Free Essay

Keynesian

In: Business and Management

Submitted By Shringar
Words 7811
Pages 32
Keynes, ‘love of money’ and the current crisis
Paolo Paesani1
This version 1 October 2010 Preliminary version
ABSTRACT
Keynes saw ‘love of money’, love for the unlimited accumulation of liquidity as mark of personal success and shield against uncertainty, as a defining element of capitalism. This paper investigates connections between ‘love of money’ and the current crisis establishing two main linkages: bonus-based compensation mechanisms and hedge funds. Closer scrutiny and regulation both of bonuses and hedge funds can help prevent future crises. Permanent solutions to the problems posed by ‘love of money’ however will come only from new models of education and persuasion. Keywords: Causes of the financial crisis JEL:

1

University of Rome “Tor Vergata”, e-mail paolo.paesani@uniroma2.it. A previous significantly different version of this paper has been published in Italian in Il Ritorno dell’Economia Politica , G. Bonifati and A. Simonazzi (Eds.) Donzelli Editore, 2010, Roma. I would like to thank Annalisa Rosselli and Matteo Formenti for their helpful suggestions and comments. The usual disclaimer applies.

“Whereas modern theory serves as a simulacrum of the economy – stylised and abstract to be sure – Keynes theory is a diagnostic instrument in the service of Doctor Keynes, consulting economic physician” (Hoover 2006, p. 78) “I also want to emphasise strongly the point about economics being a moral science. [A science that]…deals with introspection and with values […] with motives, expectations, psychological uncertainties ” (Keynes 1938, CW 14, p. 400) “The love of money is the root of all evils” (1 Timothy 6:10)

Introduction “The fact is – a fact not yet recognised by the great public – that we are now in the depth of a very sever international slump, a slump which will take its place in history amongst the most acute ever experienced. It will require not merely passive movements of bank rates to lift us out of the depression of this order, but a very active determined policy”. These words, an accurate description of present times, were written by John Maynard Keynes eighty years ago on 10 May 1930 in The Nation (Harrod 1972, p. 469). As the world economy spirals into a deep recession, Keynesian economics has once more become fashionable (Farmer 2009a). The debate on Keynes and the crisis has been largely focused on anti-cyclical policy measures, on their short and long-run consequences, on exit strategies and on international transmission mechanisms (e.g. Krugman 2008, Ferguson 2009, Steil 2009, Farmer 2009b). Considerably less attention has been paid to diagnosis, especially in the academic literature, with some recent notable exceltpions (Leijonhufvud 2009a, Bateman et al. 2010). Prevailing interpretations of the current crisis see it as the consequence of exogenous factors including (1) anomalous financial conditions (extraordinarily low real and nominal interest rates, a global savings glut, very low expected and realized volatility), (2) rapid innovation in financial instruments that made credit-risk trading easier, (3) regulation failures, (4) fundamental flaws in the rating agencies' business model, (5) the procyclical behaviour of leverage in much of the financial system and of the Basel capital adequacy requirements, (6) privately rational but socially inefficient disintermediation, and competitive international de-regulation (Buiter (2007, Greenspan 2008, Blundell-Wignall et al. 2008, Geithner 2008, Sharma 2008 among many others). According to this school of thought

Financial crises and deep depressions arise from one of the following: non-essential institutional flaws which prevent the market from working its wonders, the system of intervention contains openings which allow some dirty rotten scoundrels to operate or external shocks dislodge the economy”. (Minsky 1991, p. 5)

2

Similar interpretations leave little room for psychological factors and for the idea that

The natural laws of development of capitalist economies lead to the emergence of conditions conducive to financial instability. Law and policymakers need to be aware of institutional evolution and to develop instruments to contain the potential for both inflationary surges and deflationary disruptions. Potential instability is a basic system characteristic.(Minsky 1991, p.6).

Building on this intuition, shared by the author of this paper, Minskian interpretations of the current crisis see it as the latest manifestation of recurrent financial instability (Rochon 2003, Wray 2009). De Antoni (2009), adopting a strictly Keynesian perspective, argues that the current crisis comes from the US and from the exhaustion of investment opportunities compensated by lending to households rather than from an externally financed rise in investment leading to euphoria and fragility in the sense of Minsky. Both Minskian and Keynesian interpretations agree on the relevance of psychological endogenous factors. Most investigations of the psychological

determinants of the current crisis come from the field of behavioural finance. Dow (2009) explores the role for psychology within Minsky’s financial instability hypothesis moving away from behavioural models. This paper adopts yet a different approach within the same strand of literature, focusing on the Keynesian concept of ‘love of money’. Keynes thought that ‘love of money’, love for the unlimited accumulation of liquidity as mark of personal success and shield against uncertainty and fear, was an essential driver of capitalism. Love of money is a specific form of greed,2 greed for liquidity, for purchasing power and for social recognition in a competitive and uncertain world. It is one of those psychological forces which Akerlof and Shiller (2009), possibly perpetrating a solecism (King 2010), have recently labelled animal spirits. As both ‘love of money’ and (endogenous) crises characterise modern finance-based capitalism (Hein and Truger 2001), the goal of this paper is to investigate possible connections between these two phenomena.3 Focusing on the current crisis, the main conclusion of the paper is the main connections are related to bonus-based compensation mechanisms and hedge funds. Aggressive competition on financial markets, the adoption of dubious and fraudulent practices, the huge amount of resources spent to fend off all attempts at changing bonus-based compensation mechanisms in the banking and financial sector are all related to the ‘love of money’ motive and to its potential disruptive effects.
The claim that human greed may cause over-lending and financial crisis is a recognised fact by Keynesian scholars. In A Short History of Financial Euphoria (1993), for example, John Kenneth Galbraith shows how human greed was behind all the financial bubbles. Mason (2009) identifies greed as the qualifying element of the current crisis. 3 On money and capitalism see among others Lau and Smithin (2002).
2

3

The structure of the paper is as follows. Section 1 recalls the key facts of the crisis. Section 2 discusses Keynes’s view of capitalism and ‘love of money’. Section 3 explores ‘love of money’ in connection with the present crisis. Section 4 discusses why recognition of the disruptive impact of ‘love of money’ is impossible within mainstream economics. Section 5 concludes.

1. The facts of the crisis

At the start of the 21st century central banks inundated the world financial system with liquid reserves in response to a series of potentially destabilising events: the ‘millennium bug’ (Kelly 1998), the looming recession, the events of 9/11, the second war in Iraq; a monetary policy for a time of war as De Cecco (2007) defines it.4 The policy succeeded and banks, their fears receding, embarked on a lending spree, mostly directed to household sectors, especially in the US (De Antoni 2009). Bank loans were then turned into liquid and (apparently) safe securities through securitisation.5 Trading volumes of mortgage and asset-backed securities increased supported by optimistic ratings and financial innovation (CDOs, CDS). Lending encouraged economic recovery. The wealth-owning classes obtained huge windfall gains thanks to booming stock-exchanges and fast rising house prices. These were either spent or reinvested (e.g. through the home equity mechanism). Income distribution became increasingly iniquitous and polarised throughout the western world (Palma 2009) . In 2004 central banks responded to mounting inflationary pressures by gradually restricting monetary conditions. Marginal debtors were the first to be affected. Doubts on the value and liquidity of asset-backed securities spread. Mortgage delinquencies and foreclosures rose sharply after U.S. house prices peaked and began to fall in early 2007. Banks and other financial intermediaries started registering large losses on their holdings of non-prime residential mortgages and mortgage-backed securities (Blundell-Wignall 2008). As Leijonhfvud (2009a) recalls “August 7, 2007 has become the date generally accepted as the day the crisis hit. It was not the day that problems first began to reveal themselves. There had been trouble in American housing and mortgage markets going back to the previous autumn. But on August 7, the interbank market froze. The banks would not lend to each other. This was virtually unprecedented, something that market participants had not experienced before”. Banks tightened their lending standards, which reduced the availability of loans and increased their cost.

Before this time monetary expansion had been the policy chosen both by the central bank of Japan and the US Federal Reserve, in response to the intrinsic fragility of the US financial system (De Cecco 2001). 5 On securitisation and its role in the crisis see González-Páramo 2008. On the relationship between securitisation, financial fragility and instability see Kregel (2007). For a reconstruction of the current crisis see Krugman (2009)

4

4

Tensions in money markets came in several waves. Money market tensions intensified again in early March 2008, as the financial turmoil showed signs of worsening and spreading. (BIS 2008, p. 3-4) As investors retreated to the safety of government bonds, yields on risky assets were driven up. Investor concerns intensified during 2008 as financial losses continued to mount. The crisis peaked in September 2008 when the bankruptcy of Lehman Brothers and near-bankruptcy of American International Group (AIG).6 Risks of a new recession emerged. As BIS (2008) recalls

What had started as a problem specific to the US subprime mortgage market became a source of outsize losses for financial firms worldwide on their holdings of related securities. Uncertainty about the size and distribution of losses was exacerbated by the complexity of the new structures used in the securitisation process. Retrenchment from risk-taking led to illiquidity, exposing weaknesses in the funding arrangements of many financial firms. Indeed, the situation was punctuated by the near failure of sizeable financial firms, prompting intervention by the public sector to avert potential systemic repercussions from a disorderly collapse. (BIS 2008)

The rapidity and severity with which the crisis of the US sub-prime mortgage market spread to the rest of the world depended on the high degree of coupling7 and complexity8 of the international banking and financial system, the result of many years of financial deregulation inspired by a laissez-faire approach to finance (Dowd 1996) often encouraged by monetary and regulatory authorities especially in the U.S. (e.g. Greenspan 1998) . The liquidation of the Glass-Steagall act, the adoption of the originate-to-distribute model by many banks in lieu of the traditional originateto-hold model, the diffusion of derivative products and financial innovation engendering the false belief that risk diversification meant risk elimination form part of this process (on this see Davidson 2008). As recently noted in a report by UNCTAD,

Financial deregulation driven by an ideological belief in the virtues of the market has allowed “innovation” of financial instruments that are completely detached from productive activities in the real sector of the economy. Such instruments favour speculative activities that build on apparently convincing information, which in reality is nothing other than an extrapolation of trends into the future” (UNCTAD 2009).

6 7

Source http://timeline.stlouisfed.org/ Tight coupling is where every component of a certain process is tightly linked, with little room for error. With tight coupling, each action of the system immediately triggers the next. (Source http://www.futureblind.com/2009/01/thereal-causes-of-the-financial-crisis/). 8 Interactive complexity is when a system is not only complex, but has components that can interact in unexpected or varied ways. There are non-linear interactions and feedback loops that occur within the process. As long as the system isn’t tightly coupled, the problem can eventually be fixed because there is the time and flexibility to solve it. (Source http://www.futureblind.com/2009/01/the-real-causes-of-the-financial-crisis/).

5

Lack of accounting transparency and the use of statistical models often tested on incomplete and insufficient data, exacerbated the problem. As Truman (2009) recalls starting in the summer of 2007, the monetary authorities generally acted quickly to adopt measures responding to the demand by financial institutions for increased access to central bank liquidity. As part of the containment phase of the crisis, a few central banks have embraced so-called unconventional monetary policies with respect to what they buy, on what terms, and whether they worry about the consequences for the liability sides of their balance sheets. It was not until the second year of the crisis, starting in late 2008, that discretionary fiscal policy came to be widely used by those countries with scope to do so. BIS (2010) documents the partial success of these interventions at a global level.

2. Keynes, capitalism and love of money

As Backhouse and Bateman (2009) note, Keynes believed that capitalism was not an end in itself but an essential mean to attain material prosperity and to preserve individual freedom. As a mean however it was fragile and, especially after World War I, in need of regulation and repair. The adjective he most frequently used to qualify pre-war capitalism was “individualistic”; a term referring both to businessmen and to the institutions preserving private enterprise and related to capitalism being founded on individual saving and private accumulation of wealth. Wealth accumulation in turn depended on distributive inequality, on people accepting to live frugal lives, on perceived fairness in rewards, on the stability of the value of money. If one or more elements failed, as they had done at the end of World War I, the delicate and complex machine of capitalism would cease to function. While accepting it as a necessity, Keynes raised technical, moral and aesthetic objections against capitalism (Moggridge 2005). Technically, capitalism was prone to instability, stagnation and distributional inequality (Keynes 1936, Ch. 24). On aesthetic grounds its main defect was its disregard for valuable things that paid no money: art, friendship, the contemplation of beauty and the free pursuit of knowledge, things which Keynes, with his Cambridge and Bloomsbury background, valued most (Dostaler 2007).

The same rule of self-destructive financial calculation governs every walk of life. We destroy the beauty of the countryside because the unappropriated splendours of nature have no economic valur. We are capable of shutting off the sun and the stars because they pay no dividend. (Keynes 1933 p. 242).

6

This view was the utilitarian and economic – one might almost say financial – ideal, as the sole, respectable purpose of the community as a whole; the most dreadful heresy, perhaps, which has ever gained the ear of a civilized people. Bread and nothing but bread, and not even bread, and bread accumulating at compound interest until it has turned into stone (Keynes 1936 p. 242)

On the moral side, it was ‘love of money’ that Keynes found most detestable in capitalism. As Backhouse and Bateman (2010) recall, in the second half of the 1920s Keynes thought of writing a book titled An Examination of Capitalism. In the end he gave up the project leaving behind two outlines of what he intended to cover. Interestingly, the starting point was ‘the love of money’ and the idea that capitalism was a device through which “greedy instincts” could be mobilized to promote “technical improvements, hard work, and saving”. According to Dostaler (2007), the reflection on the fragility of possessing monetary wealth and the expression of contempt for the love of money appear in many of Keynes writings, starting with the first papers he read in front of the Apostles. Keynes believed that ‘love of money’, the basis of capitalism, was an instinct whose neurotic dimension seemed obvious to him, an idea he shared with Freud. In his 1925 Short view of Russia Keynes argued that

It seems clearer every day that the moral problem of our age is concerned with the love of money, with the habitual appeal to the money motive in the nine-tenths of the activities of life with the universal striving after individual economic security as the prime object of endeavour, with the social approbation of money as the measure of constructive success, and with the social appeal to the hoarding instinct as the foundation of the necessary provision for the family and the future”. (Keynes, 1925 pp.268-9)

In 1926 in the End of Laissez faire Keynes noted that

Capitalism depends upon an intense appeal to the money-making and money-loving instincts of individuals as the main motive force of the economic machine’ and ‘love of money’ ,‘one of the most powerful of human motives’ which ‘is harnessed to the task of distributing economic resources in the way best calculated to increase wealth […]acting through the pursuit of profit, as an adjutant to natural selection, to bring about the production on the greatest possible scale of what is most strongly desired as measured by exchange value’ (Keynes 1926).

In 1930 in the Economic Possibilities for our Grandchildren , describing a future world free of economic care defined, Keynes wrote

7

The love of money as a possession - as distinguished from the love of money as a means to the enjoyments and realities of life - will be recognised for what it is, a somewhat disgusting morbidity, one of those semi-criminal, semi-pathological propensities which one hands over with a shudder to the specialists in mental diseases”. Love of money is related to intense, unsatisfied purposiveness to blidly pursue wealth in the attempt to secure a spurious and delusive immortality. (Keynes 1926)

Dostaler (2009), focusing on the psychological dimension of the love of money, explains that

Keynes came to believe that the irrational love of money was the very motor of capitalism. The majority of human beings desire money for itself, and some prove themselves willing to transgress all moral boundaries to acquire it. […] To enrich oneself becomes to accumulate without end. There is no limit to the amount of money one can possess. The mark of success, of power, of notoriety, becomes a sum of money. We are “worth” the sum”.

Like Freud, Keynes saw the pursuit of money as a means of channelling aggressive impulses

Dangerous human proclivities can be canalised into comparatively harmless channels by the existence of opportunities for money-making and private wealth, which if they cannot be satisfied in this way, may find their outlet in cruelty, the reckless pursuit of personal power and authority, and other forms of self-aggrandissement. It is better that a man should tyrannise over his bank balance than over his fellow-citizens; and whilst the former is sometimes denounced as being but a means to the latter, sometimes at least is an alternative. (Keynes 1936, p. 374)

and, money the ‘subtle device for linking the present to the future’ (Keynes 1936, p. 294), also as a shield against fear of uncertainty and death.9

Our desire to hold money as a store of wealth is a barometer of the degree of our distrust of our calculations and conventions concerning the future. Even though this feeling about money is tself conventional or instinctive, it operates, so to speak at a deeper level of our motivation. It takes charge at the moments when the higher more precarious conventions have weakened. The possession of actual money lulls our disquietude”. [Keynes 1937, pp. 116]

9

Runde (1994) confirms that Keynes's reference to uncertainty in the context of the liquidity preference theory is essentially about the uncertainty which originates from the shattering of the state of confidence, the conventional basis on which rests the trust we put in our probabilistic calculations Runde is here referring to Keynes's two-tier theory of belief where probability is, at the first level, a measure of the belief in some conclusion relative to some specific body of evidence. Weight is at the second level, a measure of the completeness of the evidence on which that belief is based.

8

3. Love of money and the current crisis: bonuses and hedge funds

Leijonhufvud (2009b) description of the climate in the imminence of the crisis, is an excellent starting point to investigate connections between ‘love of money’ and the current crisis.

When leverage is rising all around with everyone buying on credit, everyone is also merrily making money. The profits thus made reinforce the process. Meanwhile, securitisation of loans and credit default swaps serve to obscure rising risk. Competition forces even those firms and individuals who realise that risk is rising to follow along or else be pushed out of the game altogether. A loan officer who does not lend, a risk manager who does not go along, a manager whose bank branch does not grow will all be under threat to lose their positions. The pressure to run with the herd becomes hard to resist. In this stage of the process, opposition to government interference with .free enterprise will be fierce and almost universal. But risk is constantly increasing and the financial system as a whole becomes steadily more fragile until eventually it is so fragile that when it finally breaks it can be difficult to identify what exactly made it happen”. [Leijonhufvud 2009, p. 5]

Loan officers, risk managers and bankers were induced to over-lend and to take advantage of securitisation, often resorting to dubious and fraudulent practices (e.g. predatory lending), because competition forced them to do so with bonuses as the prize to win. The increasingly enormous size of monetary bonuses paid in recent years the financial industry is the first connection between ‘love of money’ and the current crisis. As Friedman and Friedman (2009) recall

Richard Fuld, CEO of Lehman Brothers, earned approximately half-a-billion dollars between 1993 and 2007. Kristof (2008) observes that Fuld earned about $17,000 an hour to destroy a solid, 158-year old company. A.I.G. Financial Products, a 377-person office based in London, nearly destroyed the mother company, a trillion-dollar firm with approximately 116,000 employees. This small office found a way to make money selling credit default swaps to financial institutions holding very risky collateralized debt obligations. A.I.G. Financial Products made sure that its employees did very well financially; they earned $3.56 billion in the last seven years (Morgenson, 2008b). One of the big problems at many Wall Street firms was how compensation was determined. Bonuses made up a huge part of how people were compensated. One individual at Merrill Lynch received $350,000 as salary but $35,000,000 as bonus pay. Bonuses were based on short-term profits; this distorted the way incentives work. Employees were encouraged to take huge risks. since they were interested in the bonus. Bonuses were based on the earnings for that year. Thus, billions in bonuses were handed out by

9

Merrill Lynch in 2006 when profits hit $7.5 billion. Of course, those profits were only an illusion as they were based on toxic mortgages. After that, the company lost triple that amount; yet the bonuses were not rescinded (Story, 2008). (Friedman and Friedman 2009, p 11).

Sinclair et al. (2008) conclude their discussion on the economics of bonuses claiming that this form of compensation can bring large benefits but also be harmful. In the financial sector, this is especially true, above all when bonuses are related to noisy indicators of performance over brief periods. Burtless (2009) confirms that, in the current crisis, many of the decisions about asset purchases and extensions of credit were made by senior managers who had financial interests that differed substantially from the long-term interests of the shareholders for whom they supposedly worked. Kirkpatrick (2009), in his discussion of corporate governance lessons from the financial crisis, confirms that remuneration and incentive systems have played a key role, causing the development of unsustainable balance sheet positions and that remuneration problems also exist at the sales and trading function level. Friedman and Friedman (2009), in their broad and documented analysis of the consequences of unethical behaviour in the context of the present crisis, conclude that this debacle could not have occurred if the parties involved had been socially responsible and not motivated by greed. Conflicts of interest and the way CEOs are compensated are at the heart of this financial catastrophe. Erkens et al. (2009) find that firms that used CEO compensation contracts with a heavier emphasis on annual bonuses (as opposed to equity-based compensation) experienced larger losses during the crisis and took more risks before the crisis. Taleb (2009) argues the mismatch between the bonus payment frequency (typically, one year) and the time to blow up (about five to 20 years) is the cause of the accumulation of positions that hide risk by betting massively against small odds. A second connection between ‘love of money’ and the present crisis is related to the existence of hedge funds. As Stromqvist (2009) recalls, ”Hedge fund” is a collective term for different types of investment fund. A common feature of these funds is that they have absolute earnings targets, irrespective of market developments. Hedge funds are primarily intended for institutional investors and financially-strong private individuals. Over the last ten years, the hedge fund market has grown dramatically. In 1996, the approximately 2 000 hedge funds around the world managed a total of approximately USD 135 billion. Slightly stretching the concept, ‘love of money, the endless pursuit of liquid wealth per se as mark of success and shield against uncertainty is indeed the distinguishing feature of hedge funds. First, possession of huge liquid wealth is a pre-requisite to enter into a hedge fund. Second, ‘love of money’ and bonus-based compensation mechanisms affect the way hedge funds are managed and create powerful incentives to speculate an risk. Third, Many hedge funds protect their investments 10

against losses (so-called hedging) although this does not apply to all funds. As Crotty (2009) notes, partners in hedge and private equity funds typically charge 2 percent of assets managed plus 20 percent of profits. Since high returns both raise profit and help increase the size of assets under management, there are strong reasons to take risk in pursuit of high returns in a boom. Partners do not have to return their boom-induced fortune in the downturn. Fourth, mutual fund managers’ pay also rises with the size of assets under their control, and assets are maximized in a boom by earning the high returns associated with risky investments. This is an industry susceptible to herd behavior. Hedge funds are seen by many as contributing to financial crises including the present one. The criticism mainly relates to the possibility that hedge funds have a strong negative impact on asset prices by launching speculative attacks on certain companies, sectors or currencies, through short-selling. This effect may be reinforced if the speculative manoeuvre generates herd behaviour among investors. Hedge funds have also been accused of contributing to the development of financial bubbles and manipulating asset prices. Lo (2008) concludes his discussion on hedge funds, systemic risk, and the financial crisis of 2007–2008 , recognising the role of fear and greed, the main determinants of ‘love of money’ as also determining the way hedge funds are usually managed.

3. Mainstream blindness to ‘love of money’

As Chick and Tily (2004) note, in mainstream economics Keynes is dead. Standard macroeconomics is now classical economics, even though it may appear to be constructed from Keynesian components. Over the past three decades, economists have largely developed and come to rely on models that disregard key factors—including fundamental uncertainty, heterogeneity of decision rules, revisions of forecasting strategies, and changes in the social context—that drive outcomes in asset and other markets. The current academic agenda has largely crowded out research on the inherent causes of financial crises (Colander et al. 2009) Leijonhufvud (2008) explains the theoretical blindness of the economic profession vis à vis Keynesian interpretations of the current crisis to mainstream reliance on the market efficiency hypothesis, rational expectations and the representative agents (Malkiel 2003). Wray and Teymogne (2008) remind us that “the efficient market hypothesis, like all approaches derived from the old neoclassical theory, relegates money and finance to the sidelines.” As Davidson (2008b) points out, underlying the efficient market hypothesis is a fundamental axiom, the ergodic axiom. This axiom presumes that there exists an unchanged probability distribution governing past, present, and future events. In a world of efficient financial markets, holders of market-traded assets can readily 11

liquidate their position at a price close to the previously announced market price whenever any holder wishes to reduce his/her position in that asset. Keynes’s liquidity preference theory on the other hand presumes that the economic future is uncertain. Consequently, the classical ergodic axiom is not applicable. In a nonergodic world, current or past probability distribution functions are not reliable guides to the probability of future outcomes. If a deep rooted belief in the efficient market hypothesis and ergodicity rendered many in the economic profession blind to the risks posed by the financial deregulation this is all the more true in the case of the psychological factors including the ‘love of money’ . A recent book, collecting the comments of twelve renowned economists on Keynes’s Economic possibilities for our Grandchildren (Pecchi, Piga 2009) provides an excellent occasion to test the distance between mainstream Keynesian views of capitalism and ‘love of money’. Keynes’s contempt for the money motive and the strenuous “purposeful money-makers (who) may carry all of us along with them into the lap of economic abundance” is generally dismissed as the confused and elitist expression of moralistic prejudice and the perfect example of a unscientific approach to economics. Boldrin and Levine (2009), for example, attack Keynes for confusing real and monetary factors. Phelps (2009) sees Keynes disdainful attitude towards the quest for wealth as unusual for an economist, emblematic of anti-materialism and blind to the intellectual satisfactions in business life. Ohanian (2009) describes Keynes’ attitude as that of a judgemental and critical social commentator who uses his economist’s pulpit to make a rather puritan-based vision of the future. Fitoussi (2009), recognises that Keynes’ rejection of capitalism, with its greediness and egoistic behaviour, is not so badly founded but labels Keynes’ attitude Elite Communism and pities Keynes’ contempt for the wealthy classes. For mainstream economics, as represented by these comments, Keynes’s criticism of love of money is either pointless or wrong for at least four reasons. First, rational economic agents, free from money illusion, are interested in maximising utility and profit functions rather than money balances. Second, under normal conditions, nominal money holdings are kept to a minimum in favour of yield-bearing assets and appropriate risk-hedging strategies. Money is a medium of exchange and only transitorily a store of value. The concept of ‘love of money’ itself, with its moralistic and puritan tinge, is incompatible with the status of economics as a deductive science and with neutrality on moral and aesthetic issues. Fourth, if ‘love of money’ conduces to higher saving and wealth, to the competitive selection of the best CEOs and the most profitable investment strategies by aggressive risk-taking hedge funds it should be welcomed rather than decried as an example of Adam Smith’s ‘invisible hand’ at work.

12

Fundamental uncertainty answers the first two criticisms. In response to the third criticism we may use Meltzer’s words in his review of Pecchi and Piga (2009)

None of the essaysts mention that Keynes’s beliefs about material wealth, money, avarice, and greed were standard beliefs based to a considerable extent on what he learned from the philosopher G. E. Moore during his student years at Cambridge. […] [For Keynes] the objects of life were, or should be, love, truth, beauty, timeless contemplation, and the pursuit of knowledge. […] He rejected the Benthamite utilitarian calculation, with its emphasis on gains and losses in utility. (Meltzer 2009, p. 761)

And Keynes’ own words when he writes

I also want to emphasise strongly the point about economics being a moral science. I mentioned before that it deals with introspection and with values. I might add that it deals with motives, expectations, psychological uncertainties. One has to be constantly on guard against treating the material as constant and homogeneous. (Keynes 1938)

In response to the last criticism, Friedman and Friedman (2009) recall that Joan Robinson made the point more than 30 years ago that the pursuit of self-interest may be harmful to society and that Adam Smith should not be associated with this doctrine.10 In actuality, Smith believed that society cannot subsist among those who are at all times ready to hurt and injure one another.” Raw self-interest without a foundation of morality is not what Adam Smith is all about. Robinson ended a commencement address with the following warning: “I hope … that you will find that the doctrines of Adam Smith are not to be taken in the form in which your professors are explaining them to you” (Robinson, 2007).

4. Concluding remarks

The tree of the current crisis has many roots, some superficial, others reaching deep into the social and economic fabric of our societies. ‘Love of money’ belongs to the latter group. Following Keynes’ views on capitalism and the money-motive, this paper defines ‘love of money’ as love for the unlimited accumulation of liquidity as mark of material success and shield against uncertainty. It is a concept related to greed but greed of a special kind, greed for liquidity and for social recognition and greed mixed with fear of uncertainty and death.
10

On this see also Roncaglia (2005) p. 145, footnote 56.

13

As both ‘love of money’ and (endogenous) financial crises characterise finance-based capitalism, the goal of this paper has been to investigate possible connections between the two phenomena. Focusing on the current crisis, two main connections have been established: bonusbased compensation mechanisms and hedge funds. Both these mechanisms revolve around huge flows of money motivating economic agents to adopt high-risk strategies which certainly enhance the possibility of a crisis. Aggressive competition on financial markets, the adoption of dubious and fraudulent practices, the huge amount of resources spent to fend off all attempts at regulating bonusbased compensation mechanisms are all related to the ‘love of money’ motive and to its potential disruptive effects. Expansionary measures in response to the crisis may be useful in the short run but are unlikely to provide definitive to the problems posed by ‘love of money’ . On the contrary, by postponing / avoiding structural adjustment and by validating moral hazard and excessive risktaking, standard Keynesian policies may be actually setting the stage for the next crisis. Assuming that little can be done about ‘love of money’ in the short to medium run, the only policy prescription against the havoc it wreaks is to seriously regulate bonuses and compensation practices in the banking and financial industry especially in the hedge fund sector, whose destabilising potential through leverage-based speculation is the highest. This should be part of a broader regulatory reform plan aimed which should be inspired by two guiding principles. First, robust barriers will have to be re-established to prevent the spreading of financial contagion when it occurs in some part of the system barriers similar to those much that were established in the USA and in the rest of the world during the 1930s and 1940s. Second, a “keep it simple” approach should be adopted both in regulation and in financial contract drafting in order to reduce the overall level of complexity which far to often breeds uncertainty and fraud. In the long run, however, solving the problems posed by ‘love of money’, including its potential to generate financial crises, will require a new economic philosophy and a constant effort of persuasion. Reference Akerlof G.A., and Shiller, R.J. 2009 Animal Spirits, Princeton University Press, Princeton Backhouse, R.E., And Bateman B.W. 2009. ‘Keynes And Capitalism’, History Of Political Economy, Vol. 41, No. 4, 645-671 Bateman, B., Hirai, T., and Marcuzzo, C. 2010 The Return to Keynes, Belknap Harvard, Cambridge (MA) and London BIS, 2008 A, Annual Report, Bank For International Settlements, Basel

14

BIS, 2008b, “Central Bank Operations In Response To The Financial Turmoil” Report Submitted By A Study Group Established By The Committee On The Global Financial System This Study Group Was Chaired By Francesco Papadia Of The European Central Bank, CGFS Papers No 31 Blundell-Wignall A., 2008. ‘The Subprime Crisis: Size, Deleveraging And Some Policy Options’, Financial Market Trends , OECD 2008 Blundell-Wignall A., P. Atkinson S. Hoon Lee 2008 ‘The Current Financial Crisis: Causes And Policy Issues’, Financial Market Trends , OECD 2008 Boldrin, M., and Levine, D.K. 2009 ‘All the Interesting Questions, Almost All the Wrong Reasons’, contained in Pecchi and Piga (2009), Ch. 12, pp. 161-78 Buiter W.H., 2007 “Lessons From The 2007 Financial Crisis” , CEPR Discussion Paper No. DP6596, December Burtless G., 2009, “The Financial Crisis And A Flaw In Corporate Capitalism” , The National Journal, Brookings, 17 March 2009 Available At Http://Www.Brookings.Edu/Opinions/2009/0317_Capitalism_Burtless.Aspx Chick V., G. Tily, 2004‚ ‘Transfiguration And Death: Keynes’s Monetary Theory’ Available At Www.Uwe.Ac.Uk/Bbs/Aheconference/Papers/Chick-Tily.Doc Colander D., et al. 2009‚ “The Financial Crisis And The Systemic Failure Of Academic Economics” , University Of Copenhagen Dept. Of Economics Discussion Paper, No. 09-03 Crotty, J. 2009 ‘Structural Causes of the Global Financial Crisis: A Critical Assessment of the ‘New Financial Architecture’, Cambridge Journal of Economics, vol. 33, no. 4, ??? Davidson, P. 2008a “Securitization, Liquidity,And Market Failure” ”, Challange , Vol. 51, P. 4356, May/June ————, 2008b “How To Solve The U.S. Housing Problem And Avoid A Recession: A Revived HOLC And RTC .” Schwartz Center For Economic Policy Analysis, New School, New York, January 2008a (Available At Http://Mpra.Ub.Uni-Muenchen.De/7427/1/MPRA_ Paper_7427.Pdf) ————, 2009, John Maynard Keynes, Palgrave Macmillan De Antoni, E. 2009. ‘Minsky, Keynes and Financial instability: the recent subprime crisis”, mimeo De Cecco M., 1999 ‘The Lender Of Last Resort’, Economic Notes, 1 ————, 2007 Gli Anni Dell’incertezza, Introduzione, Editori Laterza, Bari Dostaler G. 1999. ‘Keynes And Economics: The Early Stages’, UQAM Economics Department, Working Paper Series No. 9901, January ————, 2007 Keynes And His Battles, Edward Elgar, Cheltenham ————, 2009 ‘Keynes and the love of money. The Freudian Connection’, paper presented at the 36th Annual Conference of the History of Economics Society, June 26-29, University of Colorado, Denver 15

Dow, S. 2009. ‘Market Sentiment and Minskian Financial Crisis: a Keynesian/agency structure / psychology analysis”, paper presented to the ‘World Economy in Crisis – the Return of Keynesianism?’ Conference, Berlin, 30-31 October 2009 Dowd K., 1996 “The Case For Financial Laissez-Faire”, The Economic Journal, Vol. 106, No. 436 (May, 1996), Pp. 679-687 Erkens, D., Hung, M., and Matos, P. 2009. ‘Corporate Governance in the 2007-2008 Financial Crisis: Evidence from Financial Institutions Worldwide’, ECGI Finance Working Paper, 249/2009 Farmer R., 2009a “Confidence, Crashes And Animal Spirits”, NBER Working Paper Series, ————, 2009b “Why Keynes Was Right And Wrong And Why It Matters”, Financial Times, May 27, 2009 Ferguson N., 2009. ‘A History Lesson For Economists In Thrall Of Keynes’, Financial Times, May 30, 2009 Fitoussi, J.-P. 2009 ‘The End of (Economic) History’, contained in Pecchi and Piga (2009), Ch. 11, pp. 151-60 Friedman H.H., and Friedman, L.W. 2009. ‘The Global Financial Crisis of 2008: What Went Wrong?’, Working paper, available at http://ssrn.com/abstract=1356193 González-Páramo, J.M. 2008 ‘Financial Turmoil, Securitisation And Liquidity’ , Speech By José Manuel González-Páramo Global ABS Conference 2008, Cannes, 1 June 2008 Geithner, T., (2008), ‘The Current Financial Challenges: Policy And Regulatory Implications?’ Testimony Of Timothy Geithner, President And Chief Executive Officer, Federal Resrve Bank Of New York Greenspan, A., 1998 ‘The Regulation Of OTC Derivatives’ Testimony Of Chairman Alan Greenspan Before The Committee On Banking And Financial Services, U.S. House Of Representatives, July 24, 1998 ————, 2008 Testimony Of Dr. Alan Greenspan Oversight And Reform, October 23, 2008 Before The Committee Of Government

Harrod F. R. 1972, The Life Of John Maynard Keynes, Macmillan, London Hein E., and Truger, A. 2010. ‘Finance-dominated Capitalism in Crisis – the Case for a Global Keynesian New Deal’, Institute for International Political Economy, WP 06/2010, Berlin Hoover K., 2006 ‘Doctor Keynes: Economic Theory In A Diagnostic Science’, Contained In R.E.Backhouse And B.W. Bateman (Eds.) The Cambridge Companion To Keynes, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge Kelly E.W. 1998 ‘Countdown To Y2K: An Economic Assessment’, Remarks By Governor Edward W. Kelley, Jr. At The Annual Economic Symposium At Houston Baptist University, October 29, 1998 16

Keynes J.M., 1925 ‘A Short View Of Russia’, London, Hogarth Press, Reproduced In Collected Writings vol. 9, Pp. 253-71 ————, 1926 The End Of Laissez-Faire, London, Hogarth Press, Reproduced In Collected Writings vol. 9, Pp. 272-94 ————, 1930 ‘Economic Possibilities For Our Grandchildren’, Nation And Athenaeum, 48, 11 And 18 October, 36-37, 96-8, Reproduced In Collected Writings vol. 9, Pp. 321-32 ————, 1931 ‘The Consequences To The Banks Of The Collapse Of Reproduced In Collected Writings Vol. IX, Pp. 168-78 Money Values’,

————, 1933. ‘National Self-Suffiency’, New Statesman And Nation, 8 July 1933, 36-7, 15 July, 65-7; Collected Writings Vol. 21, Pp. 233-46 ————, 1933. ‘Art And The State’, Lister, 26 August; Collected Writings Vol. 28, Pp. 341-49 ————, 1936 The General Theory Of Employment, Interest And Money, London, Macmillan ————, 1937 ‘The General Theory Of Employment’, Quarterly Journal Of Economics, Vol. 51, February, Pp. 209-23, Reproduced In Collected Writings Vol. XIV, Pp. 109-23 ————, 1938 ‘Letter to Harrod’, Reproduced In Collected Writings Vol. XIV, pp. 300 King, J.E. 2010 ‘Keynes and ‘Psychology’’, Economic Papers, vol. 29, pp. 1-12 Kirkpatrick, G. 2009 ‘The Corporate Governance Lessons from the Financial Crisis’, Financial Market Trends, OECD 2009 , Pre-publication version for Vol. 2009/1 Kregel, J. 2007. ‘The Natural Instability Of Financial Markets’, Levy Institute Working Paper Series, No. 523. Kristof, N. 2008, ‘Need a job? $17,000 an hour. No success required’. New York Times, September 18, OP-ED, A29. Krugman P., 2008. ‘Deficits And The Future’, The New York Times, December 1, 2008 ————, Books 2009 The Return of Depression Economics and the Crisis of 2008, New York, Penguin

Lau, J.Y.F and Smithin, J. 2002 “The Role of Money in Capitalism”, Internationa Journal of Political Economy, vol. 32, pp- 5-22 Leijonhufvud A., 2008 “Keynes And The Crisis” , CEPR Policy Insight No. 23, May ——————, 2009a ‘Keynes And The Crisis’, Cambridge Journal Of Economics, Vol. 33, 741756 ——————, 2009b “Two Systemic Problems” , CEPR Policy Insight No. 29, January

17

——————, 2009c “Spreading The Bread Thin On The Butter”, Contained In L. Pecchi, G. Piga (Eds.) Revisiting Keynes. Economic Possibilities For Our Grandchildren, Ch. 7, Pp. 127-34 Lo, A.W. 2008. ‘Hedge Funds, Systemic Risk, and the Financial Crisis of 2007–2008’ Written Testimony prepared for the U.S. House of Representatives Committee on Oversight and Government Reform November 13, 2008 Hearing on Hedge Funds Malkiel B.G., 2003 “The Efficient Market Hypothesis And Its Critics” , Ceps Discussion Paper No. 91, January Mason, P. 2009 Meltdown. The End of the Age of Greed, Verso, London Meltzer, A. 2009 Review ‘Revisting Keynes: economic Possibilities for Our Grandchildren’ , History of Political Economy, vol. 41, pp760-762 Minsky H. 1991 ‘Financial Crises: Systemic Or Idiosyncratic’, Levy Institute Working Paper Series, No. 51. Moggridge, D.E. 2005 ‘Keynes, the Arts, and the State’ , History of Political Economy, Duke University Press Morgenson, G. 2008. ‘Behind insurer’s crisis, blind eye to a web of risk’. New York Times, September 28 1, 28. Ohanian, L.E. 2009 ‘Back to the Future with Keynes’, in chi and Piga (2009), Ch. 6 pp. 105-15 Palma, G. 2009. ‘The revenge of the market on the rentiers: why neo-liberal reports of the end of the history turned out to be premature’, Cambridge Journal of Economics, vol. 33, no. 4, 581-608 Pecchi L., G. Piga 2009, Revisiting Keynes: Economic Possibilities For Our Grandchildren, New York, MIT Press, Princeton University Press Phelps, E.S. 2009 ‘Corporatism and Keynes: His Philosophy of Grwoth’, contained in Pecchi and Piga (2009), Ch. 5, pp. 95-104 Robinson, J. 2007. ‘Morality and economics’. Commencement Address. Retrieved July 9, 2007 from Economist’s View http://economistsview.typepad.com/economistsview/2007/07/morality-and-ec.html Rochon L.-P.., (2003) ‘Financial Instability Hypothesis’, Contained In J.E. King (Ed.) The Elgar Companion To Post Keynesian Economics, Edward Elgar, London Roncaglia, A. 2005 The Wealth of Ideas, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge Runde, J. 1994. “Keynesian Uncertainty And Liquidity Preference.” Cambridge Journal Of Economics 18(1): 129–44. Sharma, V. K. 2008 ‘Genesis, Diagnosis And Prognosis Of The Current Global Financial Crisis’ Address By Shri V K Sharma, Executive Director Of The Reserve Bank Of India, At The Senior Management Conference, Mumbai, 21 November 2008.

18

Skidelsky, R. 2008 “Keynes Is Back”, Prospect, October Sinclair, P., Spier, G. and Skinner, T. 2008 ‘Bonuses, Credit Rating Agencies and the Credit Crunch’, University of Michigan, Working Paper Steil, B. 2009 “Why Keynes Was Wrong And Why It Matters”, Financial Times, May 19, 2009 Story, L. 2008, ‘On Wall Street, bonuses, not profits, were real’. New York Times, December 18 A1, A35. Strömqvist, M. 2009. ‘Hedge funds and the financial crisis of 2008’, Sveriges Riksbank Economic Commentaries, no. 3, 2009 Taleb, N.N. 2009 ‘How bank bonuses let us all down’ , Financial Times, February 24, 2009 Truman E.M., 2009 Policy Responses To The Global Financial Crisis, Remarks Presented At The Ninth Annual International Seminar, On "Policy Challenges For The Financial Sector Emerging From The Crisis: Building A Stronger International Financial System," Board Of Governors Of The Federal Reserve System, World Bank, And International Monetary Fund June 3, 2009 UNCTAD 2009 The Global Economic Crisis: Systemic Failures And Multilateral Remedies, Report By The UNCTAD Secretariat Task Force On Systemic Issues And Economic Cooperation, United Nations Geneva Wray, L.R. 1992. “Alternative Theories Of The Rate Of Interest.” Cambridge Journal Of Economics 16(1): 69–89. _________ 2009a. ‘The rise and fall of money manager capitalism: a Minskian approach’, Cambridge Journal of Economics, vol. 33, no. 4, 581-608 _________ 2009b. ‘Money Manager Capitalism and the Global Financial Crisis’, Real World Economics Review, vol. 51, 1, 55-69 Wray, L.R., Tymoigne E., 2008. ‘Macroeconomics Meets Hyman P. Minsky: The Financial Theory Of Investment’, Levy Economics Institute, Working Paper No. 543

19

Similar Documents

Premium Essay

Keynesian

...Identify a period in history when any government in the world applied Keynesian economic methods in trying to stimulate their economy. (Do not use the Great Depression as an example). Address the following: 1. Identify and describe the Keynesian actions. Keynesian economics is centered around the premise that governments should play an active role in promoting economic policy and regulating the private sector.  Increased government spending and deficits will increase demand in the economy for more production, and that producers will increase supply to meet that demand, hiring more workers and reducing unemployment in the process. President Obama used a stimulus package of nearly $ 1 trillion using the rationale that it would cause the unemployment rate in America to drop to 5.8% and never exceed 8%. As of May of this year, the unemployment rate is at 8.2% and barely moving. The rate has exceeded 8% for 41 straight months as of May. Prior to the recession of 2008 unemployment had not measured over 8% in America since Dec. 1983. Not included in the 8.2% quoted unemployment rate is the estimated 7.2 million people who have given up looking for work or the 8.2 million underemployed workers (part time because they cannot find a full time job). If these two factors were included in the unemployment, it would be 22.8%. Unemployment rate: 8.2% Unemployed + underemployed: 14.9% Unemployed + underemployed + long-term discouraged workers: 22.8% In 2011, the economy...

Words: 357 - Pages: 2

Premium Essay

Keynesian Economics

...According to Forbes.com, Obama has taken our economy back to the discredited Keynesian economics. John Maynard Keynes believed that in order to stimulate the economy, government needed to spend more money and increase deficits, which would in turn rejuvenate the economy and increase production. One journalist writes, “Keynesian economics is the false vision of human action which says the way to promote economic recovery and renewed growth is through increased government spending, deficits and debt. If that sounds nuts, that’s because it is.” (Obamanomics: The Final Nail In the Discredited Keynesian Coffin, 2012) As we have seen, the yearly deficit in the United States is steadily increasing, and there has been no turn around in the deficit as predicted by Keynes. This shows that Keynes belief in restoring the government by increasing deficits has failed. “Keynesian economics arose in the 1930s in response to the Depression. It never worked then, as the recession of 1929 extended into the decade long Great Depression. And it never worked anywhere it’s been tried since then, in the U.S. or abroad.” (Obamanomics: The Final Nail In the Discredited Keynesian Coffin, 2012) The Keynesian beliefs have increased unemployment, raised inflation into the double digits, and greatly increased interest rates. According to Forbes, Obama is spending huge amounts of money, increasing the federal deficit, just as Keynes believed. “Obama’s first major act in office was to pursue the unreconstructed...

Words: 536 - Pages: 3

Premium Essay

Keynesian Economics

...KEYNESIAN ECONOMICS: Preamble:: As early as 1848, Karl Marx indicated the inherent weakness of uncontrolled capitalist system guided by ruthless exploitation of labour. In the then prevailing ‘Mercantilist’ system combined with the ‘Gold Standard’, country’s wealth and power was dependent on export surplus. Export prices had to be kept low by low wages. Marx argued that creating supply while not creating purchasing power would lead to creation of ‘surplus value’. Economies would experience excess production, stock piling, down turn and periodic unemployment. Over time, the down turn would get worse. For labour, having a job or being unemployed made little difference. Marx believed that periodic recession and crisis of capitalism would lead to the self destruction of the system and its eventual downfall. He called on labour to revolt. ‘You have nothing to lose but your chains’ he said. His clarion call was ‘workers of the world unite’. It is an irony of history that Marx, a great philosopher, proved to be poor prophet, precisely because of his own advocacy. Had Marx not said what he did say, his prophecies would have come true. His ideas resulted in significant system reforms in Britain. Publication of Marx’s Communist Manifesto in 1948 put the British society and polity on guard. In 1850s British Parliament enacted a number of laws aimed at labour reforms. Trade Unions were recognized. Minimum wages were instituted. Limitations were prescribed on hours of work,...

Words: 3780 - Pages: 16

Free Essay

Keynesian Theory

...Hannah Grace S. Bielza AC-301 The Keynesian Theory * In the depression of the 1930s democratic nations were concerned about the problem of inflation. Wherein, general level of prices for goods and services is rising and, consequently, the purchasing power of currency is falling. * Because of inflation, workers are unwilling to accept further cuts in their wages for the reason that their earnings were already cut down by unemployment and part-time work. It is really hard to work, earning a small amount of money while having a huge amount of expenses that’s why a lot of workers don’t want to cut their wages. * Explanation of wages and wage changes in this kind of setting inevitably directed attention to general wage levels rather than to wage rates in the labor markets. This means that the employers focus on this average wage paid to employees rather than the rate per hour or based on production. * John Maynard Keynes advanced his full employment theory by publishing “General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money” in 1936 which provides basic analysis on which the theory is based. * To many theorists in the classical tradition, Adam Smith’s, “Wealth of the Nations” provided rationalization for policies they thought necessary but could not embrace with clear conscience. There’s no scholarly document to prove that this will fit more closely to the needs of the times. Keyne’s Theory on Employment * Keynes admitted that the Classical and Neo classical...

Words: 873 - Pages: 4

Premium Essay

Keynesian Economics

...Keynesian Economics, Helping the US Economy Keynesian philosophy states that in order to manage economic downturns, government intervention in the economy is imperative. It was Keynesian Economic Philosophy that kept America out of another depression during the Great Recession due to the fiscal and monetary stimulus (Seidman 32-53, 22p). By examining the government’s need for spending money on welfare, cutting taxes, regulating and monitoring the financial markets, and government spending on military, America sees how a Keynesian approach is a necessity. The American Government needs to continue using the Keynesian model in order to enhance the performance of the economy. Keynesian Philosophy provides government assisted programs to those who qualify. One form of assistance is Welfare. Welfare provides benefits and economic assistance to low or no income Americans. With the dismal economy, there are now over 100 million people on welfare according to the Census Bureau; and this doesn’t include those receiving Social Security or Medicare (GOPUSAStaff). Food Stamps are one of many divisions of welfare. The food stamps program, also known as the Supplementary Nutrition Assistance Program (SNAP), helps low or no income citizens buy food. There are over 46 million people on SNAP as of June, 2012 (Luhby). That is more than one in seven Americans and more than 25% of eligible Americans do not participate in the food stamps program. There are millions of low-income seniors struggling...

Words: 2071 - Pages: 9

Premium Essay

Keynesian Economics

...Who was Keynes and what were his ideas? John Maynard Keynes, born in 1883, is considered to be one of the most influential economists of the 20th century. He was most prominent during the Great Depression in the 1930s when he tried to create an economical revolution in economic thinking with his ideas of intervention in markets. The idea is also generally; that in the short run productive activity is very much influenced by aggregate demand, (aggregate demand is the total spending in the economy with the equation; Consumption + Investment + Government Expenditure + (Exports - Imports)) and that aggregate demand does not equal the productive capacity of the economy. Keynes believed strongly that Government Intervention would strongly help the economy to succeed and grow. His three main argument points concerning the Government were : The Government has a role to play in moderating the business cycle. Government can use short term monetary policy to engineer the economy. During economic hardship the government should spend to try and 'spur' on economic growth. In the second point I mentioned monetary policy, but what is it? It involves changes in the base rate of interest to influence the growth of aggregate demand, the money supply and price inflation. A short goal would be set for the economy to achieve this by changing the base rate. If the economy is doing well, the government should stop spending money, or spend less, but if the economy is bombing, the government...

Words: 1112 - Pages: 5

Free Essay

Keynesian Economics

...governments to come in and make markets work better... Keynes saved capitalism from the capitalists.” - Prof. Joseph Stiglitz Keynes’ theory opposed Adam Smith’s metaphor of “the invisible hand” – which envisages a self-correcting economy, in the form of the self-regulating behaviour of the market - due to individuals' efforts to maximize their own gains in a free market which benefits society, even if original ambitions include no benevolent intentions. Instead Keynes said that capitalism doesn’t always work on its own accord, but that government intervention is sometimes necessary (especially during periods of recession – which Keynesians see as an “economic malady” rather than a normal part of the business/trade cycle. Keynesian theory in modern macro-economics Alistair Darling MP, Chancellor of the Exchequer, 2007-2010 – “The dominant thinking in Europe at the moment is exactly repeating the mistakes (I believe) that were made at the end of the First World War”. This statement was made in reference to the fact that Germany is now imposing the idea of tough budget cuts in Greece in exchange for emergency loans. Darling compares this action to the forced pay of reparations by Germany, imposed by the Allies after WWI in the Treaty of Versailles. The fact that the debtor country has such a weak economy defies the possibility of making such large repayments. In order to repay...

Words: 1016 - Pages: 5

Free Essay

Keynesian Theory

...Why were Keynesian ideas revolutionary? The Great depression started from October 29, 1929 when the stock market crash and ended in early 1940s. It started with severe economic collapse rooted by over-extended and over-confident stock market. The most severe country that was affected was US and other countries are mildly affected. The government intervened directly and increased the productivity essential for the World War II to end the Great Depression. Classical Theory is based on free market concept therefore it requires minimum or zero government intervention. Individuals can decide depending on their own interest and this lets them manage the economic resources based on their interest. Classical Theory believes that consumer spending and business investment is a larger portion as compared to government expenditure plus the higher the government expenditure, it will reduce the private sector economic growth. Classical Theory believes the economy will get corrected by itself in the theory of invisible hand. Keynes theory is based on the aggregate demand which is influenced by the public and private sector. It is influenced and affected by fiscal policies which are changes in government expenditure and tax. Keynes believes prices are rigid which will only cause output to fluctuate when there are changes in consumption, investment and government expenditure. Even if consumer spending or business investment is absent, government expenditure...

Words: 515 - Pages: 3

Premium Essay

Abuse of Keynesian Economics

...| The Abuse of Keynes’ Theory of Government Spending | And Why Government Spending Needs to Stop | | Chase Cooper | 12/13/2012 | Political Economy Dr.Ramos Abstract: The goal of my research paper is to analyze and present how John Maynard Keynes’ theory on government spending is being abused by the American government insofar that the American government is not following the guidelines and foundations that premised Keynes’ theory, and instead are picking the parts of the theory that allow them to spend at unsustainable levels, creating problems that, one way or another, eventually have to be resolved. My research will prove how the American government is conducting fiscal policy in a way that abuses Keynes’ theory on government spending, and, as a result, why Keynes would not support the American government in their spending endeavors, despite using his theory as their justification. I will be critiquing the application of Keynes’ theory from the Austrian, specifically the works of Friedrich A. Hayek, and Monetarist perspectives, supported by arguments given by Milton Friedman. Section 1: Keynes’ Theory on Government Spending John Maynard Keynes published his famous work, The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, in 1936, during the Great Depression. Economies all over the world were suffering severely from the Great Depression, and there was little hope of economic recovery in the near future. Keynes agreed with the classical economist’s notion...

Words: 5554 - Pages: 23

Premium Essay

Classical vs Keynesian

...their own self-interest regarding economic decisions. This ensures economic resources are allocated according to the desires of individuals and businesses in the marketplace. Classical economics uses the value theory to determine prices in the economic market. An item’s value is determined based on production output, technology and wages paid to produce the item. Classical economics focuses on creating long-term solutions for economic problems. The effects of inflation, government regulation and taxes can all play an important part in developing classical economic theories. Classical economists also take into account the effects of other current policies and how new economic theory will improve or distort the free market environment. Keynesian Economics Assumptions Rigid or Inflexible Prices: While a wage hike is easier to take, wage falls hit some resistance. Likewise, while for a producer, commodity prices are easily upwardly...

Words: 581 - Pages: 3

Premium Essay

Keynesian Model Perceptives

...Keynesian and Classical Model Perspectives “The Keynesian perspective emphasizes the importance of aggregate demand (spending by consumers, business, and government) and considers government fiscal policy (spending and taxing) to be the major factor in maintaining a vibrant economy. Keynesians believe changes in total spending have their greatest short-term impact on real output and not prices.” Keynesian economics was practiced in the early 60’s it emphasized financial growth through taxation. “First, the levels of national income and employment depend on aggregate demand rather than on the capacity to supply output or the desire to work. Second, a high level of saving can therefore reduce national income. Third, an increase in government spending can raise national income and return the economy to full employment.” “Today these ideas are regarded as relevant only to some short-run situations and not to the basic long-term goals facing economic policy. Fluctuations in aggregate demand influence short-run cyclical movements of output and employment but the sustained rate of economic growth reflects the accumulation of capital, the supply of labor, and the advance of technology. A rise in the level of saving can reduce aggregate activity temporarily but only a sustained high level of saving makes it possible to have the sustained high level of business investment that contributes to the long-run growth of output. Increased government spending can provide a temporary stimulus...

Words: 440 - Pages: 2

Premium Essay

Keynesian and Monetary Policy

...1) Monetary policy is the manipulation of the money supply with the objective of affecting macroeconomic outcomes such as GDP growth, inflation, unemployment, and exchange rates. Monetary policy in the United States is conducted by the Federal Reserve, in particular, by the FOMC. Keynesian monetary policy focus on how changes in the money supply affect interest rates and investment spending. In turn, aggregate demand shifts and affects prices, real GDP, and employment. The Keynesian view of the monetary policy transmission mechanism operates as follows: First, the Fed uses its policy tools to change the money supply. Second, changes in the money supply change the equilibrium interest rate, which affects investment spending. Finally, a change in the investment changes aggregate demand and determines the level of prices, real GDP, and employment. Since the 1950s, a new view of monetary policy, called monetarism, has emerged that disputes the Keynesian view that monetary policy is relatively ineffective. Monetarism is the simpler view that changes in monetary policy directly change aggregate demand, and thereby prices, real GDP, and employment. Thus, monetarists focus on the money supply, rather than on the rate of interest. 2) Monetarism is the prevailed economic theory per 2008. This theory dominated in the 20 year period leading up to the 2008 economic crisis. Monetarism argues that the markets are self-correcting and self-regulated. It believes that capital market naturally...

Words: 494 - Pages: 2

Premium Essay

Macroeconomics: Classical or Keynesian

...Which is better: Classical or Keynesian? And which one most embraces the idea of liberty? Classical framework does embrace the idea of liberty and freedom more. The classical framework is based on laissez faire principles, which opposes any government regulation of the economy. However, Team B believes that the Keynesian theory is better for the economy overall. Limited government involvement can influence the economy positively. For example, government involvement can help improve the economy in a recession. In a recession, spending benefits the economy. If the government spends or influences individuals to spend, it can help improve the economy and limit the negative effects of the recession. The government can help the economy reach its potential income as well. The potential income of an economy is the level of income that an economy is potentially able to produce without increasing inflation (Colander, 2010). Economies might not be able to reach their potential income without any government interference. Using recessions as an example the forces of the market may not be powerful enough to restore the economy. The economy would suffer from a changing equilibrium income. The equilibrium income is defined as the income level the economy moves towards because of the cycles of declining or increasing production (Colander, 2010). These fluctuations from the recession would alter the equilibrium income negatively and pull the economy further away from reaching its...

Words: 269 - Pages: 2

Free Essay

Keynesian Economic Theory

...Virtual Economy Home page Keynesians - Introduction Keynesian economists are, not surprisingly, so named because they are advocates of the work of John Maynard Keynes (if only all economics was that easy!). Much of his work took place at the time of the Great Depression in the 1930s, and perhaps his best known work was the 'General Theory of Employment, Interest & Money' which was published in 1936. In this section we look more generally at the work of Keynesian economists. Follow the links below or at the foot of the page to find out more detail about what they believed in and the policies they proposed. * Beliefs * Theories * AS & AD * Policies * Virtual Economy policies Keynesians - Beliefs Keynes didn't agree with the Classical economists!! In fact the easiest way to look at Keynesian theory is to see the arguments he gave for Classical theory being wrong. In essence Keynes argued that markets would not automatically lead to full-employment equilibrium, but in fact the economy could settle in equilibrium at any level of unemployment. This meant that Classical policies of non-intervention would not work. The economy would need prodding if it was to head in the right direction, and this meant active intervention by the government to manage the level of demand. Follow the links in the navigation bar at the foot of the page or in the side panel to find out more detail on the sort of policies this may involve. Keynesian beliefs can be illustrated...

Words: 1124 - Pages: 5

Premium Essay

Keynesian Approach to Stabilisation

...14. The Keynesian Approach to Stabilization Economists of the nineteenth century did not have our concept of government. They did not consider government’s role in stabilizing the economy. No matter, for the classical view was that prices and wages would automatically adjust to provide full employment and maximum output. If there were a recession, it would be the fault of suppliers providing goods that people did not want. Prices would fall, and suppliers would smarten up. Meanwhile, any unemployment would cause wages to be bid down.. The lower wages would make hiring look attractive, and the unemployed would be re-hired. Yes, if employers reduce their demand for labour, the wage will drop. This however will not change the fact that fewer people are employed than before. More people are hired than if demand had dropped and the wage had not responded, but the fact is, not as many people are hired as before. The labour market does not completely self-correct as wishfully assumed in Figure 14-1. It will not completely correct until labour demand rises back to its original level; this will happen when whatever caused the reduced labour demand is resolved. Figure 14-1. Classical View: Market Self-Correction. Note: It is useful to think of classical economists as assuming that Aggregate Demand is perfectly flexible or elastic. Consequently, only supply drives the economy. As we shall see below, Keynes makes the opposite assumption. Keynes’ reaction to the...

Words: 3086 - Pages: 13