Free Essay

Rationality, Norms and Identity in Ir

In: Social Issues

Submitted By Samolyakkatya
Words 8767
Pages 36
Original Article

Rationality, norms and identity in international relations Ji Young Choi
Department of Politics & Government, Ohio Wesleyan University, Elliott Hall 204, Delaware,
OH 43015, USA.
E-mail: jychoi@owu.edu

Abstract This article examines major debates between rationalism and constructivism.
It presents that there are politically significant motives of social actions, including norms and identity, which cannot be completely subsumed by the concept of instrumental rationality. These ideational or social-psychological motivations are governed primarily by thymos or affect (the moral or emotional part of the human personality) and/or valueoriented rationality. We need more flexible assumptions about main actors and their motives than those of rationalism to explain appropriately the politics of anger, loyalty and a sense of justice at international levels. However, constructivism’s emphasis on ideational motivations cannot totally replace rationalism in explaining international political life. Constructivism maintains that identity or norms are causally prior to actors’ interests. Yet when there is conflict between pursuit of interests and maintenance of identity or norms, actors’ strong and well-defined self-interests can overrule their contested or unstable identity or norms. In short, causal arrows can flow in either direction between identity or norms and interests. This implies that rationalism and constructivism are complementary rather than competitive in explaining international political life.
International Politics (2015) 52, 110–127. doi:10.1057/ip.2014.41
Keywords: rationalism; constructivism; rationality; norms; identity; international relations theory

Introduction
Since the 1990s, one of the major debates in International Relations (IR) scholarship has been between rationalism and constructivism (Katzenstein et al, 1998; Fearon and Wendt, 2002). How to define the relationship between rationality and norms or identity has been one of the main issues in this debate. Rationalists tend to subsume norms and identity under the concept of instrumental rationality. This article maintains that ideational or social-psychological motivations such as norms and identity cannot be fully explained by instrumental rationality. My argument is that
© 2015 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1384-5748 International Politics www.palgrave-journals.com/ip/ Vol. 52, 1, 110–127

Rationality, norms and identity

the politically significant motives of social actions are broader and more diverse than most rationalists allow for. But I also argue that constructivism cannot totally replace rationalism in explaining international political life because solid and well-defined self-interests formed by cost–benefit analysis can lead actors to forsake their normative values and identities. The essay is composed of three sections. In the first section, I explore the major differences between rationalism and constructivism, and define instrumental rationality, identity and norms. In the second, concepts like thymos, affect and value-oriented rationality are introduced, and I discuss some limits or problems of rationalism, particularly the concept of instrumental rationality, in the study of IR. Finally, I try to classify social behavior into three ideal-type categories
(self-interest-driven behavior, norm/identity-driven behavior and the combination or conflict between the two), and show that causal arrows can flow in either direction between identity or norms and self-interests. In the conclusion, I summarize the main arguments, stressing that we have to make a greater effort to strike a balance between theoretical ‘parsimony’ and the ‘complexity’ of social actions to improve the political relevance of IR theory.

Rationalism and Constructivism
Rationality has long been one of the main concepts in the study of IR. Major traditional theoretical approaches in IR such as realism and liberalism – approaches that fall within the rationalist tradition – assume that actors (whether they are states or non-state actors) are by and large rational in the sense that they seek to advance their preferences in such a way so as to maximize their interests (Keohane, 1988;
Katzenstein et al, 1998). More specifically, rationality means that an actor orders one’s interests or preferences and makes the choice that ranks in highest in the order in a given situation. In IR contexts, rationalism can be defined as ‘formal and informal applications of rational choice theory to IR questions’ or any work developed in ‘the tradition of microeconomic theory’ (Fearon and Wendt, 2002,
p. 54). Indeed, the behavioral revolution in the 1960s and the incorporation of economic methods into IR theories in the late 1970s and 1980s were closely related to the increasing influence of rationality in the discipline of IR (Finnemore and
Sikkink, 1998, pp. 889–890).
However, the deeper root of rationalism lies in the onset of ‘modernity’ in the
West. The seventeenth century French philosopher Descartes captured the idea of modernity very well. The central axis of his philosophy (and modernity) was a rational or thinking ego: Cogito ergo sum (I think, therefore I am). Modernity was basically an ‘individualist project’ as the rational or thinking ego became the ‘sole protagonist’ of the world and its history (Guzzini, 2000, p. 151). It is therefore understandable that rationalism is predicated upon methodological individualism, according to which an individual actor is ontologically primitive and ‘all social
© 2015 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1384-5748

International Politics

Vol. 52, 1, 110–127

111

Choi

phenomena (their structure and their change) are in principle explicable only in terms of individuals’ (Elster, 1982, p. 453). Modernity has also developed in the West mainly due to the modern scientific revolution. According to the modern scientific world view, the universe is in essence physical or material, that is, ‘the order of this universe is natural, accessible to reason and observation, and describable in impersonal, materialistic, mechanical, and mathematical terms’ (Thiele, 1997,
p. 68). Thus, modern scientific endeavors study observable repeated phenomena in nature and seek to establish governing laws that can be applied regardless of temporal and spatial differences. Since the eighteenth century, many social thinkers have tried to apply this outlook derived from the natural world to the study of the social
(human) condition. For instance, Condorcet argued for the ‘Law of Progress’ and predicted an irreversible social progress to perfectibility through the application of mathematics and physics to the study of social phenomena (Thiele, 1997, p. 72).
Rationalists like Condorcet were in general insensitive to cultural and historical difference in the study of social phenomena. It is also worth noting that modern thinkers – Hobbes and Locke in particular – saw rationality in instrumental terms.
They were concerned about how to preserve the physical body and how to protect one’s private property. In their view, (human) rationality or reason is an instrument of achieving one’s ends, defined mainly in terms of material self-interests such as personal safety and security of possessions (Fukuyama, 1992, pp. 158–159; Lebow,
2008, p. 45).
Influenced by this tradition, major mainstream IR theories have emphasized the central role of instrumental rationality in international life. Kahler (1998, p. 920) sees that realism opposes ‘the image of a unified and rational self’ and depicts the relationship between realism and rationalism as mutually contradictory. This is, however, a misrepresentation of realism. It is true that realists reject the optimistic view of modernity that human history has progressed and will progress by the application of human reason and the natural sciences. However, this does not mean that realists deny the rationality of actors in their analysis of interstate relations. A classical realist, Morgenthau (1948 [1973], pp. 4–5, 8), for example, makes clear that realism seeks to develop a rational theory that reflects ‘the rational elements of political reality’. Morgenthau even attempted to advance a rationalist theory of international politics by suggesting that there are universal laws in international politics, the most fundamental being that states will always seek to maximize their interests, which are defined as power. He sees that a rational foreign policy is what most political leaders do and should do.
Kenneth Waltz, a neo-realist, might be viewed as being less of rationalist than
Morgenthau because of his structuralist bent (Kahler, 1998, pp. 924–925). However,
Waltz’s theory is a modified version of rationalism for two main reasons. First, the fundamental ontology of neo-realism is individualistic because it views the structure of an international system as varying according to changes in the distribution of (military and economic) capabilities of ‘individual’ actors (states) (Waltz, 1979, p. 91, 97;
112

© 2015 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1384-5748

International Politics

Vol. 52, 1, 110–127

Rationality, norms and identity

see also Wendt, 1987; Dessler, 1989). Second, Waltz (1979, p. 91) likens the state to an individual or a firm in a market. In his words, ‘(i)nternational-political systems, like economic markets, are formed by the coaction of self-regarding units’. This means that within some structural constraints, which can be called the ‘opportunity set’, the state behaves by and large rationally because there are costs or penalties if it does not
(Waltz, 1979, pp. 91–93). Other neo-realists such as Grieco (1988) and Mearsheimer
(2001) also adopt the view that states are rational actors and behave according to their self-interests because states have a keen interest for their survival and relative (military/ economic) gains in a self-help world.
Though liberals may disagree with realists in some respects, they too look at interstate relations within a rationalist framework. Neo-liberalism or neo-liberal institutionalism in particular adopts more utilitarian assumptions than traditional liberal theories, drawing on microeconomic theory to explain state behavior
(Axelrod, 1984; Keohane, 1984). To this degree, both neo-realism and neo-liberalism share the view that the state, as the primary actor on the international scene, is a largely rational egoistic entity. Whereas neo-liberals see that interstate cooperation is possible because international institutions can mitigate the effects of anarchy considerably, neo-realists are skeptical about this view. Even though the two sides suggest different explanations of state behavior in an anarchical interstate system, their debate in the end led to ‘a period of considerable unity in the discipline’ (Smith,
1997, p. 170; see also Wendt, 1992, pp. 391–392). Although there were exceptions or modifications (for example, Walt, 1987), instrumental rationality based on utilitarian assumptions was the core concept of neo-realism and neo-liberalism.
All this changed in the late 1980s when the cataclysmic change in world politics associated with the end of the Cold War led to the rise of cultural or sociological approaches to IR, broadly labeled ‘constructivism’ (Katzenstein, 1996; Checkel,
1998; Hopf, 1998; Katzenstein et al, 1998).1 During the Cold War era, many states’ identities had been relatively stable. But after the breakdown of a stable bipolar order in the late 1980s, state or national identity became more complicated in many parts of the world (Katzenstein, 1996, pp. 18–19). In addition, the post-Cold War world witnessed a renewed emphasis on a complex array of international norms such as human rights, democracy and environmentalism. Taken together, these changes led a new generation of constructivists to stress the significance of socially constructed norms – norms that had not been not been addressed in depth by rationalists. As
Finnemore (1996, p. 2) put it, ‘interests are not just out there waiting to be discovered; they are constructed through social interaction’. Indeed, according to constructivism, material or raw facts are only given meaning through the process of social interactions and practices in an inter-subjective social context; actors’ interests are thus not just a given but ‘social cognitive products’ (see also Checkel, 1998,
p. 326; Guzzini, 2000, p. 160; Hopf, 2002, p. 17). Constructivism in this sense adopted an ideational or social-psychological approach to international phenomena rather than a materialistic or behavioral–individualistic one. Indeed, in the view of
© 2015 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1384-5748

International Politics

Vol. 52, 1, 110–127

113

Choi

constructivists, rationalism’s actors are too atomistic and materialistic; rationalists, they believe, do not give enough attention to social and ideational relations in shaping or changing actors’ interests.
This may of course be unfair to rationalists. After all, many rationalists do not exclude the role of ideational factors and the socialization of actors in their analysis of international affairs. For example, neo-liberal institutionalists accept that ideas and beliefs can play a crucial role in the political decision-making processes (Axelrod and
Keohane, 1993; Keohane, 2000). Realists too admit that ideas, norms and perceptions play a certain role in the international system (Jervis, 1976; Walt, 1987). Waltz, no less, points to the fact that norms in the international system emerge spontaneously by repeated interactions among states through which they experience a form of socialization. In his view, in order to survive in the anarchical international system, states tend to emulate or copy other successful states. These (informal) norms about how to behave in this system make the functions and attributes of states similar in spite of their different capabilities (Waltz, 1979, pp. 74–76, 97–98). However, from the perspective of constructivists the rationalists’ ideas or norms are too ‘thin’; their actors remaining largely ‘undersocialized’. Thus, even though rationalists might believe that ideas and norms can constrain or influence the states’ behaviors, in the end their interests and identities are nearly fixed. Indeed, for them, ideational factors are intervening rather than independent variables; they are ‘secondary’ or ‘derivative’ factors in their analysis of interstate relations (Checkel, 1998, p. 327; Wendt, 1999, p. 23).
For constructivists, on the other hand, ideational or social-psychological factors are significant independent variables. In particular, identity and norm(s) are two central concepts for their critique of rationalism. Identity is defined as ‘role-specific understandings … about self’ in relation to others and is conceived of as forming the basis of actors’ interests, as actors identify their interests in the process of defining their social roles and situations (Wendt, 1992, pp. 397–398; see also Hopf, 2002, pp. 16–18). National or state identity refers to a common understanding of a collective self and it has to do with rules about the membership of a nation or state and common political goals and purposes (Abdellal et al, 2009). Importantly, historical narratives based on ‘collective memory’ strengthen people’s national identity because they provide meaning, purpose and self-worth (see also Hymans,
2006, pp. 27–28; Lebow, 2008, p. 16). Emotions like ‘we-feelings’ bind together members of a group, and a group identity is related to our psychological needs, which cannot be fully explained by material incentives or disincentives alone (Mercer,
2005, pp. 96–97; Sasley, 2011, pp. 455–459).2 Identity is also related to how a nation defines ‘threats’ as well as ‘interests’, and such definitions of a national identity have considerable effects on national security policies (Katzenstein, 1996, p. 19). Thus, national or state identity normally develops in relation to the identification of its enemies or rivals and how to overcome the (perceived) threat that they pose.
Norms have long been an interest in the study of IR. However, along with the behavioral revolution and the incorporation of microeconomic methods into IR,
114

© 2015 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1384-5748

International Politics

Vol. 52, 1, 110–127

Rationality, norms and identity

norms became marginalized in the study of world affairs. Norms are defined as
‘collective expectations (or understandings) for the proper behavior of actors with a given identity’ (Katzenstein, 1996, p. 5; see also Hurrell, 2002, p. 143). Like identities, norms emerge through social interactions and are related to shared expectations about how one should behave in a specific situation. Norms are also related to legitimacy, defined as the ‘normative belief’ that norms, rules and institutions should be obeyed. Hurd (1999) maintains that there are three ideal-type mechanisms of social control (coercion, self-interest and legitimacy) and points out that rationalist IR theories have tended to play down the role of legitimacy in international politics. Legro (1997) demonstrates that even in a very difficult period for international norms, the two decades leading to World War II, not all international norms were ineffective. Even in a total war, states did not use particular forms of military power, in part because of international prohibitions of certain kinds of warfare. Constructivists hold that norms constitute as well as regulate states
(Katzenstein, 1996, pp. 5, 17). Norms not only constrain or influence actors’ behaviors, but can also redefine their interests and identities as well. For example, before the mid-1980s, the United States prioritized strategic and economic interests in relation to apartheid South Africa. But transnational anti-apartheid activists were able to promote ‘a global norm of racial equality’; this in turn ‘reconstituted’ US national interests and changed its policies toward South Africa (Klotz, 1995). Indeed, this particular case study shows that the changing normative structure of the international system – as much as the distribution of material capabilities – is required to explain patterns of international interactions.

The Limits of the Concept of Instrumental Rationality in IR
In response to the critique of constructivism, some rationalists have come to recognize the limits of their own approach. They admit that actors’ rationality is
‘bounded’ because of imperfect information and that actors can miscalculate the costs and benefits of courses of action, especially when they have to make decisions with limited information under time pressure (Mearsheimer, 2001, p. 38; Glaser,
2010, pp. 2–3). Some writers have also striven to explicate ideational or socialpsychological motives such as norms, ideas and identities by expanding their conceptual scope. For instance, norms are here viewed as one type of an actor’s interests or preferences, which means that the utility (interests or preferences), which the actor seeks, can be ideational or normative as well as materialistic or selfregarding (Yee, 1997, pp. 1016–1017; Chong, 2000; see also Snidal, 2002, p. 75). In spite of these efforts, the basic logic of instrumental rationality – the conscious calculation to maximize one’s preferences – remains the same.
However, it is somewhat empty to argue that any social action is driven by instrumental rationality, that is, the conscious means–ends or cost–benefit calculation
© 2015 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1384-5748

International Politics

Vol. 52, 1, 110–127

115

Choi

to maximize one’s utility. A theory or theoretical paradigm focuses on certain important aspects of the reality and leaves out others. There are always certain areas that are not covered by the theory. Then, if it tries or pretends to explain everything, it accounts for nothing (Snidal, 2002, p. 87). Instrumental rationality is a very useful analytical concept for explaining certain important motivations of social actions, but it is legitimate to assume that there are certain motives of social actions that are not covered by the concept of instrumental rationality alone. In some cases, social behaviors are driven primarily by strong ideological, moral or emotional motivations that are not explained satisfactorily by the concept of the simple means–ends or cost– benefit calculation. That is why social actors do not behave in the same way in the same or similar situation and many unexpected (from the standpoint of instrumental rationality) social actions and outcomes are produced. Such behaviors might be nonrational in view of instrumental rationality, but they are not necessarily irrational from the standpoint of actors. This implies that rationalism’s assumption about social actors’ motives is too narrow and it has limits in explaining their behaviors appropriately in certain (potentially) important cases.
In fact, several influential Western philosophers and thinkers have addressed this non-rational aspect of human motivations and behaviors, although their thoughts have not been widely accepted and used by rationalists. According to Plato, for instance, a human being has three parts of the soul: reason, desire and thymos.
Thymos, a Greek word, can be translated into ‘spiritedness’, ‘self-esteem’ or a ‘sense of justice’. It is related to the moral or emotional aspect of the human personality and can arouse emotions of anger, shame or humiliation, and pride (Fukuyama, 1992, pp. xvi–xvii; Lebow, 2008, pp. 14–19). Weber also called to attention to social motivations like ‘affect’ and ‘habit’ that are not governed by conscious calculation or deliberation (Hopf, 2010, pp. 540–541). The Weberian concept of affect that emphasizes the role of emotions or feelings in social actions is very similar to
Plato’s thymos. As well, Hegel emphasizes that human beings differ fundamentally from animals because we desire to be recognized by other humans as a being with a certain dignity. In Hegel’s view, a human is not merely an economic or material animal and human history is characterized by ‘the struggle for recognition’, that is, the struggle for prestige, status and dignity. Indeed, only humans are able to overcome their basic biological needs (for example, self-preservation) for some abstract principles such as ideology and religion (Fukuyama, 1992, pp. xix–xxi,
143–152). That is why sometimes they can sacrifice their self-interests for their ideologies, cultural or ethnic loyalties, or religious beliefs. Humans are also different from other animals because they have concerns about others’ dignity or worth. They have compassion for others and feel anger when other humans’ dignity is seriously damaged (Fukuyama, 1992, pp. 171–172). Modern (especially Anglo–Saxon) thinkers (and rationalists today), however, have focused on the instrumental aspect of reason along with desire and have neglected the thymotic part of motives in explaining social actions.
116

© 2015 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1384-5748

International Politics

Vol. 52, 1, 110–127

Rationality, norms and identity

Thymos has both bright and dark sides. On the one hand, it can promote political behaviors based on bravery and justice. On the other, it can encourage intense
(sometimes meaningless) competition and bloody conflicts for status and recognition
(Fukuyama, 1992, p. 181). Thus, thymos can lead to pro-democracy uprisings, human rights movements and global justice movements in which many people sacrifice their material comfort and possession and risk even their lives for a certain cause. At the same time, however, it can lead to bloody battles among national, ethnic or religious groups because of their different loyalties, ideologies and faiths. For example, after the end of the Cold War, we have witnessed the proliferation of ethnic conflicts, the reemergence of religious fundamentalism, the spread of international terrorism, and the redefinition of national or local cultures as backlashes against globalization. We have also observed the increasingly important role of norms entrepreneurs and NGOs in world politics that have led various global social movements (Finnemore and Sikkink, 1998; Keck and Sikkink, 1998).
Some rationalists admit that there are certain social phenomena that instrumental rationality cannot explain appropriately, but they believe that their explanations function as a ‘rational baseline’ against which actors’ behaviors driven by nonrational (normative or psychological) motivations can be evaluated (Glaser, 2010,
p. 3; Snidal, 2002, p. 75). This implies that actors’ behaviors that do not follow this baseline are ‘mistakes’ in calculation or ‘deviations’ from the normal patterning of human actions (Mercer, 2005, pp. 87–89). However, as Weber pointed out, instrumental rationality (Zweckrationalität) is just one type of rationality. There is also value or value-oriented rationality (Wertrationalität) that leads to reasoned moral social behaviors (along with thymos or affect) and these cannot be classified as mere mistakes or deviations (Hopf, 2010, p. 540). Instrumental rationality concerns actors’ capacity for means–ends calculations, whereas value-oriented rationality is related to our ‘reasoned judgments about the value of ends themselves’ (Lichbach,
1997, p. 268).
Indeed, some phenomena that instrumental rationality has difficulty explaining can have great political significance in the international arena. For example, 9/11, which is a watershed moment in contemporary world politics, cannot be explained properly by (neo-)realism and (neo-)liberalism, which assume that social actors are rational egoistic entities. Territorial conquest and material gains are not ends that terrorists who carried out 9/11 pursued, and it is far-fetched to argue that a utilitymaximization strategy based on cost–benefit calculations played a central role in driving their behavior. Without considering their religious faith and identity (Islamic fundamentalism), and the emotions of resentment and frustration that are related to their faith and identity, there is no way to give an appropriate explanation of their motive and behavior (Zakaria, 2001). Interestingly enough, a violent American response to 9/11 (the War on Terror), which was not viewed (by at least some thirdparty observers) as very rational in instrumental terms, was also related to American people’s experience of humiliation that degraded their collective self-respect
© 2015 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1384-5748

International Politics

Vol. 52, 1, 110–127

117

Choi

(Saurette, 2006). Global social movements (for example, international human rights movements including the anti-apartheid movement) have relevance as well. As
Finnemore and Sikkink (1998, p. 888) put, successful norm entrepreneurs or NGOs’ leaders are usually strategic thinkers, but they have a strong commitment to specific norms or values and their thymotic anger over injustice play a crucial role in spreading their norms and changing state policies. A more recent example is the Arab
Spring that toppled authoritarian regimes in Tunisia, Egypt, Libya and Yemen.
Widespread (thymotic) anger among citizens in those countries over economic and political injustice (for example, endemic poverty, lack of economic opportunities, corruption, political oppression and so on) was the root cause of the popular uprisings
(Sassoon, 2012).
We can apply this discussion to the rise of China as well, a nation that is causing a sea change in world politics. Whether China has the intention as well as the capacity to become a global hegemon is a hotly debated issue today in the study of
IR. To address this issue, it must be understood that China’s national identity has been shaped by the ‘Century of Humiliation’. A national identity is shaped by narratives about the past, particularly about historical interactions with other nations.
Such narratives are also related to a nation’s self-image or its perception about its position in the international system (Gries, 2004, p. 9). Sinocentrism has a long and deep tradition in China, according to which Chinese 5000 years’ civilization is universal and superior. However, China’s national pride (Chinese people’s collective self-esteem) was seriously damaged by Western powers’ encroachment and Japan’s occupation of its territory between the mid-nineteenth and the mid-twentieth centuries, known by Chinese as their ‘Century of Humiliation’ (Gries, 2004, pp. 46–48). China’s communist revolution was indeed the product of Chinese nationalism that had been reinforced by the ‘Century of Humiliation’ as much as of
Marx–Leninism (Bajoria, 2008). Viewed from this prism, what China ultimately desires is to overcome its humiliation and recover its national pride and prestige as the Middle Kingdom and finally to be ‘recognized’ as superior to the West.
Rationalists hold that the accumulation of wealth and power is the dominant goal of the state, particularly of a great power. The accumulation of wealth and military power is, however, just means, not the ultimate goal of China. What China ultimately pursues is to overcome its humiliation and to be recognized. In short, as Yee (1997) puts, there are ‘brute’ facts that instrument rationality alone cannot explain fully or satisfactorily, and behaviors governed by thymos and/or value-oriented rationality can engender crucial political consequences in the international arena.

Three Categories of Social Behavior and the Study of IR
In the previous section, we focused on the limits of the concept of instrumental rationality in explaining the diverse motives of actors in international politics, using
118

© 2015 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1384-5748

International Politics

Vol. 52, 1, 110–127

Rationality, norms and identity

several illustrative examples. However, my argument is not that rationalism can be replaced by constructivism or by other approaches that emphasize the role of ideational or social-psychological motives in social actions. Rationalism has strength in explaining social behaviors driven mainly by cost–benefit calculations to maximize one’s (materialistic) self-interests. My point is that rationalism gives insufficient attention to social behaviors that are driven by different types of motives and that such social behaviors can produce greatly significant (international) political outcomes. In other words, we do not need to set one specific approach as a baseline a priori nor assume that there is only one dominant motive in all social actions.
I would also like to emphasize that not all main actors are nation-states in IR contexts. As discussed above, international terrorist groups, NGOs, even individuals like norms entrepreneurs play a crucial role in shaping or changing the texture of world politics. We do not need fixed (and a priori) views on main actors in the international arena to explain important international political phenomena.
Especially, (neo-)realism has maintained a state-centric view and has neglected the role of these non-state actors in world politics. As a result, it faces serious difficulty in explaining some crucial international or global political phenomena in which non-state actors are deeply involved. For example, (neo-)realists zero in on interstate military conflicts particularly among Great Powers, but today we witness the rise of asymmetrical wars between nation-states and non-state actors (for example, terrorist groups). This means that the main units of analysis are not necessarily nation-states.
Depending on (international) political consequences, the main actors in a given situation should be determined rather than assumed a priori. Even when we assume that the state is the main actor in a specific situation, we do not need to view the state as a unitary actor. If necessary, we may need to open the black box of the state. To trace out what motives drive its behavior in a specific time frame, we may need to know who or what groups are key players or decision makers during the period and what factors influence their decisions for state policies.
The key point here is that we need more flexible assumptions on main actors and their motives than those of rationalists in order to explain properly many crucial international political phenomena today. Rationalism (especially neo-realism) tends to emphasize the importance of ‘parsimony’ in theory construction. But in my view, too much emphasis on parsimony can make a theory or paradigm lose its real-world or policy relevance. A parsimonious theory or (formal) model may look elegant, but if it does not have real-world or policy relevance then what is its purpose? In my view, rationalism, particularly a neo–neo approach, maintains too strict assumptions on main actors and their motives, thus leaving today’s many significant international political issues unexplained or underexplained. In short, we have to make more efforts to strike a balance between theoretical parsimony and real-world or policy relevance. I propose that we classify social behaviors into three ideal-type categories or models rather than to try to defend one specific view on social actions: (i) self-interest-driven
© 2015 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1384-5748

International Politics

Vol. 52, 1, 110–127

119

Choi

behavior governed principally by instrumental rationality; (ii) norms/identity-driven behavior governed mainly by thymos and/or value-oriented rationality; (iii) the combination or conflict between the two. To be sure, in many cases norms or ideational considerations are not totally separable from actors’ self-interests, as they are closely interwoven with one another in their social actions. Nonetheless, this categorization can be helpful for analytical purposes and further research on different
(international) conditions that give rise to different actions or outcomes. Like any generalized set of categories and concepts, the three considered below make certain assumptions. First, in some situations (materialistic) self-interests governed by the logic of instrumental rationality are the predominant motive of actors and ideational factors like norms and identities do not play a significant role in their behaviors. For example, extremely selfish states or greedy political leaders may totally ignore international norms and pursue purely egoistic goals or interests. Second, some actions are driven chiefly by ideational, religious or moral motives such as ideologies, norms and identities. In this case, their strong commitment to a certain ideational cause dominates actors’ motive. For instance, suicide bombers, religious fundamentalist groups and radical political activists who are deeply devoted to their faith or ideology may be willing to give up their material comfort and safety for it.
Third, there are situations in which the above two categories of social actions are combined or directly conflict with each other. In fact, most situations can be classified into this category because most actors, consciously or not, take into account both their (material) self-interests and moral or ideational factors like norms and identity when they take any social or political action. In this third category, we can assume a situation in which there is no serious conflict between norms or identities and self-interests because they largely coincide with one another. For example, in IR contexts the promotion of democracy or human rights in enemy or non-ally countries by a country can coincide with the pursuit of its national (strategic) interests. Another example is that pursuing regional identity and norms (and joining a regional organization) can coincide with the pursuit of a country’s national economic and security interests. In such situations, in which there is no serious conflict between norms or identities and self-interests, it is worth pursuing an eclectic mode of analysis or a bridge-building approach between rationalism and constructivism (Katzenstein and Sil, 2008). In other words, we have to look at both cost–benefit calculation and moral or ideational consideration and how they interact with one another in co-producing certain political behaviors and outcomes.
However, in the third category it is also reasonable to assume a situation in which norms or identities and self-interests directly conflict with each other. Constructivists in IR tend to view ideational factors such as norms, ideas, cultures and identities as causally prior to interests (Jepperson et al, 1996). Basically I agree that an actor’s interests come from an understanding of the self and its interactions with its
(ideational as well as physical) environments. But we may have to admit that in
120

© 2015 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1384-5748

International Politics

Vol. 52, 1, 110–127

Rationality, norms and identity

some cases actors’ strong and clear-cut self-interests can overturn their normative values or identities. In particular, it is not unusual to witness such cases in interstate relations. For example, although many Arab countries (and their leaders) supported
‘Pan-Arabism’ or ‘Pan-Islamism’ with Iraq in implementing their foreign policies, especially toward the United States, when the Gulf War broke out in 1991, most of them turned from ‘Pan-Arabism’ or ‘Pan-Islamism’ to their national interests
(Telhami, 1993). Recently, several Eurozone countries are experiencing economic crises and we cannot rule out the possibility that some of them (for example, Greece) seek to give up on ‘Pan-Europeanism’ or ‘European identity’ and to exit from the
Eurozone for their national economic interests. As Krasner (2000, p. 134) puts it,
‘norms can be longstanding and widely recognized but also frequently violated’ because they are not solid in the international arena as in a domestic society. Also, social actors’ identities are not always robust. Moreover, a state usually has multiple identities and various social groups within it compete for definition or redefinition of national identities (Barnett, 1999). For instance, Ukraine has recently experienced a very serious national identity struggle between pro-European and pro-Russian groups. When the state’s identity is not stabilized, and especially if the state is experiencing ‘identity conflict’, it makes sense to assume that interest can trump identity. Risse et al (1999) explains this identity-interest problematique clearly in their study of the politics of the euro, the common currency of the Eurozone countries. In the case of Britain, its political leaders had strong beliefs about ‘English identity’ or
‘trans-Atlantic identity’ rather than ‘European identity’, whereas German political leaders had strong beliefs about ‘Euro-patriotism’, as they sought to overcome the
German militarist and ultra-nationalist past. In both Britain and Germany, opinions on the expected economic benefits from joining the euro were highly divided among elites. Ultimately, Germany decided to join the euro, whereas Britain decided not to join it. On the other hand, France took the middle ground. French identity has been contested in elite discourses, whereas political leaders had strong beliefs about the economic benefits from joining the euro, especially after the failure of economic policies in the 1980s. The result is that France joined the euro after French elites had adjusted French identity, Europeanizing their perceptions of ‘French distinctiveness’.
This study suggests that when identities (or norms) are firmly established and interests are ambiguous, causal arrows tend to go from identities (or norms) to interests. On the other hand, when identities (or norms) are unstable or fluid and interests are clear-cut, causal arrows tend to go from interests to identities (or norms).
Regionalism in East Asia also supports the view that interest can trump identity, especially when actors’ identity is not stabilized. The rise of a region-wide identity in
East Asia (an East Asian identity) is a relatively new phenomenon compared with regional identities in other major regions such as Europe. External developments like the launch and/or strengthening of common institutions in Europe and North
America, and the Asian Financial Crisis in the 1990s put pressures on East Asian
© 2015 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1384-5748

International Politics

Vol. 52, 1, 110–127

121

Choi

countries to pursue shared interests based on a newly constructed common identity.
External pressures and the ‘experience of common problems’ helped East Asian countries recognize the existence of ‘common’ others (by distinguishing ‘us’ from
‘them’) and enhanced their collective consciousness of a common identity (Terada,
2003, p. 254). A regional identity in East Asia though is very shallow and unstable because it was externally imposed and lacks an internal cohesiveness. Unlike Europe,
East Asia has a wide diversity in terms of cultural values, religious faiths, and political/economic ideologies and systems. On the other hand, two major powers in the region, China and Japan, have showed their very clear-cut interests in regional policies: taking a leadership role in constructing a regional economic/financial architecture. The two countries agree to establish a solid and common regional institution modeled on the European Union, but the problem is each wants to do that under its own leadership and direction (Grimes, 2008). Ideas on a regional project like the East Asian Community have been proposed and discussed among policymakers in East Asia, but there has been little progress in formal regional institutionalization under this divided leadership and there has been a wide gap between public statements and actual achievements. This case illustrates how actors’ strong self-interests can trump their identity when their identity is shallow or unstable. In short, as the three ideal-type categories of social action demonstrates, there are various motives of social actions that can generate significant political outcomes:
(i) self-interest-driven behavior governed mainly by instrumental rationality;
(ii) norm/identity-driven behavior governed primarily by thymos or affect, and/or value-oriented rationality; (iii) the combination or conflict between the two. In the third category, when there is a direct conflict between two different motives (interest versus norm/identity), we need to closely examine the direction of causal arrows.
I suggest that when identities (or norms) are solid or deep and interests are unclear or fluid, causal arrows tend to move from identities (or norms) to interests. On the other hand, when identities (or norms) are contested or unstable and interests are welldefined, causal arrows tend to move from interests to identities (or norms). I admit that there should be more systematic empirical studies, especially on conditions under which an actor’s identity (or norms) becomes unstable or contested. My study, however, shows that causal arrows can flow in either direction between identity/ norms and interest, and that one theoretical approach based on a single motive cannot fully explain today’s diverse international affairs that have political significance.

Conclusion
Rationalists in IR have assumed that actors are rational interest-seekers and for them the interests of actors (and their identities) are exogenously given. To be sure, all theories inevitably assume something as given or bracket some issues because we
122

© 2015 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1384-5748

International Politics

Vol. 52, 1, 110–127

Rationality, norms and identity

cannot deal with all the issues at the same time (Wendt, 1999, pp. 33–34). But
I agree with constructivism that rationalists’ views on the motives of social actions are too restrictive to explain many important aspects of international political life.
The maximization of one’s interests through cost–benefit calculation is one of the dominant motives of social behaviors, but it is not the only significant motive. In some cases, social actors behave widely differently in the same or similar situation and certain actors do not follow expected patterns of behaviors (especially from the viewpoint of instrumental rationality). Social actions driven by strong ideological and moral commitment or loyalty are not captured very well by the simple logic of cost–benefit calculation. These ideational or social-psychological motivations are governed primarily by thymos and/or value-oriented rationality rather than by instrumental rationality, and the behaviors that are driven by these motivations can result in greatly crucial (international) political outcomes.
Especially, since the end of the Cold War, we have witnessed politically momentous events in the international arena including the proliferation of ethno-religious conflicts, the reemergence of religious fundamentalism, the spread of international terrorism, and the increasingly important role of norms entrepreneurs and NGOs in world politics that have led various global social movements. These important international political phenomena that are related to the politics of anger, loyalty, values or a sense of justice have not been explained appropriately or have been underexplained by rationalism in IR perhaps because it does not have an efficient analytical tool to account for those phenomena. We may need to have more flexible assumptions on main actors and their motives than those of rationalists to explicate them in a more appropriate way. With its attention to moral or ideational factors such as norms and identities in world politics, constructivism is better prepared to explain those phenomena. Constructivism, however, cannot totally replace rationalism in explaining international political affairs. Although it holds that identities or norms shape and change actors’ interests, actors’ strong and clearly defined self-interests can overrule their norms or identities as my arguments and examples suggest.
As the three ideal-type categories or models of social behaviors suggest, the two approaches are complementary rather than competitive in explaining social and international phenomena. In some cases when there is no serious conflict between norms or identities and self-interests, an eclectic mode of analysis or a bridgebuilding approach between rationalism and constructivism is possible and should be encouraged. When there is a direct conflict between the two sets of motives, we need to investigate carefully where causal arrows move as they can flow in either direction.
There should be also more empirical research on conditions under which certain motives (for example, identity or norms) become very unstable or solid. Rationalism’s parsimony is valuable in theory construction, but overemphasis on parsimony makes a theory lose its real-world or policy relevance. Thus, certain important international political questions or issues have not been asked or addressed seriously by it. We may have to make more efforts to strike a balance between theoretical ‘parsimony’
© 2015 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1384-5748

International Politics

Vol. 52, 1, 110–127

123

Choi

and the ‘complexity’ of social actions in the real world to improve the political relevance of IR theory in a rapidly changing today’s world.

Acknowledgements
My special thanks goes to Sean Kay, Jim Peoples and Michael Cox for their insightful and valuable comments and suggestions on the earlier version of this article. About the Author
Ji Young Choi is assistant professor in Politics and Government and affiliate
(assistant) professor in International Studies and East Asian Studies at Ohio
Wesleyan University located in Delaware, Ohio, USA. His main research interests are in the politics of economic globalization, global financial governance, the comparative study of regionalism (Europe and East Asia), hegemony cycles or global political power shifts and the rise of China, and Korean security and political economy. Notes
1 Constructivism has various branches, but here we focus mainly on a modern or mainstream version rather than on a postmodern or feminist one. Concerning different versions of constructivism, see
Finnemore and Sikkink (2001, p. 395), Fearon and Wendt (2002, p. 57) and Adler (2002, pp. 97–98).
2 In fact, these psychological aspects of identity have been less investigated by constructivists than its social aspects and there should be further research on its psychological dimensions.

References
Abdelal, R., Herrera, Y.M., Johnston, A.I. and McDermott, R. (eds.) (2009) Measuring Identity: A Guide for Social Scientists. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.
Adler, E. (2002) Constructivism and international relations. In: W. Carlsnaes, T. Risse and B. Simmons
(eds.) Handbook of International Relations. London: Sage, pp. 52–72.
Axelrod, R. (1984) The Evolution of Cooperation. New York: Basic Books.
Axelrod, R. and Keohane, R.O. (1993) Achieving cooperation under anarchy: Strategies and institutions.
In: D.A. Baldwin (ed.) Neorealism and Neoliberalism: The Contemporary Debate. New York:
Columbia University Press, pp. 85–115.
Bajoria, J. (2008) Nationalism in China. New York and Washington DC: Council on Foreign Relations, http://www.cfr.org/china/nationalism-china/p16079, accessed 20 May 2013.
Barnett, M.N. (1999) Culture, strategy and foreign policy change: Israel’s road to Oslo. European Journal of International Relations 5(1): 5–36.
124

© 2015 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1384-5748

International Politics

Vol. 52, 1, 110–127

Rationality, norms and identity

Checkel, J.T. (1998) The constructivist turn in international relations theory. World Politics 50(2):
324–348.
Chong, D. (2000) Rational Lives: Norms and Values in Politics and Society. Chicago, IL: University of
Chicago Press.
Dessler, D. (1989) What’s at stake in the agent-structure debate? International Organization 43(3):
441–474.
Elster, J. (1982) Marxism, functionalism, and game theory: The case for methodological individualism.
Theory and Society 11(4): 453–482.
Fearon, J. and Wendt, A. (2002) Rationalism versus constructivism: A skeptical view. In: W. Carlsnaes,
T. Risse and B. Simmons (eds.) Handbook of International Relations. London: Sage, pp. 52–72.
Finnemore, M. (ed.) (1996) Defining state interests. National Interests in International Society. Ithaca, NY:
Cornell University Press, pp. 1–33.
Finnemore, M. and Sikkink, K. (1998) International norm dynamics and political change. International
Organization 52(4): 887–917.
Finnemore, M. and Sikkink, K. (2001) Taking stock: The constructivist research program in international relations and comparative politics. Annual Review of Political Science 4(1): 391–416.
Fukuyama, F. (1992) The End of History and the Last Man. New York: Avon Books.
Glaser, C.L. (2010) Rational Theory of International Politics: The Logic of Competition and Cooperation.
Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Grieco, J. (1988) Anarchy and the limits of cooperation: A realist critique of the newest liberal institutionalism. International Organization 42(3): 485–508.
Gries, P.H. (2004) China’s New Nationalism: Pride, Politics, and Diplomacy. Berkeley, CA: University of
California Press.
Grimes, W.W. (2008) Currency and Contest in East Asia: The Great Power Politics of Financial
Regionalism. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.
Guzzini, S. (2000) A reconstruction of constructivism in international relations. European Journal of
International Relations 6(2): 147–182.
Hopf, T. (1998) The promise of constructivism in international relations theory. International Security
21(1): 171–200.
Hopf, T. (2002) Social Construction of International Politics: Identities and Foreign Policies, Moscow,
1955 and 1999. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.
Hopf, T. (2010) The logic of habit in international relations. European Journal of International Relations
16(4): 539–561.
Hurd, I. (1999) Legitimacy and authority in international politics. International Organization 53(2):
379–408.
Hurrell, A. (2002) Norms and ethics in international relations. In: W. Carlsnaes, T. Risse and B. Simmons
(eds.) Handbook of International Relations. London: Sage, pp. 137–154.
Hymans, J. (2006) The Psychology of Nuclear Proliferation: Identity, Emotions, and Foreign Policy.
Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.
Jepperson, R.L., Wendt, A. and Katzenstein, P.J. (1996) Norms, identity, and culture in national security.
In: P.J. Katzenstein (ed.) The Culture of National Security: Norms and Identity in World Politics.
New York: Columbia University Press, pp. 33–75.
Jervis, R. (1976) Perception and Misperception in International Politics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton
University Press.
Kahler, M. (1998) Rationality in international relations. International Organization 52(4): 919–941.
Katzenstein, P.J. (ed.) (1996) Introduction: Alternative perspectives on national security. In: The Culture of National Security: Norms and Identity in World Politics. New York: Columbia University Press, pp. 1–32.
Katzenstein, P.J., Keohane, R.O. and Krasner, S.D. (1998) International organization and the study of world politics. International Organization 52(4): 645–685.
© 2015 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1384-5748

International Politics

Vol. 52, 1, 110–127

125

Choi

Katzenstein, P.J. and Sil, R. (2008) Eclectic theorizing in the study and practice of international relations.
In: C. Reus-Smit and D. Snidal (eds.) Oxford Handbook of International Relations. Oxford: Oxford
University Press, pp. 109–130.
Keck, M.E. and Sikkink, K. (1998) Activists beyond Borders: Advocacy Networks in International Politics.
Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.
Keohane, R.O. (1984) After Hegemony: Cooperation and Discord in the World Political Economy.
Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Keohane, R.O. (1988) International institutions: Two approaches. International Studies Quarterly 32(4):
379–396.
Keohane, R.O. (2000) Ideas part-way down. Review of International Studies 26(1): 125–130.
Klotz, A. (1995) Norms reconstituting interests: Global racial equality and U.S. sanctions against South
Africa. International Organization 49(3): 451–478.
Krasner, S.D. (2000) Wars, hotel fires, and plane crashes. Review of International Studies 26(1):
131–136.
Lebow, R.N. (2008) A Cultural Theory of International Relations. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University
Press.
Legro, J.W. (1997) Which norms matter? Revisiting the ‘failure’ of internationalism. International
Organization 51(1): 31–63.
Lichbach, M.I. (1997) Social theory and comparative politics. In: M.I. Lichbach and A.S. Zuckerman (eds.)
Comparative Politics: Rationality, Culture, and Structure. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, pp. 239–276.
Mearsheimer, J.J. (2001) The Tragedy of Great Power Politics. New York: W.W. Norton.
Mercer, J. (2005) Rationality and psychology in international politics. International Organization 59(1):
77–106.
Morgenthau, H.J. (1948 [1973]) The Politics among Nations: The Struggle for Power and Peace, 5th edn.
New York: Alfred A. Knopf.
Risse, T., Engelmann-Martin, D., Knopf, H.J. and Roscher, K. (1999) To euro or not to euro? The EMU and identity politics in the European Union. European Journal of International Relations 5(2):
147–187.
Sasley, B.E. (2011) Theorizing states’ emotions. International Studies Review 13(3): 452–476.
Sassoon, J. (2012) Economic Lessons from Iraq for Countries of the Arab Spring. Middle East Program:
Occasional Paper Series (Spring 2), Washington DC: Woodrow Wilson International Center of
Scholars, http://www.wilsoncenter.org/sites/default/files/Economic%20Lessons%20from%20Iraq_0
.pdf, accessed 10 March 2014.
Saurette, P. (2006) You dissin me? Humiliation and post 9/11 global politics. Review of International
Studies 32(4): 495–522.
Smith, S. (1997) New approaches to international theory. In: J. Baylis and S. Smith (eds.) The
Globalization of World Politics: An Introduction to International Relations. Oxford: Oxford University
Press, pp. 165–190.
Snidal, D. (2002) Rational choice and international relations. In: W. Carlsnaes, T. Risse and B. Simmons
(eds.) Handbook of International Relations. London: Sage, pp. 73–94.
Telhami, S. (1993) Arab public opinion and the Gulf War. Political Science Quarterly 108(3): 437–452.
Terada, T. (2003) Constructing an ‘East Asian’ concept and growing regional identity: From EASEC to
ASEAN+3. The Pacific Review 16(2): 251–277.
Thiele, L.P. (1997) Thinking Politics: Perspectives in Ancient, Modern, and Postmodern Political Theory.
Chatham, NJ: Chatham House Publishers.
Walt, S.N. (1987) The Origins of Alliances. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.
Waltz, K.N. (1979) Theory of International Politics. Boston, MA: McGraw-Hill.
Wendt, A. (1987) The agent-structure problem in international relations. International Organization 41(3):
335–370.
126

© 2015 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1384-5748

International Politics

Vol. 52, 1, 110–127

Rationality, norms and identity

Wendt, A. (1992) Anarchy is what states make of it: The social construction of power politics.
International Organization 46(2): 391–425.
Wendt, A. (1999) Social Theory of International Politics. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.
Yee, A.S. (1997) Thick rationality and the missing ‘Brute Fact’: The limits of rational incorporations of norms and ideas. The Journal of Politics 59(4): 1001–1039.
Zakaria, F. (2001) The politics of rage: Why do they hate us? Newsweek 15(October): 22–40.

© 2015 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1384-5748

International Politics

Vol. 52, 1, 110–127

127

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.

Similar Documents

Free Essay

Feminisim and International Relations

...morality cannot be an constant guide to IR because there is an "ineluctable tension between the moral command and the requirements of successful political action." He argues that state actors must think and act in terms of power and must do whatever it takes to defend the national interests of their state. J. Ann Tickner, commenting on the primacy of power in Morgenthau's writings, explains that what he considers to be "a realistic description of international politics is only a picture of the past and therefore not a prediction about the future", and proposes what she considers to be a feminist alternative: a world in which state actors think of power in terms of collective empowerment, not in terms of domination over one another, could produce more cooperative outcomes and pose fewer conflicts between the dictates of morality and the power of self-interest (Art & Jervis, 2005). Emergence of Feminism Most of the early feminists in IR were IR theorists, researchers, and policy practitioners, who read syllabi full of scholarly articles by mainly or only men, and seen IR as a scholarly place often hostile to women and femininity. Feminist scholarship came into the discipline of International Relations(IR) around the 1980s and 1990s. It was not IR that produced the feminist insight, for feminism is, according to Daddow (2009), "a wider social and intellectual movement that has had a big impact in politics, society, and education" (p. 145). IR Feminist scholars began looking for...

Words: 1856 - Pages: 8

Free Essay

Is Aanteken

...International Security Lecture 1 March 30th, 2015 The politics of security knowledge What is international security? We could start thinking about the security council of the UN But also about the invasion of Afghanistan (chapter 7 UN in order to secure the international security) We can also think about security in terms of the invasion of Iraq in 2003. This was a unilateral act of war, but sure it can also mean other things We can think of the national security agency, the agency in charge of spying all the signals and communications to a certain extent. What’s interesting about the NSA, it is seen as a threat to the security of the privacy. Lately, with the reports of the UN development programme, we start talking about HUMAN security (not military security, but rather the security of individuals, having a livelihood that’s acceptable). Whether security is international or not, it can be a rather confusing word The protection of values we hold dear. We search for it, we pursue it, we achieve it, we deny it to others. * what is to be secured? Is it the security of states? Or individuals? * What is the actual threat that we’re facing? Primarily to be dealing with military threats, or are there other types of threats we are facing. Essentially contested concept A concept that ‘inevitably’ involves endless disputes about their proper uses on the part of their users – Walter Gallie There can be ambiguity (one persons freedom-fighter is the other’s...

Words: 16869 - Pages: 68

Free Essay

Soft Power

...1177/1354066113503479European Journal of International RelationsSolomon E IR J Article The affective underpinnings of soft power European Journal of International Relations 2014, Vol. 20(3) 720­–741 © The Author(s) 2014 Reprints and permissions: sagepub.co.uk/journalsPermissions.nav DOI: 10.1177/1354066113503479 ejt.sagepub.com Ty Solomon University of Glasgow, UK Abstract The concept of soft power occupies a prominent place in International Relations, foreign policy, and security studies. Primarily developed by Joseph S. Nye, the concept is typically drawn upon to emphasize the more intangible dimensions of power in a field long dominated by overtly material (i.e. military) power. Recently, some scholars have reframed soft power — specifically the key notion of attraction — as a narrative and linguistic process. This literature, however, has downplayed some of the other deep-seated underpinnings of soft power, which this article argues lie in the dynamics of affect. Building upon the International Relations affect and aesthetics literatures, this article develops the concept of soft power as rooted in the political dynamics of emotion and introduces the concept of affective investment. The attraction of soft power stems not only from its cultural influence or narrative construction, but more fundamentally from audiences’ affective investments in the images of identity that it produces. The empirical import of these ideas is offered in an ...

Words: 12815 - Pages: 52

Premium Essay

Int' Political Economy

...International political economy (IPE), also known as global political economy, is an academic discipline within the social sciences that analyzes international relations in combination with political economy. As an interdisciplinary field it draws on many distinct academic schools, most notably political science and economics, but also sociology, history, and cultural studies. The academic boundaries of IPE are flexible, and along with acceptable epistemologies are the subject of robust debate. This debate is essentially framed by the discipline's status as a new and interdisciplinary field of study. Despite such disagreements, most scholars can concur that IPE ultimately is concerned with the ways in which political forces (states, institutions, individual actors, etc.) shape the systems through which economic interactions are expressed, and conversely the effect that economic interactions (including the power of collective markets and individuals acting both within and outside them) have upon political structures and outcomes. IPE scholars are at the center of the debate and research surrounding globalization, both in the popular and academic spheres. Other topics that command substantial attention among IPE scholars are international trade (with particular attention to the politics surrounding trade deals, but also significant work examining the results of trade deals), development, the relationship between democracy and markets, international finance, global markets, multi-state...

Words: 6475 - Pages: 26

Premium Essay

Townley and Foucault

...® Acodemy of Management Heview 1993, Vol. 18, No. 3. 518-545. FOUCAULT. POWER/KNOWLEDGE. AND ITS RELEVANCE FOR HUMAN RESOURCE MANAGEMENT BARBARA TOWNLEY The University of Alberta Drawing on the work of Michel Foucault. I argue that human resource management (HRM) may be best understood as a discourse and set of practices that attempt to reduce the indeterminacy involved in the employment contract. Here I reread HRM practices from a Foucauldian power-knowledge perspective and suggest that this provides an avenue to reorient contemporary, historical, and comparative analyses of the area. A glimpse at human resource management (HRM) texts would seem to give light to a comment by Beer, Spector, Lawrence, Mills, and Walton (1984) that HRM is a series of seemingly disjointed activities. This notion echoes an earlier view of Baldamus (1961: 347) that what is encompassed by HRM's subject matter is "anything from supervision, incentives and profit sharing to machine-paced production, methods of training and employee selection." Often this heterogeneity is excused in terms of HRM's reflecting the ad hoc and reactive nature of its origins (Jacoby, 1985; Niven, 1967; Ozanne, 1967). What the heterogeneity of HRM highlights, however, is the importance of an organizing principle, or analytical focus, as opposed to common sense description, which gives HRM practices a theoretical coherence. HRM's heterogeneity stresses the importance of an order "that turns a set of bits, which have limited...

Words: 12810 - Pages: 52

Premium Essay

The European Union and Its Power over Opinion: What Can Belarus Tell Us About the European Identity?

...about the European identity? Contents Abstract Page 4 Introduction ` Page 5 Chapter 1: Constructing a European identity Page 8 Chapter 2: The European Union as a normative actor Page 21 Chapter 3: The Belarusian problem Page 30 Conclusion Page 49 Bibliography Page 52 Abstract Europe has embarked upon an unprecedented process of state integration witnessing the widespread deferral of policy making to intergovernmental institutions. The European Union’s institutionalism has facilitated an assimilation of values into an increasingly coherent, if complex regional identity. A normative self-conception has emerged that Brussels has sought to project onto its external relations through the Common Foreign and Security Policy. Brussels increasingly considers itself a transformative actor in global politics offering an alternative to great power realpolitik. This paper finds that while European multilateralism offers an environment conducive to a normative foreign policy, the extent to which it is able to exert any ideational influence is constrained by the level of engagement it is willing to pursue. Europe maintains a policy of isolating the Lukashenko regime and has failed to engage Belarusian civil society. As a result it has had a negligible impact on Belarusian political culture. Europe’s failure to adequately engage Belarus also suggests a contradiction within the European identity construction. Introduction ...

Words: 13537 - Pages: 55

Premium Essay

Ir Theories

...Theories of International Relations Third edition Scott Burchill, Andrew Linklater, Richard Devetak, Jack Donnelly, Matthew Paterson, Christian Reus-Smit and Jacqui True Theories of International Relations This page intentionally left blank Theories of International Relations Third edition Scott Burchill, Andrew Linklater, Richard Devetak, Jack Donnelly, Matthew Paterson, Christian Reus-Smit and Jacqui True Material from 1st edition © Deakin University 1995, 1996 Chapter 1 © Scott Burchill 2001, Scott Burchill and Andrew Linklater 2005 Chapter 2 © Jack Donnelly 2005 Chapter 3 © Scott Burchill, Chapters 4 and 5 © Andrew Linklater, Chapters 6 and 7 © Richard Devetak, Chapter 8 © Christian Reus-Smit, Chapter 9 © Jacqui True, Chapter 10 © Matthew Paterson 2001, 2005 All rights reserved. No reproduction, copy or transmission of this publication may be made without written permission. No paragraph of this publication may be reproduced, copied or transmitted save with written permission or in accordance with the provisions of the Copyright, Designs and Patents Act 1988, or under the terms of any licence permitting limited copying issued by the Copyright Licensing Agency, 90 Tottenham Court Road, London W1T 4LP. Any person who does any unauthorized act in relation to this publication may be liable to criminal prosecution and civil claims for damages. The authors have asserted their rights to be identified as the authors of this work in accordance with the Copyright...

Words: 132890 - Pages: 532

Free Essay

Getting

...International Relations Theory The new edition of International Relations Theory: A critical introduction introduces students to the main theories in international relations. It explains and analyzes each theory, allowing students to understand and critically engage with the myths and assumptions behind each theory. Key features of this textbook include: • discussion of all of the main theories: realism and (neo)realism, idealism and (neo)idealism, liberalism, constructivism, postmodernism, gender, and globalization two new chapters on the “clash of civilizations” and Hardt and Negri’s Empire innovative use of narratives from films that students will be familiar with: Lord of the Flies, Independence Day, Wag the Dog, Fatal Attraction, The Truman Show, East is East, and Memento an accessible and exciting writing style which is well-illustrated with boxed key concepts and guides to further reading. • • • This breakthrough textbook has been designed to unravel the complexities of international relations theory in a way that allows students a clearer idea of how the theories work and the myths that are associated with them. Cynthia Weber is Professor of International Studies at the University of Lancaster. She is the author of several books and numerous articles in the field of international relations. International Relations Theory A critical introduction Second edition Cynthia Weber First published 2001 by Routledge Second edition published 2005 by Routledge...

Words: 74303 - Pages: 298

Premium Essay

Samsung Case Study

...Maintaining the “Single Samsung” Spirit: New Challenges in a Changing Environment Caryn Ng Kar Yan B1102572 Keah Mei Sian B1102580 Nur Fathiha Bte Johan Ariffin B1100381 Mohd Roshan bin Mohd Yusop B0101223 Sarkunarajah S B1001971 Wan Arjunaidi Bin Awang @ Wan Abdul Halim E0300073 Abstract Samsung portrayed a very interesting and impressive success story in every aspect of development. Although they were hit hard by financial crisis in 2009, Samsung survived the ordeal with their impressive financial performance. The astonishing part of their achievement is mostly guided by internal management capability, positive aligned culture and belief system that empowering human capital is the foundation in building and maintaining a great organization. Their strong belief system in emphasizing and investing on employees well being pays off when they become the leading company beating some of the top companies such as Sony, Apple and HTC. The process and development of human capital was never an easy matter for Samsung, in fact the culture has been practiced and improvised regularly ever since 1950 to fit to the demand and maturity of the current society and technology. Nevertheless at the end, Samsung indeed make a marked in the world with sustaining a Single Samsung culture. 1. Perform a PEST on Samsung and identify the change drivers POLITICAL | ECONOMIC | * Work hand in hand with the government; consist the same agendas and values.Change...

Words: 6166 - Pages: 25

Premium Essay

Global Political Economy

...GRADUATE DIPLOMA IN INTERNATIONAL RELATIONS AND DIPLOMACY STUDENT GUIDELINE NOTES GLOBAL POLITICAL ECONOMY MODULE Paste the notes here… Political economy originally was the term for studying production, buying and selling, and their relations with law, custom, and government. Political economy originated in moral philosophy (e.g. Adam Smith was Professor of Moral Philosophy at the University of Glasgow), it developed in the 18th century as the study of the economies of states — polities, hence political economy. In late nineteenth century, the term "political economy" was generally replaced by the term economics, used by those seeking to place the study of economy upon mathematical and axiomatic bases, rather than the structural relationships of production and consumption (cf. marginalism, Alfred Marshall). History of the term Originally, political economy meant the study of the conditions under which production was organized in the nation-states. The phrase économie politique (translated in English as political economy) first appeared in France in 1615 with the well known book by Antoyne de Montchrétien: Traicté de l’oeconomie politique. French physiocrats, Adam Smith, David Ricardo and Karl Marx were some of the exponents of political economy. In 1805, Thomas Malthus became England's first professor of political economy, at the East India Company College, Haileybury, Hertfordshire. The world's first professorship in political economy was established...

Words: 39122 - Pages: 157

Premium Essay

Entrepreneur

...Organizational Behavior - MGT502 VU MGT - 502 ORGANIZATIONAL BEHAVIOR Lesson 1 OVERVIEW OF COURSE This subject/course is designed to teach the basic language of organizational behavior to diverse audience/students, including those who are studying this as a supporting subject for their bachelor degree program. This course is designed to provide you the foundations of organizational behavior whether you intend to work in any field of interest. Organizational behavior offers both challenges and opportunities for managers. It recognizes differences and helps managers to see the value of workforce diversity and practices that may need to be changed when managing in different countries. It can help improve quality and employee productivity by showing managers how to empower their people as well as how to design and implement change programs. It offers specific insights to improve a manager’s people skills. In times of rapid and ongoing change, faced by most managers today, OB can help managers cope in a world of “temporariness” and learn ways to stimulate innovation. Finally, OB can offer managers guidance in creating an ethically healthy work climate. Managers need to develop their interpersonal or people skills if they are going to be effective in their jobs. Organizational behavior (OB) is a field of study that investigates the impact that individuals, groups, and structure have on behavior within an organization, and then applies that knowledge to make organizations work...

Words: 81220 - Pages: 325

Free Essay

Code

...C O D E C ODE v e r s i o n 2 . 0 L A W R E N C E L E S S I G A Member of the Perseus Books Group New York Copyright © 2006 by Lawrence Lessig CC Attribution-ShareAlike Published by Basic Books A Member of the Perseus Books Group Printed in the United States of America. For information, address Basic Books, 387 Park Avenue South, New York, NY 10016–8810. Books published by Basic Books are available at special discounts for bulk purchases in the United States by corporations, institutions, and other organizations. For more information, please contact the Special Markets Department at the Perseus Books Group, 11 Cambridge Center, Cambridge MA 02142, or call (617) 252-5298, (800) 255-1514 or e-mail special.markets@perseusbooks.com. CIP catalog record for this book is available from the Library of Congress. ISBN-10: 0–465–03914–6 ISBN-13: 978–0–465–03914–2 06 07 08 09 / 10 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1 Code version 1.0 FOR CHARLIE NESSON, WHOSE EVERY IDEA SEEMS CRAZY FOR ABOUT A YEAR. Code version 2.0 TO WIKIPEDIA, THE ONE SURPRISE THAT TEACHES MORE THAN EVERYTHING HERE. C O N T E N T S Preface to the Second Edition Preface to the First Edition Chapter 1. Code Is Law Chapter 2. Four Puzzles from Cyberspace PART I: “REGULABILITY” ix xiii 1 9 Chapter 3. Is-Ism: Is the Way It Is the Way It Must Be? Chapter 4. Architectures of Control Chapter 5. Regulating Code PART II: REGULATION BY CODE 31 38 61 Chapter 6. Cyberspaces Chapter 7. What Things Regulate...

Words: 190498 - Pages: 762

Premium Essay

Help

...CHAPTER-BY-CHAPTER ANSWER KEY CHAPTER 1 ANSWERS FOR THE MULTIPLE CHOICE QUESTIONS 1. b The sociological perspective is an approach to understanding human behavior by placing it within its broader social context. (4) 2 . d Sociologists consider occupation, income, education, gender, age, and race as dimensions of social location.(4) 3. d All three statements reflect ways in which the social sciences are like the natural sciences. Both attempt to study and understand their subjects objectively; both attempt to undercover the relationships that create order in their respective worlds through controlled observation; and both are divided into many specialized fields. (5-7) 4. c Generalization is one of the goals of scientific inquiry. It involves going beyond individual cases by making statements that apply to broader groups or situations. (7) 5. b The Industrial Revolution, imperialism, and the development of the scientific method all contributed to the development of sociology. The fourth influence was the political revolutions in America and France — there was no political revolution in Britain at that time. (8-9) 6. d Positivism is the application of the scientific approach to the social world. (9) 7. d Of the four statements, the one that best reflects Herbert Spencer’s views on charity is “The poor are the weakest members of society and if society intervenes to help them, it is interrupting the natural process of social evolution.” While many contemporaries of Spencer’s were...

Words: 52339 - Pages: 210

Premium Essay

Politics, Theology

...POLITICS, THEOLOGY AND HISTORY RAYMOND PLANT CAMBRIDGE UNIVERSITY PRESS Politics, Theology and History is a major new book by a prominent academic and an active politician. It ranges widely across the disciplines of theology, political theory and philosophy and poses acute questions about the basic moral foundations of liberal societies. Lord Plant focuses on the role that religious belief can and ought to play in argument about public policy in a pluralistic society. He examines the potential political implications of Christian belief and the ways in which it may be deployed in political debate. The book is a contribution to the modern debate about the moral pluralism of western liberal societies, discussing the place of religious belief in the formation of policy and asking what sorts of issues in modern society might be the legitimate objects of a Christian social and political concern. Raymond Plant has written an important study of the relationship between religion and politics which will be of value to students, academics, politicians, church professionals, policy makers and all concerned with the moral fabric of contemporary life. r ay m on d pl an t is Professor of European Political Thought at the University of Southampton and a Member of the House of Lords. He was a Home affairs spokesperson for the Labour Party from 1992 to 1996, and Master of St Catherine's College, Oxford, from 1994 to 2000. Lord Plant's main publications are Social and Moral Theory in Casework...

Words: 144283 - Pages: 578

Free Essay

Thinking Fast and Slow

...In memory of Amos Tversky Contents Introduction Part I. Two Systems 1. The Characters of the Story 2. Attention and Effort 3. The Lazy Controller 4. The Associative Machine 5. Cognitive Ease 6. Norms, Surprises, and Causes 7. A Machine for Jumping to Conclusions 8. How Judgments Happen 9. Answering an Easier Question Part II. Heuristics and Biases 10. The Law of Small Numbers 11. Anchors 12. The Science of Availability 13. Availability, Emotion, and Risk 14. Tom W’s Specialty 15. Linda: Less is More 16. Causes Trump Statistics 17. Regression to the Mean 18. Taming Intuitive Predictions Part III. Overconfidence 19. The Illusion of Understanding 20. The Illusion of Validity 21. Intuitions Vs. Formulas 22. Expert Intuition: When Can We Trust It? 23. The Outside View 24. The Engine of Capitalism Part IV. Choices 25. Bernoulli’s Errors 26. Prospect Theory 27. The Endowment Effect 28. Bad Events 29. The Fourfold Pattern 30. Rare Events 31. Risk Policies 32. Keeping Score 33. Reversals 34. Frames and Reality Part V. Two Selves 35. Two Selves 36. Life as a Story 37. Experienced Well-Being 38. Thinking About Life Conclusions Appendix Uncertainty A: Judgment Under Appendix B: Choices, Values, and Frames Acknowledgments Notes Index Introduction Every author, I suppose, has in mind a setting in which readers of his or her work could benefit from having read it. Mine is the proverbial office watercooler, where opinions are shared and gossip is exchanged. I...

Words: 189666 - Pages: 759