γ is positive but finite, the housing stock is fixed in the short run but augmentable in the long run. Note that the decision rule of the construction company would not change if instead of maximising its fundamental value, V , it maximised its market www.economics-ejournal.org 13

value, p k K = V + bK , where b is the bubble component in the market value of a unit of installed capital, as long as the bubble component is independent of the actions of the firm (see below). Unlike its owners, this enterprise does not die. Its discount rate is therefore the risk-free real interest rate, without the annuity premium added (see Buiter (1989)). The production function for housing services is assumed to be linear in the capital stock and is given by α ( s ) K ( s ) . The first-order conditions for an optimum imply that optimal investment is governed by equations (42) and (43):

⎛ ⎞ 1 I = ⎜ δ + n + ( q(t ) − 1) ⎟ K (t ) γ ⎝ ⎠
2 s ∫t ( (r(u)+δ ))du ⎡ p(s)α(s) +γ (δ + n)⎛ I (s) −(δ + n) ⎞ + γ ⎛ I (s) − (δ + n)⎞ ⎤ ds q(t) = ∫ e ⎢ ⎜ ⎟ ⎜ ⎟⎥ ⎢ ⎝ K(s) ⎠ 2 ⎝ K(s) ⎠⎥ t ⎣ ⎦ ∞ −

(42)

(43)

or ⎛ I ⎞ γ⎛ I ⎞ pα + γ (δ + n) ⎜ − (δ + n) ⎟ + ⎜ − (δ + n) ⎟ & q ⎝K ⎠ 2⎝K ⎠ = r +δ + q q
2

(44)

The shadow price of the capital stock (the current value co-state variable of

K (t ) in (41), is Tobin’s ‘marginal q’. The market value of the equity held in the construction companies is also given by (39). Because the investing firm is assumed to be a price taker, and because the production function of housing services is linear in the capital stock and the investment adjustment cost function is linear homogeneous in the investment rate and the capital stock, Tobin’s marginal q also equals Tobin’s average q, which is the fundamental value of a unit of installed housing capital. This result, first established by Hayashi (1982), implies that

V (t ) = q(t ) K (t )

(45)

www.economics-ejournal.org

14

The intuition is, as stated in Hayashi (1982), that average Tobin’s q (and marginal Tobin’s q) are independent of the initial capital stock if the production and installation functions are linear homogeneous and if the firm is a price-taker. I write the market value of a unit of installed housing capital as

pk = q + b

(46)

The first term on the RHS of (46) is the fundamental value of a unit of k installed housing, defined by (43) and (42), that is, its shadow price. When p is interpreted not as a shadow price in a dynamic optimisation problem, where the boundary conditions for optimality ensure that the shadow price supports the optimum (that is, b (t ) = 0 ), but rather as an asset market price set in a market where there is no invisible hand to impose the transversality condition, there can also be a bubble term b(t) in (46). If the bubble is (myopically) rational, then

& b = (r + δ )b

(47)

The competitive rental rate for housing services, x , earned by households as dividends from their ownership of housing capital (see equation (2)) is given by

⎛ I ⎞ γ⎛ I ⎞ x = pα + γ (δ + n) ⎜ − (δ + n) ⎟ + ⎜ − (δ + n) ⎟ − δ p k . ⎝K ⎠ 2⎝K ⎠
2

(48)

2.4

Equilibrium in the Housing Market or Housing Autarky
We now impose economy-wide equilibrium in the housing market:

R(s) = α (s) K (s), s ≥ t
It follows from (49), (46), (45), (39) and (32), that

(49)

www.economics-ejournal.org

15



− r ( u ) du ( r ( u ) + β ) du Z ( s )e ∫t ds = F (t ) + b(t ) K (t ) − Λ (t ) + ∫ (W ( s ) − T ( s ) ) e ∫t ds (50) ∫ − t t

s



s

Here Λ (t ) , the present discounted value of all future costs of housing investment, is given by:
− r ( u ) du Λ (t ) = ∫ e ∫t A( s )ds t ∞ s = βe

− μt

−∞ t ∞ t ∫

t ∞

( r ( u ) + μ ) du e ∫t a( s, v)e β v dsdv if β > 0 ∫ − s s

(51)

− ( r ( u ) + μ ) du = e − μt ∫ e ∫ a( s, v)ds if β = 0 t

Once we impose the housing market equilibrium or housing autarky condition, given by the first equality in (49), we can rewrite the three consumption functions in the following manner:

where

⎛ 1 ⎞ C =⎜ ⎟ ξ ( F + bK − Λ + Ω + H ) ⎝ 1 −η ⎠ Z = (1 − η )C pR = η C = α K

(52)

& F = rF + W − T − (1 − η )C − A
− [ r ( u ) + β ]du Ω(t ) = η ∫ (W ( s ) − T ( s ) )e ∫t ( eβ ( s −t ) − 1) ds t ∞ s (53)

or
− r ( u ) du & Ω(t ) = r (t )Ω(t ) − βη ∫ e ∫t (W ( s) − T ( s) )ds t ∞ s (54)

www.economics-ejournal.org

16

d (bK ) = rbK dt

(55)

Equation (55) constrains the bubble and/or the housing investment process. If the bubble is rational, that is, it satisfies the homogeneous equation of the equation of motion driving the fundamental valuation q , as given by equation (47), it follows that the following relationship has to hold:

& b(δ K + K ) = 0

(56)

This implies that either there is no rational bubble, b(t ) = 0 or gross housing & investment is zero, I (t ) = 0 , and K = −δ K . Irrational bubbles could, of course, exist even if (56) does not hold.

3

The Pure Wealth Effect of House Price Changes on Consumption

The key properties of the model can be inferred from the consumption functions summarised in equations (52) to (56). First, when the birth rate, β , is zero, the term Ω(t ) in equation (52) (and defined in equation (54)), housing variables affect aggregate consumption, consumption of housing services and consumption of non-housing goods and services only through the cost of future investment, Λ , and through the bubble

term in the house price equation, bK . This is the pure case of ‘everyone always owns the house they live in’. No-one is long or short housing. Second, when the birth rate is positive, Ω(t ) becomes positive s ∞ − [ r ( u ) + β ]du > 0 ). The term Ω(t ) represents (assuming that ∫ (W ( s ) − T ( s ) )e ∫t the present discounted value of the housing services demanded by future generations (generations yet to be born). In a rational expectations model, this demand from future generations is reflected in today’s fundamental price. t www.economics-ejournal.org

17

The OLG structure of the model, which is present when β > 0 , even though all generations currently alive have identical life expectancies μ −1 because of the assumption of an age-independent probability of death, therefore invalidates the absence of wealth effects from a change in fundamental house prices found in the representative agent version of the model. All generations currently alive are ‘long housing’, because of the arrival of future generations. The present discounted value of the housing services current generations will consume is less than the present discounted value of current and future housing services demanded by both current and future generations. It is this total current and future demand for housing services, by those currently alive and by those yet to be born, that is reflected in the fundamental house price, q. It is true that the Yaari-Blanchard version of the OLG model does not generate effects on aggregate consumption (C, Z and R) from changes in fundamental house prices through a redistribution of wealth or income among those currently alive. Age, that is, date of birth, and the distinction between those born and still alive and those not yet born, are the only sources of consumer heterogeneity in the YaariBlanchard model. But age in the Yaari-Blanchard model does not affect the expected remaining lifetime or the marginal propensity to consume out of wealth. The Yaari-Blanchard model does not have life-cycle effects. In the AllaisSamuelson OLG model, where households have a fixed finite lifespan, there will in general be age-specific propensities to consume, and possibly also age-specific preferences over housing and non-housing consumption. The only household heterogeneity that matters for aggregate consumption in the Yaari-Blanchard model is that between those born and still alive on the one hand and the unborn – future generations – on the other hand. The present discounted value of the real resource cost of future investment in housing Λ (t ) , given in equation (51) may of course be affected by the same factors that cause a change in the value of the existing housing stock, but that is a quite separate matter from a change in the fundamental value of the existing housing stock having a pure wealth effect on consumption. This effect of house prices on investment in housing is recognized through the housing investment function, given in equation (42), which makes gross housing investment an increasing function of Tobin’s q. So Λ (t ) is a function not of the current price of housing capital but of the sequence of future (expected) prices of housing capital. I summarise this discussion as three Propositions:

www.economics-ejournal.org

18

Proposition 1: In the representative agent model (the Yaari-Blanchard OLG model with a zero birth rate), a change in the fundamental value of a unit of installed housing, q , has no wealth effect on aggregate consumption demand, the demand for housing services or the consumption demand for non-housing goods and services. Proposition 2: In the representative agent model (the Yaari-Blanchard OLG model with β = 0 ), a change in the bubble component of the price of a unit of installed housing, b, is associated with a wealth effect on aggregate consumption demand, on the demand for housing services and on the consumption demand for non-housing goods and services. This bubble can only be a rational bubble if gross investment in housing equals zero. Proposition 3: In the OLG version of the Yaari Blanchard model ( β > 0 ) higher fundamental house prices have a positive aggregate wealth effect and a positive effect on aggregate consumption demand, on the demand for housing services and on the consumption demand for non-housing goods and services if the higher fundamental house prices reflect (expected) demand for housing services by future generations.

3.1

Why the Common Error?

How did so many of students of consumption behaviour and wealth effects miss the obvious point of Proposition 1, despite the frequent use of the representative agent framework? The most likely reason is that the standard consumption function is the decision rule of an individual, or an aggregation of such individual decision rules. When studying consumption behaviour, equilibrium conditions are not normally imposed on these decision rules. On the whole this is good practice – the fact that prices and economy-wide aggregate quantities taken as parametric by individuals are in fact endogenously determined by the interaction of these price-taking economic agents, does not mean that it is not helpful to treat individual decision rules and equilibrium conditions conceptually distinct. But when we deal with general equilibrium responses to policies or shocks, the equilibrium conditions do

www.economics-ejournal.org

19

of course have to be imposed. This was obviously not done in such papers as Mishkin (2008) or Mulligan and Threinen (2008). Without imposing the ‘housing autarky’ assumption (49) and using equations (39), (45) and (46), total consumption, non-housing consumption and housing consumption can, respectively, be written as in equations (29), (30) and (31) respectively, that is, as functions of total non-human wealth, F + p k K and human wealth, H , with the equations of motion for non-human wealth and human wealth given by (32) and (33) respectively. In this representation of the consumption function, non-housing financial wealth, F and housing wealth p k K enter with the same marginal propensities to spend, ξ . The equation C = ξ F + p k K + H is the standard ‘permanent income’ consumption function where aggregate consumption is proportional to the sum of aggregate non-human and human wealth, and where aggregate non-human wealth includes the value of the housing stock on the same terms as other non-human wealth. However, when we impose the housing autarky assumption, the same aggregate consumption function can be written as

(

)

⎛ 1 ⎞ C =⎜ ⎟ ξ ( F + bK − Λ + H + Ω ) and the absence of a pure wealth effect ⎝ 1 −η ⎠ of fundamental housing wealth on aggregate consumption demand is confirmed when β = 0 because this implies Ω = 0 . When housing is pure ‘land’, that is non-augmentable and indestructible, then Λ = 0 and the consumption function simplifies to

⎛ 1 ⎞ C =⎜ ⎟ ξ ( F + bK + H + Ω ) . ⎝ 1 −η ⎠

This makes it even clearer that in the model under consideration, in the representative agent special case, when β = Ω = 0 , a change in housing wealth affects consumption if and only if it is due to a change in the speculative bubble component of house prices.

www.economics-ejournal.org

20

3.2
3.2.1

Qualifications of the Housing Wealth Irrelevance Result
Wealth isn’t Well Being

At the risk of belabouring the obvious, Proposition 1 says that, in the representative agent version of the model, a change in the fundamental value of a unit of housing does not lead to any change in consumption demand. However, since R (t ) = α (t ) K (t ) , a larger physical stock of housing capital increases equilibrium consumption of housing services and raises utility - makes you better off. Wealth (the value of your endowments) bears no obvious relation to utility in any case, as wealth values the infra-marginal units of assets at the marginal contribution to lifetime utility of the last unit: in a world without scarcity, all endowments would be valued at zero and wealth would be zero, but utility would be maximal. 3.2.2 Changes in Housing Wealth due to a Housing Bubble

Proposition 2 points out that when the change in the house price is due to a bubble rather than to a change in fundamental value, that is, b (t ) ≠ 0 in equation (52), the change in house prices does represent a pure wealth effect. Even if the economy is autarkic in housing, the bubble-inclusive price of the house exceeds the value of the endowment of current and future housing services by the amount of the bubble. Whether the housing market in the US or elsewhere has been characterised by a speculative bubble between, say, 2000 and 2007 is a hotly debated issue (see e.g. Case and Shiller (2003) and Himmelberg, Mayer, and Sinai (2005)). In the simple model of the paper, the marginal propensity to spend out of a change in house prices due to a change in the bubble component of the house price is the same as the marginal propensity to consume out of any other component of non-human or human wealth. Note again that if there can be non-zero gross investment in housing, then there cannot be (myopically) rational speculative bubbles & (speculative bubbles that satisfy b = (r + δ )b , the homogenous equation of the equation of motion for the fundamental value of housing given in equation (44)). The empirical relevance of asset bubbles is a contested issue. Clearly, if the fundamentals driving house prices are stationary but house prices are nonstationary, a non-stationary bubble must be present. With finite length time series, however, it is very difficult to distinguish between the hypothesis that the www.economics-ejournal.org 21

fundamentals are stationary and there is a non-stationary bubble, and the alternative interpretation that the fundaments themselves are non-stationary, in which case no bubble is required to rationalise the non-stationarity of house prices. Recent studies by Laibson (2009) and Khandani et al. (2009) have stressed the contribution of rising house prices to consumer demand in the US, prior to the financial crisis that started in August 2007. Both these studies come down on the side of a possible role for speculative bubbles in driving US house prices. The issue remains, however, open. My definition of an asset price bubble is the standard one: an asset price bubble is any deviation between the market price of the asset and its fundamental price - the present discounted value of the future earnings stream to which the asset represents a claim. In practice, when the future earnings stream is uncertain and the appropriate (stochastic) discount factors cannot be readily and objectively observed, the distinction between the bubble component and the fundamental component of an asset price may not be as easily established as in my theoretical paper. With imperfect information and observation, the distinction between bubbles and misperceptions about the drivers of the fundamental valuation can become fuzzy. Indeed, as shown in an early (unpublished) paper by myself and Paolo Pesenti (Buiter and Pesenti (1990)) we should that rational speculative bubbles could even be functions of the same variables that drive the fundamental valuation. Finally, in a dynamic model in which the future behaviour of predetermined state variables, like the capital stock, can be influenced by today’s asset bubbles, the distinction between bubbles and fundamentals becomes further blurred, because today’s bubbles shape tomorrow’s fundamentals. This blurring of the distinction between bubbles and fundamentals is closely related to the notion of reflexivity developed by George Soros (2009), in which imperfect cognition and human action interact to produce the possibility of self-fulfilling prophesies. If faulty past and present expectations affect prices, if these prices influence present and future fundamentals and if these fundamentals in turn shape future expectations etc., then the economy can generate self-reinforcing patterns that do not in any meaningful sense tend towards equilibrium. A serious consideration of this important class of issues is clearly beyond the scope of this paper.

www.economics-ejournal.org

22

3.2.3

Distributional Effects, including Intergenerational Distribution

In more general OLG models, especially those with systematic variations in household size over the life cycle and with age-dependent propensities to consume (among other reasons because remaining (conditional) life expectancy is negatively related to age after some point), a decline in house prices redistributes wealth from those for whom the value of the housing stock they own is greater than the present discounted value of their future consumption of housing services to those for whom the value of the housing stock they own is less than the present discounted value of their future planned consumption of housing services. That is, a house price decline redistributes wealth from homeowners to tenants. In Proposition 3, I showed that even in the Yaari Blanchard model, redistribution through higher fundamental house prices from the unborn to those current alive will make those currently alive better off if the price increase reflects a higher future demand for housing services by those not yet born. It therefore raises aggregate consumption today. More generally, in a life-cycle model, the young, and all others planning to trade up in the housing market in the future will benefit from a current decline in house prices. The old and all others planning to trade down in the housing market in the future will lose when house prices fall. If the old have higher marginal propensities to consume out of wealth, as life-cycle principles would suggest, this means that a redistribution from the young to the old through higher house prices will boost aggregate consumption. If younger households, and especially younger households with rising age-earnings profiles (e.g. yuppies) are liquidityconstrained, the marginal propensity to consume of these yuppie households (who are short housing) could be larger than the marginal propensity to consume of the old. Higher house prices would then depress aggregate consumption through the redistribution channel. An Allais-Samuelson overlapping generations model is the natural vehicle for analyzing these intergenerational distributional effects. Other distributional effects can occur in open economies where the residents are tenants of non-resident landlords. 3.2.4 Credit or Collateral Effects

Finally, unlike human capital, housing wealth is collateralisable. This means that households can borrow using the value of the homes they own as security. www.economics-ejournal.org 23

Unsecured borrowing is more expensive than secured borrowing and may often not be possible on any terms. With free labour (no slavery or indentured labour), future labour earnings cannot be collateralised in a legally enforceable way and, unless reputational concerns are a powerful motivator, commitments to use future after-tax labour income to service unsecured debt may not be credible. Housing wealth therefore permits credit constraints to be relaxed (see e.g. Hurst and Stafford (2004), Iacoviello (2004) and Klyuev and Mills (2006)). A decline in house prices reduces the amount households can borrow (through ‘mortgage equity withdrawal’ or MEW). Assuming that human wealth is not collateralisable at all, a simple way to bring the housing collateral role into the model of this paper is to introduce the further constraint on individual household optimisation that net financial wealth cannot be negative, or that it is bounded from below:

− f (t , v) ≤ p k (t )k (t , v) + χ (t , v) χ ≥0 or, in the aggregate version:

(57)

− F (t ) ≤ p k (t ) K (t ) + X X ≥0

(58)

This constrains net debt not to exceed the value of the housing stock plus some (exogenous) maximum amount of unsecured borrowing, χ for the individual and X for the aggregate population. If this constraint is binding, a fall in house prices will clearly lower aggregate consumption in the short run, regardless of whether housing price changes have a pure wealth effect, that is, even in the representative agent version of the model. In the long run it will, for given sequences of wages and real interest rates, lower consumption, because of the greater household net indebtedness permitted by the relaxation of the borrowing constraint. In his simulation of the effect of a house price decline on consumption and investment demand in the US, Mishkin (2008) captured this credit effect of a change in house prices by assigning to housing wealth double the long-run marginal propensity to consume (0.076) he assigned to other financial wealth (0.038). There are two problems with this approach. www.economics-ejournal.org 24

First, because of the housing autarky argument, the model of this paper suggests that, without the collateral/credit effect, the marginal propensity to consume out of housing wealth would be zero, not 0.038 in the representative agent version of the model. The redistributive effects of an increase in house prices in OLG models do favour a net expansionary effect from higher house prices if the higher prices reflect future demand by generations as yet unborn. Redistribution from the young to the old caused by higher house prices will tend to boost aggregate consumption for life-cycle reasons but may depress it if the young are more likely to be liquidity-constrained than the old. It is therefore doubtful that the benchmark wealth effect of house price changes in the absence of collateral constraints should be assigned the value 0.038 used for all consumption in the FRB/US model. Second, Mishkin’s specification assumes that adding a binding collateral constraint always raises the marginal propensity to consume. However, the debt incurred through MEW has to be serviced. Although current consumption will be higher as a result of a household’s ability to relax a borrowing constraint by increasing the size of its mortgage, the present discounted value of future consumption will have to be lower. At market interest rates, the present discounted value of current and future consumption does not change as a result of a decline in house prices and the associated tightening of the credit constraint. There will of course be behavioural consequences because the shadow price of credit exceeds the market price of credit in the credit-constrained equilibrium. Modelling the credit effect of a house price decline properly would introduce it as a tightening of a borrowing constraint, but with the household’s intertemporal budget constraint satisfied both in the benchmark (with borrowing collateralised against property) and in the counterfactual simulation (with lower MEW). It may not be easy to determine reliably when the consumption-reducing effect of increased debt service will kick in and dominate the consumption-increasing effect of higher borrowing potential for a credit-constrained household, but to assume, as Mishkin does, that it never kicks in surely makes no sense.

www.economics-ejournal.org

25

4

Conclusion

The value of a house is its fundamental value – the present discounted value of its future actual or imputed rentals – plus a speculative bubble component, if any. A fall in house prices due to a change in its fundamental value redistributes wealth from those long housing (for whom the fundamental value of the house they own exceeds the present discounted value of their planned future consumption of housing services) to those short housing (from whom the fundamental value of the house they own is less than the present discounted value of their planned future consumption of housing services. In a closed economy representative agent model there is no pure wealth effect on consumption from a change in house prices if this represents a change in their fundamental value. In the Yaari-Blanchard model with a positive birth rate, higher fundamental house prices will boost aggregate consumption if the higher prices reflect higher expected future housing demand by generations yet to be born. There is a pure wealth effect on consumption from a change in house prices if this reflects a change in the bubble component of house prices, even in the representative agent special case. Two other channels, not considered in the formal model, through which a fall in house prices can affect aggregate consumption are (1) redistribution effects if the marginal propensity to spend out of wealth is different between those long housing (the old, say) and those short housing (the young, say) and (2) collateral or credit effects due to the collateralisability of housing wealth and the noncollateralisability of human wealth. A decline in house prices reduces the scope for mortgage equity withdrawal. For given sequences of future after-tax labour income and interest rates, this may depress consumption in the short run while boosting it in the long run.

www.economics-ejournal.org

26

References
Bernanke, Ben S. (2007). The Financial Accelerator and the Credit Channel. Speech given at The Credit Channel of Monetary Policy in the Twenty-first Century Conference, Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta, Atlanta, Georgia, June 15. Blanchard, O. (1985). Debt, Deficits and Finite Horizons. Journal of Political Economy, 93, April, pp. 237–247. Brayton, Flint, and P. Tinsley, eds. (1996). A Guide to FRB/US: A Macroeconomic Model of the United States. Finance and Economics Discussion Series Working Paper 1996-42 (Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, October). Brayton, Flint, A. Levin, R. Tryon, and J.C. Williams (1997). The Evolution of Macro Models at the Federal Reserve Board. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, vol. 47 (December), pp. 43–81. Brayton, Flint, Eileen Mauskopf, David Reifschneider, Peter Tinsley, and John Williams (1997). The Role of Expectations in the FRB/US Macroeconomic Model. Federal Reserve Bulletin, vol. 83 (April), 227–245. Buiter, Willem H. (1988). Death, Birth, Productivity Growth and Debt Neutrality. Economic Journal, 98, June, pp. 279–293. Buiter, Willem H. (1989), "Debt Neutrality, Professor Vickrey and Henry George's `Single Tax'," Economics Letters, 29, 1989, 43-47. Buiter, Willem H. and Paolo Pesenti (1990). Rational Speculative Bubbles in an Exchange Rate Target Zone. NBER Working Paper, No. 3467, October 1990, revised June 1993. Buiter, Willem H. (2008a). Lessons from the North Atlantic Financial Crisis. Paper prepared for presentation at the conference “The Role of Money Markets" jointly organised by Columbia Business School and the Federal Reserve Bank of New York on May 29-30, 2008. Buiter, Willem H. (2008b). Housing Wealth isn’t Wealth. National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. W14204, July 2008.

www.economics-ejournal.org

27

Buchanan, Mike and Themistoklis Fiotakis (2004). House Prices: A Threat to Global Recovery or Part of the Necessary Rebalancing? Goldman Sachs Global Economics Paper No. 114, July 15. Carroll, C., M. Otsuka, and J. Slacalek (2006). How Large is the Housing Wealth Effect? A New Approach. NBER Working Paper No. 12746 (Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research, December). Case, K.E., and R.J. Shiller (2003). Is There a Bubble in the Housing Market? Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, vol. 2, pp. 299–342. Case, K.E., J.M. Quigley, and R.J. Shiller (2005). Comparing Wealth Effects: The Stock Market Versus the Housing Market. Advances in Macroeconomics, vol. 5(1). Edelstein, Robert H. And Sau Kim Lum (2004). House Prices, Wealth Effects, and the Singapore Macroeconomy. Journal of Housing Economics, vol. 13(4), December, pp. 342–367. Hayashi, F. (1982). Tobin's Marginal q and Average q: A Neoclassical Interpretation. Econometrica, vol. 50(1), January, pp. 213–224. Himmelberg, C., C. Mayer, and T. Sinai (2005). Assessing High House Prices: Bubbles, Fundamentals and Misperceptions. Journal of Economic Perspectives, vol. 19, pp. 67–92. Hurst, E., and F. Stafford (2004). Home is Where the Equity Is: Mortgage Refinancing and Household Consumption. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, vol. 36 (6), pp. 985–1014. Iacoviello, Matteo (2004). Consumption, House Prices, and Collateral Constraints: A Structural Econometric Analysis. Journal of Housing Economics, Elsevier, vol. 13(4), December, pp. 304–320. Khandani, A, A. Lo and R. Merton, R (2009). Systemic Risk and the Refinancing Ratchet Effect. NBER Working Paper No. 15362. Klyuev, V., and P. Mills (2006). Is Housing Wealth an ATM? The Relationship Between Household Wealth, Home Equity Withdrawal, and Saving Rates. IMF Working Paper WP/06/162 (Washington: International Monetary Fund). Kohn, Donald L (2006). Economic Outlook. Speech given at the Money Marketeers of New York University, New York, New York, October 4.

www.economics-ejournal.org

28

Kroszner, Randall S. (2005). Rodney Dangerfield” Redux: Still no Rrespect for the Economy. Speech given at the annual business forecast luncheon of the University of Chicago Graduate School of Business, Wednesday, December 7. Kroszner, Randall S. (2008). Testimony on the Federal Housing Administration Housing Stabilization and Homeownership Act before the Committee on Financial Services, U.S. House of Representatives, April 9, 2008. Laibson, D (2009). Bubble Economics. Hahn lecture, Royal Economic Society meeting, University of Surrey (April). Mishkin, Frederic S. (2008). Housing and the Monetary Transmission Mechanism. In Housing, Housing Finance and Monetary Policy. A Symposium Sponsored by The Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, Jackson Hole, Wyoming August 30-Spetember 1, 2007, pp. 359–413, Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City. Mulligan, Casey and Luke Threinen (2008). .Market Responses to the Panic of 2008. NBER Working Paper Series no 14446, October. Plosser, Charles I. (2007). House Prices and Monetary Policy. Lecture, European Economics and Financial Centre Distinguished Speakers Series, July 11, London, UK. Soros, George (2009). The CEU Lectures. October 26–30. Yaari, M. (1965). Uncertain Lifetime. Life Insurance and the Theory of the Consumer. Review of Economic Studies, vol. 32, April, pp. 137–50.

www.economics-ejournal.org

29

Please note: You are most sincerely encouraged to participate in the open assessment of this article. You can do so by either recommending the article or by posting your comments. Please go to: www.economics-ejournal.org/economics/journalarticles/2010-22

The Editor

© Author(s) 2010. Licensed under a Creative Commons License - Attribution-NonCommercial 2.0 Germany

Similar Documents

Premium Essay

Essay

...1 Overview of How to Write an Essay Writing essays is a major element of your education at the university level. Effective writing gives you the ability to express your ideas, theories, arguments, and projects clearly. The skills you acquire at the university level through writing essays will be aimed at practical business applications that you will be able to use in the workplace. The following information provides a succinct overview of the elements you need to know to begin writing an essay. It will help you on your writing journey. Types of Essays Narrative A narrative essay is a story told by a narrator. Generally, a narrative discusses the personal experience of the author (the first person point of view), but it can also be written about things that happen to others (third person point of view). A narrative typically involves characters, a setting, specific and vivid details, and a series of events that can include current incidents, flashbacks, or dialogue. Cause and Effect A cause and effect essay explores why events, actions, or conditions occur (cause) and examines the results of those events, actions, or conditions (effect). For example, a cause could be purchasing a new expensive home. The effect might be fewer family vacations, more time spent on upkeep, or less time with family because of extra work hours to pay for the home. Comparison and Contrast A comparison and contrast essay shows the relationship between two or more elements. The items can be compared...

Words: 6215 - Pages: 25

Premium Essay

Essay

...How to determine custom essay editing company that is legitimate This is the company you will find great editors to provide you with custom essay editing service. Students whose first language is not English may find speaking and writing in English as a difficult task for them. Most of these students are international students who have enrolled in various universities in America and in the UK. The main teaching language is English, American and Standard English respectively. It is essential for students to master well the language of instruction because it is a medium through which they are required to write their assignments and speak in classroom. Competence and fluency in English language will help students to read and understand the teaching material provided to them. It is important therefore for students to ask for support from custom essay editing services which deal with the tips of writing good essays among other academic papers and also to write for them assignment essays. Our writing and editing services is created both for students and professionals. We deal with both the non academic and academic editing and writing services to fulfill your needs. At our custom essay editing, you will find editors who are qualified in linguistics and English language. We are ready to provide you the custom essay editing service at any time of the day or night because we operate as a 24/7 service. Our custom essay editing service comprises of creative thinkers, skillful editors...

Words: 574 - Pages: 3

Premium Essay

Essay

...An essay is usually a short piece of writing. It is often written from an author's personal point of view. Essays can be literary criticism, political manifestos, learned arguments, observations of daily life, recollections, and reflections of the author. The definition of an essay is vague, overlapping with those of an article and a short story. Almost all modern essays are written in prose, but works in verse have been dubbed essays (e.g. Alexander Pope's An Essay on Criticism and An Essay on Man). While brevity usually defines an essay, voluminous works like John Locke's An Essay Concerning Human Understanding and Thomas Malthus's An Essay on the Principle of Population provide counterexamples. It is very difficult to define the genre into which essays fall. Aldous Huxley, a leading essayist, gives guidance on the subject: Like the novel, the essay is a literary Abstract This article will examine the reasons why it is important both linguistically and psychologically to build a vocabulary quickly when learning a foreign language. The article asserts that very little can be achieved or learned in a foreign language with a small vocabulary and that by building a sizable vocabulary quite quickly one can soon be able to function adequately. You may also wish to look at http://www.jalt-publications.org/tlt/files/95/feb/meara.html   Introduction   It is obvious that in order to learn a foreign language one needs to learn many many words. But how many? Educated...

Words: 332 - Pages: 2

Premium Essay

Essay

...There are some teachers who are going to require you to write a 250 word essay. Actually, it is a very short essay for that matter but for some students, it may also be a burden to have a word limit in writing. Let us take a look at the scenarios that you need to understand to compose a well developed essay. For some students, it may be limiting to have a word factor quota in writing an article. There are some individuals who can tell more out of a topic and that having 250 words will not suffice to tell everything in their minds. That is why you need to have the skills in budgeting the words that you have to write without sacrificing the ideas that you have to deliver. There are different essay types that you also need to consider so having a word limit cannot simply be an easy task. Still for some students, a 250 word essay may mean too much because there are also some people who do not want to waste their time writing. No matter what the essay structure may be, these types of people are not really eager to translate their thoughts to written form so they think 250 words simply equates to too much work. Anyway, you need to understand that having this kind of limit will eventually benefit the students as they improve their discipline, being responsible and being resourceful individuals. We can offer you to buy essays from us so you do not have to worry about the number of words in writing. Let our writers make your life easier...

Words: 273 - Pages: 2

Free Essay

Essay

...I’m sorry this is not a real essay I’m sorry this is not a real essay I’m sorry this is not a real essay I’m sorry this is not a real essay I’m sorry this is not a real essay I’m sorry this is not a real essay I’m sorry this is not a real essay I’m sorry this is not a real essay I’m sorry this is not a real essay I’m sorry this is not a real essay I’m sorry this is not a real essay I’m sorry this is not a real essay I’m sorry this is not a real essay I’m sorry this is not a real essay I’m sorry this is not a real essay I’m sorry this is not a real essay I’m sorry this is not a real essay I’m sorry this is not a real essay I’m sorry this is not a real essay I’m sorry this is not a real essay I’m sorry this is not a real essay I’m sorry this is not a real essay I’m sorry this is not a real essay I’m sorry this is not a real essay I’m sorry this is not a real essay I’m sorry this is not a real essay I’m sorry this is not a real essay I’m sorry this is not a real essay I’m sorry this is not a real essay I’m sorry this is not a real essay I’m sorry this is not a real essay I’m sorry this is not a real...

Words: 256 - Pages: 2

Premium Essay

Essay

...This is my essay. This is my essay. This is my essay. This is my essay. This is my essay. This is my essay. This is my essay. This is my essay. This is my essay. This is my essay. This is my essay. This is my essay. This is my essay. This is my essay. This is my essay. This is my essay. This is my essay. This is my essay. This is my essay. This is my essay. This is my essay. This is my essay. This is my essay. This is my essay. This is my essay. This is my essay. This is my essay. This is my essay. This is my essay. This is my essay. This is my essay. This is my essay. This is my essay. This is my essay. This is my essay. This is my essay. This is my essay. This is my essay. This is my essay. This is my essay. This is my essay. This is my essay. This is my essay. This is my essay. This is my essay. This is my essay. This is my essay. This is my essay. This is my essay. This is my essay. This is my essay. This is my essay. This is my essay. This is my essay. This is my essay. This is my essay. This is my essay. This is my essay. This is my essay. This is my essay. This is my essay. This is my essay. This is my essay. This is my essay. This is my essay. This is my essay. This is my essay. This is my essay. This is my essay. This is my essay. This is my essay. This is my essay. This is my essay. This is my essay. This is my essay. This is my essay. This is my essay. This is my essay. This is my essay. This is my essay. This is my essay. This is...

Words: 401 - Pages: 2

Premium Essay

Essay

...Process and Procedure Essay Samples are Helpful Guides in Writing Saturday, June 20th, 2009 Process and Procedure Essay Samples will Assist You in Understanding this Essay Format First of all let’s find out what essay is called process and procedure essay. It is an essay which sometimes called “how to” essay for it guides in certain activities or gives instructions as how to do some job (procedure) or complete a certain task. When you feel difficulty with this essay type, you can find process and procedure essay samples which can give you useful tips into creating an essay which will be have high rating. Process and procedure essay outlining certain procedures or directions to perform certain activity is an important task if one needs to learn how to compile clear instructions to serve the needs of professionals in different fields. These can be helpful for engineers, teachers, doctors and even housewives when it concerns cook books which are also some kind of instructive writing. Procedure essay writing is a useful skills for managerial personnel as they need to organize people and direct them toward certain activities. Process and procedure essay samples can be found online in abundance. Through these essay examples one can get some notion about procedure writing and take some notes how to complete a good piece of process essay. One may note that procedure can include descriptions, warnings and recommendations to the procedures described. To provide guidelines for...

Words: 539 - Pages: 3

Premium Essay

Essay

...Essay Writer can provide students with the exact answers to their essay assignments through our free essay section as well as our custom essay writing services. All of Essay Writer’s free essays are uploaded to our site by some college and university students in the UK to serve as informative guides and comparative templates to help you finish your own essay writing tasks with greater ease and clarity. These sample essays are readily downloadable and very easily accessible; just simply select a subject area or topic from our list of available subjects. You can then go through our list of available essay titles under that subject. Welcome to Essay Writer’s free essays section! You can now access our very extensive collection of free essays. These essays are all original and previously not made available to anyone, and are excellently written and submitted by some well meaning college students who wish to share their knowledge to help you do better in writing your own essays. Below is the list of the subject areas we cover in our free essays section. Simply select the subject that corresponds to your need. You will then be shown a list of all the essay titles available for that specific subject. Essay Writer regularly updates its free essay database. Keep checking back for additional subjects or topics. You may also bookmark our Free Essays page to make it easier to check back on the availability of our free essays. To bookmark this page, simply click on the bookmark...

Words: 314 - Pages: 2

Premium Essay

Essays

...HOW TO READ ESSAYS YOU MUST ANALYZE 1. Take a pencil in your hand. 2. Read the essay over once, quickly, looking for the main idea, for what the essay is about in general, and for what the author seems to be saying. Don't get bogged down in details. (If you come to an unfamiliar word, circle it but go on reading). 3. Check the meaning of unfamiliar words. If they seem to be key words, i.e., if the author uses them more than once, scribble a brief definition at the bottom of the page or at the end of the essay. 4. Now re-read more slowly and carefully, this time making a conscious attempt to begin to isolate the single most important generalization the author makes: his thesis. Follow his line of thought; try to get some sense of structure. The thesis determines the structure, so the structure, once you begin to sense it, can lead you to the thesis. What is the main point the author is making: Where is it? Remember, examples or "for instances" are not main points. The thesis is the generalization the author is attempting to prove valid. Your job, then is to ask yourself, "What is the author trying to prove"? Another way of identifying the thesis is to ask yourself, "What is the unifying principle of this essay"? or "What idea does everything in this essay talk about"? or "Under what single main statement could all the subdivisions fit"? If the author has stated his thesis fully and clearly and all in one place, your job is easier. The thesis is apt to be stated...

Words: 971 - Pages: 4

Premium Essay

Essay

...to write A Level Sociology Essay Assessment With reference to the present AEB syllabus, there are three main skills being assessed in your essays. 1. Knowledge and Understanding (9 marks) 2. Interpretation and Application (9 marks) 3. Evaluation (9 marks) What Does This Mean? What this means is that for writing an essay is that the content (studies, names of researcher, dates, figures, concepts, although important need to be organised coherently, applied to a variety of social situations and interpreted, and expressed in a critical fashion. You must be aware of the skills being highlighted in the question in order to use the appropriate skills in your essays. You should also practice writing essays regularly and develop a technique which addresses the skills required so that you can actually answer the question set. I hope that this handout should allow you to achieve this. Stage One Many students are too quick into diving into an answer. They have focused on certain key terms and ‘assumed’ what the essay requires from a quick look at the question. Instead, the question should be read a number of times. Task One With the title provided. Analyze the question by underlining the key features in the essay title Double underline the skills being assessed, e.g., describe and explain Identify any terms or concepts contained in the question. These terms will need to be defined, i.e. concepts such as interactionists. Essay questions will also include...

Words: 1452 - Pages: 6

Premium Essay

Essay

...from these events? How have they affected your personality or how you deal with situations now? Remember the focus of the essay is on the contrasting impacts of these events in your life. These events do not have to be major events, they could be minor in nature but their impact on you could be great and long lasting. Undertake the task of pre writing for this topic. Select your two events. Describe them in point form. Consider their diverse impacts on your life. By the end of this class you should have completed your pre writing and make sure you get your sheet signed by me. You have the week to work on your first draft. Those of you who would like to show me the first draft are free to submit it to me online and I shall hand them back to you online. I will tell you whether you are on the right track, however this is optional and you will not be penalized if you do not show me your first draft. You need to give me Draft 1 by Tuesday, Feb 26. This will be an online submission under Assignments on ilearn. I will correct it and give it back to you by Sunday March 3, and then you will work on changing the draft according to my corrections and bring it to class on Tuesday, March 5 when we will have a peer review session. So after our class today you need to upload your first drafts of the essay in a week, by Feb 26 in an area marked out as Essay 1 under Assignments on Ilearn. You need to exchange your second drafts with two of your classmates on Tuesday, March...

Words: 547 - Pages: 3

Premium Essay

Essay

...tutorial x 13 weeks)     Level: Foundation/Matriculation     Lecturers: Ms Fazidah Abdul Jamil., Mdm Goh Wan Chen, Ms Saratha Thevi Ramasamy, Ms Norzaireen Shamsul Kamar Synopsis: This course is designed for students who require the necessary skills for tertiary studies. Some basic grammatical concepts are taught and students are to apply them in their writing. Writing will focus on the development of coherent paragraphs. Reading skills will cover such strategies as scanning, skimming, main ideas, contextual clues and inferences. Learning Outcomes: Upon completion of this subject, student will be able to: 1. write summaries as well as process, comparison-contrast and cause-effect essays 2. apply basic grammatical concepts in writing 3. answer questions based on academic texts 4. give oral presentations Textbook: 1. Daise, D., Norloff, C., and Carne, P., (2011). Q: Skills for Success 4 : Reading and Writing Oxford University Press, UK 2. Paterson, K, and Wedge, R., (2013). Oxford Grammar for EAP. Oxford University Press, UK Recommended References: Cambridge International Dictionary of English (1997), Cambridge University Press, UK Mode of Assessment: [1] Class participation 5% [2] Quiz 1 15% [3] Quiz 2 10% [4] Oral Presentation 10% [5] Mid-Term Examination 20% [6] Final Examination 40% Syllabus – FDENG001 |Week |UNIT |Topics ...

Words: 469 - Pages: 2

Premium Essay

Essay

...Define Your Thesis For essays that are part of an Early Years Care & Education Degree, it is important to clearly define a thesis statement within the first paragraph of the essay. Even if you are given a topic to write, such as the importance of preschool classes in low-income neighborhoods, you need to develop a strong thesis in your own words. Here is an example: "Preschool classes in low-income neighborhoods are a crucial step in helping all children enter elementary school at the same educational level, regardless of the income of the family." Once you have defined a clear thesis, you can proceed to the rest of your essay. However, without a clear thesis, your essay will not hold up. Use Examples The majority of your essay should be a careful and clear argument that supports your thesis statement. Do research and cite as many examples as possible to prove your point. For an essay about the merits of all-day educational opportunities for preschool-aged children, check trustworthy sources such as the National Association for the Education of Young Children and national PTA. Provide each point in a strong and complete paragraph. Each paragraph should have a main statement, supporting information and a conclusion. Tie In Conclusion After you have made your argument, state your conclusion in a clear and concise manner. Whether you have proven that the teacher ratio in a preschool setting should be lower than 4 to 1 or made a case for more national funding for the education...

Words: 281 - Pages: 2

Free Essay

Essay

...Carmen Hollow Mr. Beurskens College English Critique Essay: The Morals of the Prince May 3, 2011 The Grey Area between Good and Evil: A Critique of “The Morals of the Prince” by Niccolo Machiavelli Introduction We’ve all made a promise that we couldn’t keep and we have all felt bad about breaking those promises. Whether it was a promise to our parents, our children or a co-worker, we don’t feel good about it, but sometimes it can’t be helped. Usually if we couldn’t keep a promise it was for a good reason and not a selfish one. To the person that we made the promise to, we may be viewed as uncaring or unreliable, but to ourselves we know that we had to make a decision that could hurt someone but at the same time our decision could help that same person or persons. Making a promise and not being able to keep it for one reason or another, is one of the few topics that Machiavelli writes of in his essay “The Morals of the Prince”. He also tells why he believes a prince should be feared rather than loved, and why a prince should be stingy and not generous. He wants us to know how a “perfect” prince should act and behave so that the prince will be viewed upon as a great prince. Summary Machiavelli writes about how he believes a prince should act and behave to be considered a successful prince, one that is loved and feared, liberal and stingy, one that knows when to keep his word and when to break it. In his essay, Machiavelli writes “a prince who wants to keep his post...

Words: 1138 - Pages: 5

Premium Essay

Essay

...Basic techniques for generating ideas. Brainstorming. Brainstorming consists in writing series of words or sentences just as they flow from our mind, although they have no logical order or connections. Once the words are written down, we have to establish relationships among them. This is the embryo of the future text. Free writing. Free writing is a similar technique to the brainstorming. Consists in writing a text without previous decisions or ideas about how we want to write it. Just choosing a topic and writing about it, and then we can summarise the main ideas. Organisation of information. There are some basic rules for writing a well - structured text. The text should be organised in a clear way; it must not be a twisted or an incomprehensible lot of ideas. We have to try to write according to certain conventions about hoe the text is organised. We have to structure our text in paragraphs. Each paragraph must express one idea. Some rules referring to the paragraphs: A paragraph must be clearly separated from other paragraphs, either by an empty line or by indenting the first line, or both. There must be no blank spaces or half-empty lines inside the paragraph. A paragraph in academic prose does not begin with a dot, a line or a kind of mark, except in special circumstances. Each body paragraph must normally have a topic sentence, and more than one sentence. Types of paragraphs. The introductory paragraph. There must be at least one...

Words: 1285 - Pages: 6