Free Essay

Why Companies Offshore Innovation

In: Business and Management

Submitted By mathurarni
Words 17853
Pages 72
Journal of International Business Studies (2009) 40, 901–925

& 2009 Academy of International Business All rights reserved 0047-2506 www.jibs.net Why are companies offshoring innovation? The emerging global race for talent
Arie Y Lewin1, Silvia Massini2 and Carine Peeters3
The Fuqua School of Business, Duke University, Durham, USA; 2Manchester Business School, University of Manchester, Manchester, UK; 3 Solvay Brussels School of Economics and Management, Brussels, Belgium Correspondence: AY Lewin, The Fuqua School of Business, Duke University, 1 Towerview Drive, Box 90120, Durham, NC 27708, USA. Tel: þ 1 919 660 7654; Fax: þ 1 919 660 7769
1

Abstract This paper empirically studies determinants of decision by companies to offshore innovation activities. It uses survey data from the international Offshoring Research Network project to estimate the impact of managerial intentionality, past experience, and environmental factors on the probability of offshoring innovation projects. The results show that the emerging shortage of highly skilled science and engineering talent in the US and, more generally, the need to access qualified personnel are important explanatory factors for offshoring innovation decisions. Moreover, contrary to drivers of many other functions, labor arbitrage is less important than other forms of cost savings. The paper concludes with a discussion of the changing dynamics underlying offshoring of innovation activities, suggesting that companies are entering a global race for talent. Journal of International Business Studies (2009) 40, 901–925. doi:10.1057/jibs.2008.92
Keywords: offshoring; innovation; product development; global talent; co-evolution; survey

Received: 27 June 2007 Revised: 5 August 2008 Accepted: 6 August 2008 Online publication date: 7 May 2009

INTRODUCTION Outsourcing of manufacturing activities to low-cost countries is widely practiced and well understood (e.g., Dunning, 1993; Lee, 1986; Vernon, 1966). By comparison, the offshoring of high-valueadding white-collar activities – pioneered by a few companies in the 1980s – is still a relatively undiffused practice (Amiti & Wei, 2005). However, Dossani and Kenney (2007: 779) conclude that ‘‘in less than six years, offshoring of services has evolved from an exotic and risky strategy to a routine business decision.’’ The actions of US companies that are increasingly offshoring highervalue-added knowledge-intensive processes, and are restructuring and reorganizing their innovation processes worldwide, are of particular interest to this paper (Henley, 2006; Levy, 2005). According to Apte, McCarthy and Furstoss (2006), new product development (PD) is becoming the fastest-growing offshoring segment in India. Ernst (2006) suggests that the growing globalization of markets for technology and knowledge workers drives this growth in innovation offshoring. However, the reasons underlying the decisions by firms to offshore value-adding innovative activities remain to be understood conceptually as well as empirically. Conventional wisdom and existing literature (e.g., Barney, 1991; Grant, 1996; Nonaka & Takeuchi, 1995; Patel & Pavitt, 1991; Porter, 1985) suggest that innovation activities are at

Offshoring of innovation and global race for talent

Arie Y Lewin et al

902

the core of the firm competitive advantage and should be kept under tight control. This paper aims to advance a model of why firms find it necessary to offshore innovation activities, and to test that model empirically. Offshoring refers to the process of sourcing and coordinating tasks and business functions across national borders. Offshoring may include both in-house (captive, or international in-sourcing) and, increasingly, outsourced activities that are performed by an external provider – that is, from outside the boundaries of the firm. The outsourcing activity in turn can be located either domestically (onshore) or abroad (offshore). Further, offshoring refers to sourcing rather than sales activities, and it supports global or domestic rather than local operations. Access to new markets is therefore not a primary strategic driver for offshoring (Lewin & Peeters, 2006a, b). Also, offshoring does not include the business activities and processes performed at a subsidiary in another country, such as the HR (human resources) department in a foreign subsidiary that supports local operations (i.e., local sales and distribution). Only if HR services (e.g., payroll services) are provided from offshore in support of global or home-based HR functions is the term ‘‘offshoring’’ applicable. Although it is often assumed that IT infrastructure and business processes were among the early activities that were offshored, offshoring innovation activities began coincidentally with ITO and BPO (Lewin & Couto, 2007; Manning, Lewin, & Massini, 2008). The trend is for companies increasingly to offshore more complex and higher-value-adding activities that require access to subject-matter expertise and a growing number of highly skilled and qualified workers (Lewin & Peeters, 2006a). This trend is influenced and affected by various factors, including trade liberalization policies, advances in information technologies (Doh, 2005; Dossani & Kenney, 2006; Levy, 2005), and the ability of companies to dis-intermediate and modularize almost any process, including knowledge-creating processes (Sako, 2002; Takeishi, 2002). At the same time, however, according to Farrell, Laboissiere and Rosenfeld (2006) and Mehta, Armenakis, Mehta and Irani (2006), the organizational structures and processes necessary for coordinating globally dispersed business units and activities, managing knowledge, selecting locations, and managing talent offshore represent major new managerial challenges that could limit the growth in offshoring.

In this paper, we focus on the offshoring of innovation (both captive and outsourced), and seek to study the factors underlying the evolution of offshoring practices towards global sourcing of talent and the rapidly rising trend of offshoring PD work (i.e., R&D, product design, and engineering services). In the early 1980s several leading companies, such as Texas Instruments, Motorola, and General Electric, established technology centers in India and China to secure strategic advantages, such as favorable political treatment (Delios & Henisz, 2003) and access to skilled individuals (Ernst, 2006; Thursby & Thursby, 2006). Twenty years later, small, entrepreneurial firms are increasingly offshoring new PD because of their need to grow, to increase speed to market, or simply because their survival depends on it (Buchanan, 2006; Dossani & Kenney, 2007; Rangan & Schumacher, 2006). Asia, in particular, is playing a central role in the growing global innovation networks, as indicated, for example, by the growth in US patents granted to companies in Asia between 1986 and 2003 (Ernst, 2002, 2006). Major Asian countries in that respect include South Korea, Singapore, China, Taiwan, and India. However, Hirshfeld and Schmid (2005) argue that, although firms in the US and Europe are increasingly attracted to and are exploring new science and engineering (S&E) clusters in emerging countries, advanced economies are likely to remain at the forefront of innovation activities, at least in the foreseeable future (Manning et al., 2008). In order to study the determinants of firms’ decision to offshore PD activities, we use original survey data from the Offshoring Research Network (ORN) on 880 offshore implementations initiated by US firms between 1990 and 2006. The ORN is an ongoing multi-year international project tracking the offshoring of administrative and technical work by companies in the US and Europe. In contrast to other data sets, it allows offshoring decisions to be studied at the level of individual offshore projects, rather than at more aggregate firm or industry levels. In line with a co-evolutionary framework (Lewin, Long, & Carroll, 1999; Lewin & Volberda, 1999; Murmann, 2000; Volberda & Lewin, 2003), and responding to Hutzschenreuter, Pedersen, & Volberda’s (2007) call for the need to integrate managerial intentionality (MI) into international business (IB) strategy and internationalization research as multilevel analysis (Buckley & Lessard, 2005), our empirical approach models MI, path

Journal of International Business Studies

Offshoring of innovation and global race for talent

Arie Y Lewin et al

903

dependence, and environment as factors affecting the decisions to offshore PD functions and processes. We investigate whether the emerging shortage of highly skilled technical talent in the US – which drives the need to access talent globally – explains the offshoring of PD.1 We argue that the diminishing attractiveness of S&E careers (as indicated by the decline in US nationals earning advanced degrees in S&E) combined with the 2003 cutback in H1B visa2 quota are key factors underlying this trend. The analysis also seeks to clarify the role of offshore labor cost savings opportunities in improving the efficiency of the innovation process. We argue that the opportunity to access equally qualified (or more qualified) workers at lower cost does influence companies’ decisions to offshore innovation activities, but compared with other non-technical and less advanced functions (administrative and other back-office activities), labor arbitrage objectives are less important in the decision to offshore PD. The model also tests the effect of other strategic drivers that are usually assumed to influence PD offshoring decisions, including the importance of increasing speed to market and competitive pressures. Finally, we also investigate the role of firm past experience with offshoring as a determinant of the decision to offshore innovation activities. In the section that follows, we review the relevant literature and evidence, and discuss the research questions pertaining to the role of environmental factors, managerial strategic objectives, and firm past experience as determinants of firm decisions to offshore PD functions and processes. Following a brief introduction to the ORN project, the subsequent section describes the data used in this study and provides the methodological details. Following that, we present the regressions results. The discussion section interprets the empirical findings in the broader context of the growing globalization of human capital.

LITERATURE REVIEW AND THEORETICAL FRAMEWORK Three types of arguments have traditionally been advanced to explain firm-level internationalization decisions. First, the market approach argues that firms’ internationalization is driven by the advantages of exploiting in a larger market a firm-specific advantage in one activity (Hymer, 1976). Second, the internalization approach applies transaction cost theory (e.g., Williamson, 1975) to suggest that multinationals internalize the markets for their

knowledge-based assets in multiple locations (Buckley & Casson, 1976). Finally, Dunning’s (1980) eclectic OLI approach suggests the combination of firm-specific, location-specific, and internalization advantages to explain foreign direct investment (FDI) decisions. Within that literature, offshoring can be seen as a new form of internationalization by which firms disaggregate their value chains across multiple locations, to include the option of potentially externalizing specific processes and capabilities to third-party service providers. Earlier studies in the rich literature on internationalization of R&D have shown that the phenomenon of large multinational enterprises (MNEs) locating R&D outside the home country is not ˚ ¨ recent (e.g., Granstrand, Hakanson, & Sjolander, 1992; Kenney & Florida, 1994; Lall, 1979; Pearce, 1999). Cantwell (1995), for instance, showed that back in the 1930s the largest European and US firms carried out about 7% of their total R&D at locations abroad. However, since the 1960s this figure has been steadily rising, particularly in technologically intensive industries. Kuemmerle (1999a) shows that in 1965 the 32 multinational firms studied in his paper carried out 6.2% of their R&D efforts outside the home country boundaries, whereas in 1995 the corresponding figure was 25.8%. But with the exception of large MNEs in small countries, which have historically expanded their R&D activities offshore since World War II (Cantwell, 1995), the home country remained the most important single location for R&D (Patel and Pavitt, 1991), and the dominant organizational form was one of ownership and control. Furthermore, in the 1990s, FDI involving R&D occurred primarily between a small number of highly industrialized countries (Florida, 1997; Kuemmerle, 1999b). Researchers have examined the sequence of FDI in multiple host countries. Horst (1972) argues that MNEs commonly expand through a series of host countries, starting with those that are geographically closest (see also Rugman & Verbeke, 2004). Kuemmerle (1999b) showed that there are distinct waves of FDI in R&D by country of origin. US companies were pioneer investors in R&D facilities abroad, and invested first in Europe, then in Japan, and then in the rest of the world (primarily Canada, Australia, and a small number of Asian countries). European companies invested first in other European countries, then in the US and then in Japan, but only to a very limited degree in the rest of the world. The surge of Japanese investments in

Journal of International Business Studies

Offshoring of innovation and global race for talent

Arie Y Lewin et al

904

the US, Europe, and the rest of the world started in the early 1980s. Those investments increased significantly in the late 1980s and 1990s, doing so simultaneously in the US, Europe, and the rest of the world. The study also found that the US was the most attractive location for FDI in R&D, attracting 30% of all R&D sites established abroad. A considerable part of the existing literature on FDI argues that it occurs when firms seek to exploit firm-specific capabilities in foreign environments ˚ (Dunning, 1993; Hakanson, 1990; Hymer, 1976; Vernon, 1966), and suggests that a high level of local R&D is carried out primarily to adapt products ˚ to local markets (Hakanson & Nobel, 1993; Howells, 1990). Traditionally, most FDI in manufacturing and marketing is consistent with this category. In the case of R&D, this is often called asset-exploiting R&D (Dunning & Narula, 1995) or home-base-exploiting R&D (HBE R&D) (Kuemmerle, 1999a). HBE R&D is concerned mainly with adapting home-base R&D to local requirements, and is likely to be closely connected to and located in proximity to foreign manufacturing and marketing. Several researchers have described the importance of FDI in R&D for exploiting firm-specific capabilities in foreign environments (Bartlett & Ghoshal, ˚ 1990; Hakanson, 1990; Vernon, 1966). They argue that, as local demand grows increasingly sophisticated, local R&D capabilities are utilized to adapt existing products to local needs. As firms establish manufacturing facilities abroad and assign increasingly complex products to them, locating R&D sites in close proximity to factories becomes a requisite feature. These sites support the transfer of knowledge and prototypes from the firm’s home location to actual manufacturing, especially in those regions where knowledge in particular technology sectors is accumulating rapidly. In addition, companies may also mandate the local business unit to invest in specific new R&D capabilities (Murtha, Lenway, & Hart, 2001). The importance of co-locating firm R&D capabilities with manufacturing operations offshore to serve local demand is also discussed in the industrial geography (Howells, 1990) and technology management literature (Clark & Fujimoto, 1991; Hayes, Wheelwright, & Clark, 1988; Nonaka & Takeuchi, 1995; Von Hippel, 1988). In contrast to the capability-exploiting motive for FDI in R&D, a number of researchers have pointed out that the main driver for FDI in R&D might be a firm’s need to augment its knowledge base (Cantwell, 1991; Dunning, 1998; Florida, 1997; Howells, 1990). This is often called asset-augmenting

R&D (Dunning & Narula, 1995) or home-baseaugmenting R&D (HBA R&D) (Kuemmerle, 1999a). HBA R&D requires the development of links with host-country R&D resources to enhance the knowledge base at home, and to connect more closely to the foreign R&D environment and gain access to local knowledge (Florida, 1997). Wesson (1993) has made a similar argument for FDI in general. These researchers argue that specific nations, and specific regions within them, might be particularly advantageous locations for locating R&D facilities because of the potential for knowledge spillovers from existing R&D and manufacturing networks. Such networks encompass research universities, publicly funded research institutes, and innovative competitors. Feinberg and Gupta (2004) advanced the argument that potential knowledge spillover opportunities are highly relevant for the choice of offshore location. Accordingly, the gains obtained from knowledge activities (R&D, PD and design) are becoming increasingly important (Dunning, 2000). Other externalities that make a country attractive for FDI in R&D involve the availability of supporting industries offering inputs, such as firms that provide laboratory equipment, maintenance or specialized laboratory testing services. A direct extension of these dynamics is the emergence and evolution of global R&D networks that are separate and distinct from R&D FDI or green field R&D investments (see Murtha, 2004). The rapid advances in IT and ICT have greatly enabled the ability of firms to dis-intermediate and externalize innovation processes through outsourcing and relocation of R&D groups and laboratories overseas (Howells, 1990, 1995). Moreover, companies seem increasingly to choose offshore locations independent of geographical distance, and have located their ITO, BPO, and other functions and processes in less developed, lower-cost countries. The particular case of the more recent wave of offshoring innovation should therefore be understood as part of the broader phenomenon of internationalization of R&D (Murtha, 2004). Recalling our earlier definition of offshoring, it appears that R&D offshoring strategies may be evolving from HBA to what we can define as home-base replacing (HBR) of innovation activities and capabilities. This seems to be the case for large MNEs, whose strategies have been discussed more extensively in the IB literature. Smaller and mediumsized companies (SMEs), in particular, may be adopting innovation offshoring strategies that are intended to augment their limited innovation

Journal of International Business Studies

Offshoring of innovation and global race for talent

Arie Y Lewin et al

905

capabilities (HBA). Moreover, in the case of the emergence of a new industry, offshore R&D may not be so much about replacing home-based capabilities as about providing an MNE with geographybased knowledge access in a born-global industry where it might otherwise fail to achieve any position at all (Murtha et al., 2001). In order to explain why firms choose this new form for organizing the innovation process, we rely on the literature on innovation and change, which suggests that environmental forces and managerial practices co-evolve in influencing the adoption of innovation, new organizational forms, and new practices by firms (Lewin & Volberda, 1999; Lewin et al., 1999; Murmann, 2000; Volberda & Lewin, 2003). Along the same lines, it has been argued that internationalization paths and processes should be viewed as the joint outcome of management intentionality, experience-based learning, and institutional forces (Flier, Van den Bosch, & Volberda, 2003; Hutzschenreuter et al., 2007). Following this stream of research, we adopt a co-evolutionary framework and argue that the adoption of innovation offshoring by firms is the result of three types of factors that affect offshoring dynamics and evolution at different levels: (macro) environmental factors; (micro, project level) managerial intentionality (MI); and (meso, firm level) organizational path dependence and learning.

The Environment Reflecting on and testing all the environmental variables that potentially affect decisions by firms to offshore innovation are beyond the scope of this paper. Manning et al. (2008) provide a comprehensive perspective on the co-evolutionary dynamics that are shaping the evolution of offshoring and the related globalization of innovation, identifying macroeconomic forces, domestic and offshore national policies, industry dynamics and firm-level offshoring capabilities driving offshoring decisions. Kshetri (2007) also shows how institutional factors such as regulations, rules, and habits influence offshoring decisions, and Murtha and Lenway (1994) discuss how host governments affect MNEs’ strategies, particularly by promoting offshore outsourcing through subsidies to locally based subcontractors (Murtha, 1991, 1993). In this paper we consider the growing shortage of technical and scientific talent in the US as a constraint on the ability of companies to staff innovation activities with domestically available talent. Policy debates over the growing shortage of

workers with scientific degrees have been increasing in frequency and intensity in the US, and in other countries (Cohen & Zaidi, 2002), reflecting the fact that the shift to a knowledge-based economy results in an increased importance, as well as scarcity, of knowledge workers. Freeman (2005) provides data suggesting that job market and economic opportunities for S&E graduates in the US have worsened compared with those of other high-level occupation fields such as law or medicine. As a consequence, fewer Americans are attracted to these fields of study. However, Freeman (2005) also highlights the fact that S&E job market conditions remain sufficiently good to attract highly qualified immigrants. Moreover, an increasing percentage of S&E PhDs are earned by foreignborn students (39% in 2000 compared with 6% in 1966). This fact by itself would not be a cause for alarm if these foreign students, trained in the US, were staying in the US. But it seems that increasingly they take advantage of the growing work opportunities in their home countries (Chanda & Sreenivasan, 2005; Lieberthal & Lieberthal, 2003; Zweig, 2005). As illustrated in Figure 1, the number of US nationals earning Master and PhD degrees from US S&E schools has been declining steadily, starting in 1995. Conversely, the number of foreign workers on H1B visa, normally 65,000, the majority of whom work in S&E fields, increased steadily between 1998 (135,000) and 2003 (195,000). But in 2003 the US Congress did not renew the H1B visa quota at the 2002 level, and the quota lapsed to the pre-1998 level. Since then, the quota has remained constant at 65,000. The combined result of these two forces is that, in 2006, the number of S&E workers available to work in the US was below the 1995 level. At the same time, US GDP increased between 1995 and 2006 by 43%, suggesting a growing demand for, and a possible shortage of, S&E workers. Economic theory would suggest that wages will adjust so that market conditions will improve, and the shortage will be avoided. However, because the S&E job market has become global, the adjustment, if any, is likely to require much more time than in the period when labor markets were still very much nationally bound. The fact that companies are able to offshore even technically advanced activities allows them to access S&E workers globally to support their domestic operations, which counteracts the pressure on wages in the US and may therefore delay the possible market adjustment. This might be a

Journal of International Business Studies

Offshoring of innovation and global race for talent

Arie Y Lewin et al

906

250000 200000 150000

12000000 10000000 8000000 6000000

100000 4000000 50000 0
1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006

2000000 0

H1B cap

S&E graduates

GDP (constant 2000 US M$)

Figure 1 US science and engineering graduates, and change in H1B visa policy. Data on Masters and PhD degrees in science and engineering come from the US National Science Foundation. Data for H1B visa quota come from the US Citizenship and Immigration Services.

reason why traditional economic indicators such as wages and unemployment rates do not seem to confirm the perceived shortage of S&E (Butz, Bloom, Gross, Kelly, Kofner, & Rippen, 2003). This is also consistent with Farrell et al.’s (2006) findings that the growth of offshoring innovation work will not trigger sudden upward discontinuities in wages and employment in developed nations. However, the prospect of stagnant or declining real wages in science and technology industries in Western countries may negatively affect the balance of inducements and contributions (March & Simon, 1958) for entering S&E careers in the US. Consistent with Oliver (1991), we assume that companies react strategically to consequences of misalignments between their strategic needs and the configuration of the institutional structure and the macro environment in which they are embedded. In the present case, the decline in the number of US nationals (and permanent residents) with advanced degrees in S&E, combined with the H1B visa quota cutback, have caused the misalignment. Firms can react by, for example, escaping the institutional constraints of the country (Witt & Lewin, 2007) and responding to the emerging talent shortage by accessing talent offshore and by learning to globalize their innovation activities. But, consistent with Oliver (1991), we do not expect that all firms will perceive the shortage of talent at the same time, or adjust to it in the same way (Nelson, 1991). Some companies may resign themselves to the situation, hire less-qualified workers, or voice (Hirschman, 1970) their concerns and demand political resolution through their

industry associations or lobbying networks, which indeed did enact the annual H1B quota for highly skilled talent to work in the US. However, agreeing to and implementing radical structural changes in the configuration of national institutional structures that would increase the attractiveness of careers in S&E (e.g., reforming the teaching of mathematics and science in the K-12 educational system) or attract scientists and engineers to work in the US are politically very complex issues to resolve and very bureaucratic to implement, and therefore require much time.3 At the same time as the attractiveness of S&E careers has been diminishing in the US, the talent pool of several offshore countries has been increasing. Ernst (2006) finds that the success of Asia in attracting innovation offshoring results largely from major investments in improving and expanding the talent pool available. For instance, first-year doctoral students in S&E in China increased sixfold between 1995 and 2003 (Freeman, 2005). In parallel, the Chinese government has launched programs targeted at retaining university graduates in China as well as attracting talent from abroad, Chinese and other nationalities (National Science Board, 2004). In fact, instead of an absolute shortage of S&E, which would probably appear in wage and employment statistics more than it currently does, the US may be facing a relative shortage of technical skills compared with worldwide supply. In other words, even though companies may be able to find the S&E talent in the US required for their current needs, unless other constraints such as IP issues deter them from doing so, they might

Journal of International Business Studies

Offshoring of innovation and global race for talent

Arie Y Lewin et al

907

prefer investing in countries where the relative pool of talent is larger and/or because of the opportunity to grow their S&E workforce as their business expands in the future. Another consideration for some companies is the realization that the countries with a large potential supply of S&E professionals also represent fast-growing middle-class markets that many US firms seek to enter. Learning to source and manage S&E activities in these countries might constitute a longer-term advantage as companies utilize their new local PD capabilities to start developing products adapted to the needs of both these local markets and their home markets.

Managerial Intentionality Hutzschenreuter et al. (2007) present MI as a key factor underlying the observed heterogeneity in industry performance, internationalization paths, and innovation activities. According to the authors, MI encompasses different bundling of firm-specific strategies, such as growth strategies to become global, orientation towards innovative (early mover) or mimetic (follower) internationalization strategies, managing adaptive tension (internal rate of change), use of slack resources, and attitude towards employee creativity and initiative-taking. The idea behind the concept of MI is that managers have certain strategic objectives in mind that they translate into certain decisions, which influence firm-level outcomes. In the area of offshoring, many different strategic objectives have been recognized as playing a role. Dominant conventional wisdom has been that the primary driver for offshoring IT centers, IT applications, and business processes is to realize cost savings from labor arbitrage (see, e.g., Dossani & Kenney, 2004; ´ Khan & Islam, 2006; Quelin & Duhamel, 2003). However, Lewin and Peeters (2006a, b) report a notable evolution in the strategic drivers with the emergence of company growth, access to qualified personnel and service improvement as increasingly important objectives leading firms to initiate offshoring projects. Several studies also show that the importance of cost savings as a driver of offshoring tends to decline as companies gain experience with offshoring and experiment with offshoring of increasingly complex and advanced activities. For instance, Pedersen and Jensen (2007) show that cost factors determine the initial decision to offshore but do not affect subsequent evolution towards offshoring of more advanced activities, confirming earlier findings by Maskell, Pedersen, Petersen, and Dick-Nielsen (2007) that companies

evolve from seeking cost reductions to knowledgeseeking objectives. Similarly, Dossani and Kenney (2003) illustrate the change in companies’ mindset, from cost to quality. Recent work by Bunyaratavej, Hahn, and Doh (2007) has also demonstrated that cost is not as important as the mass media might suggest, but that access to skilled and qualified personnel is a substantial driver of services offshoring among firms. They argue and find support for the notion that firms seek to obtain parity in terms of the quality of the onshore workforce, but at some level of discounted wages. However, since Bunyaratavej et al. (2007) studied actual offshoring activities rather than managerial intentions, the model developed in the present paper, which involves managerial perceptions regarding access to qualified personnel by discrete offshoring projects, provides new insight regarding possible divergences between managerial intentions and firm-level actions. In this paper we investigate four main types of firm-specific objectives as expressions of managers’ intentionality that may determine decisions to offshore innovation and PD projects (beyond cost savings): access to qualified personnel, accelerating growth, increasing speed to market, and becoming global players. Ernst (2006) argues that competing in the emerging global market for knowledge workers has become a strategic priority, especially for high-tech firms; this competition creates new sources of talent, which of necessity must be tapped in order to optimize human capital. Combined with the evidence on the tight labor market for S&E graduates in the US, this suggests that the need to find and recruit qualified personnel is likely to be an important determinant of the decision to offshore PD work. Similarly, as a means to increasing the pool of resources (talent) available to a firm, offshoring can alleviate some constraints that are potentially impeding the achievement of the firm’s growth objectives. The growth strategy of a firm may involve expansion of existing businesses and entering new markets. For science- and technologybased companies, in particular, exploiting new market opportunities often requires access to engineers and scientists capable of developing new products and technologies, or of adapting existing ones. Companies with significant growth objectives may therefore decide to offshore some of their PD activities to countries where such talent is in relatively abundant supply. The pressure to increase speed to market with new or improved

Journal of International Business Studies

Offshoring of innovation and global race for talent

Arie Y Lewin et al

908

products faster than the competition may also affect companies’ offshoring strategies. Speed to market can be improved by having access to a flexible pool of qualified engineers necessary for responding to changes in demand and for exploiting market and technological opportunities, as well as by new organizational arrangements that permit development around the clock (most PD teams typically work the day shift in the US). Deploying teams of qualified engineers offshore has been shown to provide flexibility for scaling PD efforts up or down as needed, and to allow companies to manage PD processes using a ‘‘follow the sun’’ schedule. Finally, internationalizing innovation through offshoring leads firms to globalize their activities further as they tap new geographic knowledge clusters (diverse labor pools, specific expertise) anywhere in the world.

to explain firms’ sourcing decisions (e.g., Calantone & Stanko, 2007; Murray & Kotabe, 1999; Murtha, 1991, 1993; Pisano, 1990). The argument is that firms with no experience of R&D outsourcing are likely to continue sourcing R&D internally, because experience with internal sourcing reduces the cost of performing the R&D activities internally (Coase, 1937). Similarly, it may be risky and costly for these firms to start experimenting with a new form of R&D sourcing. The same reasoning applies to offshoring decisions. Finally, firms’ past experience may also influence the range of possibilities that managers consider when making offshoring decisions (Hutzschenreuter et al., 2007).

METHODOLOGY
The Offshoring Research Network (ORN) This research uses data collected in the context of the ORN project on offshoring of technical and administrative work. ORN was launched in 2004 at Duke University Center for International Business Education and Research (CIBER), The Fuqua School of Business.4 In 2004 and 2005 ORN focused on surveying the offshoring practices of US-based companies. In 2006 the online survey was extended to involve research partners from EU universities5 that recruit companies in their country to participate in the survey, as well as conduct case studies. At the core of the ORN project is the contextual commonality of the survey, the centralized online administration of the survey (in native business language of a country where necessary) each year. The core survey enables tracking of the evolution of offshoring practices involving seven main areas: the functions offshored; choice of offshore location and rationale for this choice; type of service delivery model used (captive, third party, hybrid); strategic drivers of offshoring; perceived risks; performance metrics; and future offshoring plans (18–36 months out). A unique feature of the ORN survey is its focus on surveying the specific offshore project implementations rather than companies’ general experience with offshoring. In practice, this means that every specific function that a company (sometimes involving multiple respondents from same company) has offshored in a particular location is identified by the year it was launched, and is treated as a separate observation. This survey design results in a very fine-grained database that enables an analysis of offshoring dynamics across various administrative and technical functions located in a

Path Dependence It is unlikely that offshoring decisions will exactly reflect a manager’s vision of what should or should not be offshored at any moment in time. Offshoring decisions are also constrained by the offshoring journey a firm has followed in the past, and are influenced by past learning on how to manage offshoring projects. In other words, whether a firm does have some past experience with offshoring or not, and the kind of functions or processes previously offshored, serve to further enable or constrain future offshoring decisions. The path dependence of offshoring practices has already been recognized by several authors. For instance, Lewin and Peeters (2006a), Maskell et al. (2007) and Pedersen and Jensen (2007) describe the adoption of offshoring by firms as a progressive learning-by-doing process through which firms offshore increasingly advanced activities, including innovation activities. This experience-building process that leads firms to eventually offshore innovation confirms earlier research by Pisano (1990), who argued that R&D procurement decisions are driven in part by historical factors. Three main reasons can explain the role of companies’ past experience in determining their offshoring decisions. First, the behavioral and evolutionary perspectives of firms’ practices suggest that, because of the search rules (Cyert & March, 1963) and routines (Nelson, 1991; Nelson & Winter, 1982) normally used by firms, a history of internal R&D sourcing is likely to lead to the continuation of internal R&D sourcing, even if the environment changes incrementally. Second, several authors have used transaction costs theory

Journal of International Business Studies

Offshoring of innovation and global race for talent

Arie Y Lewin et al

909

wide range of countries or regions of the world, across industries, and across types of delivery model (captive, third party or hybrid). Finally, the ORN database includes both companies that already offshore and companies that have considered offshoring but have not yet initiated the offshoring of any application.

Data The present paper uses data from the 2005 and 2006 ORN annual surveys of US companies. The database comprises 253 companies and 880 different offshore implementations, most already operating and some in preparation at the time of the survey. Launch dates of offshore implementations range from 1990 to 2006, and are available for 476 implementations. The sample comprises both large and small companies operating in various industries (see Table 1). Median company employment is 1750 employees, and the average company employment is 22,691 employees. The analysis of the ORN survey classifies offshore implementations into six main functional categories (see Table 2): Administrative (finance and accounting, human resources, legal services, and other back office activities); Contact Centers (call centers, help desks, and technical support); IT (information-technology-related activities); Procurement; PD (R&D, engineering services and product design, including software design); and Marketing and Sales. IT applications were among

Table 1

Sample descriptive statistics

Percentage of companies Firm size (no. of employees) o500 501 to 2000 42000 Industry Business/IT services FMCG Financial services Health/biotech/pharma Manufacturing Other services Professional services Software and programming Technology

No. of offshore implementations

24 8 68

208 68 604

11 3 17 4 15 14 2 5 29

95 28 152 35 135 123 12 48 252

the earliest to be offshored, and account for the highest share of implementations in the sample (26%). This may also be a direct consequence of the positive service and quality reputation of India, which continues to be the most preferred offshore location (specifically as regards IT; see Henley, 2006). More surprising is the finding that 26% of offshore implementations involve PD activities. This suggests that companies are offshoring innovative activities that constitute the core of a firm differentiation and value creation strategy. Administrative activities also represent a large share of surveyed implementations (22%). Despite the large coverage in the press and popular media, contact centers represent only 17% of offshore implementations (Table 2 and Figure 2). ORN data show that ‘‘access to qualified personnel’’ has emerged as the second most important strategic driver of offshoring. On a five-point Likert scale it is rated important or very important (4 and 5) for 77% of offshore implementations surveyed. Similarly, the survey reveals that the availability of sufficient talent pools and adequate expertise have also emerged as very important reasons why US firms select particular offshore locations. The particular strategic objectives underlying offshoring decisions vary, depending on the type of function offshored (see Table 3). The access to qualified personnel objective is the second most important for both PD and non-PD offshore implementations. But the percentage of implementations for which this objective is rated important or very important is higher for innovation-related offshoring. In fact, this pattern of similar ranking but higher relative importance for PD implementations applies to the other major strategic drivers of offshoring as well: non-labor cost savings, growth, global strategy, competitive pressures, and speed to market. Finally, industries differ in their proportion of PD offshoring, as well as offshore countries differing in their ability to attract this type of offshoring (Table 4). In the software and programming industry almost 50% offshore implementations concern PD. In the business and IT services, health/biotech/pharma, manufacturing, and technology industries about one-third of offshore implementations are in PD. The very high percentage for the professional services industry should not be extrapolated too far, given the very low number of observations. Finally, financial services and other services, although actively involved in offshoring, have undertaken only a few implementations related to PD.

Journal of International Business Studies

Offshoring of innovation and global race for talent

Arie Y Lewin et al

910

Table 2

Distribution of offshore implementations across functions and locations

Function Product development Engineering services R&D Product design IT Administrative Finance and accounting Human resources Other back office Legal services Contact centers Procurement Marketing and sales

Percentage of total (N) 26 (230) 11 10 5 26 (227) 22 (196) 12 5 4 1 17 (147) 5 (48) 4 (32)

Location India China Latin America Philippines Western Europe Other Asia Eastern Europe Canada Other locations Mexico

Percentage of total (N) 42 11 8 8 6 6 6 5 4 4 (366) (98) (74) (71) (55) (54) (51) (40) (36) (35)

50% 50%

40%

36% 35%

30%

31%

20%

10%

11%

0% 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 Administrative Product Development Call Center/Help Desk Procurement IT

Figure 2

Cumulative percentage of firms initiating offshoring of functional category (1990–2006).

Regarding offshore locations, the proportion of PD implementations out of total offshore implementations is the highest for China (44%). Other Asian countries also attract proportionately more innovation offshoring than other locations. Weakest regions in terms of PD offshoring are the Philippines, Mexico, Canada, and Latin America. Contrarily to China, Mexico does not seem to have been able yet to upgrade its capabilities to move from manufacturing production offshoring to higher-value activities in PD.

Empirical Validation To empirically test possible determinants of firms’ decision to offshore PD work, we specify a model that estimates the probability of offshoring PD projects as a function of a series of variables related to the firms’ environment, past experience, and managers’ strategic objectives, and a set of control variables that account for differences in firms’ size and industry, and in location and service delivery model of offshore implementations. The equation is estimated as a binary logit model, where the

Journal of International Business Studies

Offshoring of innovation and global race for talent

Arie Y Lewin et al

911

Table 3

Strategic drivers of offshore implementations (percentages of 4 or 5 on five-point Likert scale)

Product development implementations (%) Labor cost savings Access to qualified personnel Other cost savings Growth strategy Part of larger global strategy Competitive pressures Increasing speed to market Improving service levels Business process redesign Adopting an industry practice Differentiation strategy Access to new markets Enhancing system redundancy 91 81 80 77 75 72 57 50 48 41 36 32 28

Non-product development implementations (%) 90 71 69 69 59 59 41 52 51 42 26 15 27

Chi-square test

0.088 5.961 5.195 3.600 8.280 8.626 12.209 0.176 0.411 0.050 3.738 21.127 0.073

Pr¼0.766 Pr¼0.015 Pr¼0.023 Pr¼0.058 Pr¼0.004 Pr¼0.003 Pr¼0.000 Pr¼0.675 Pr¼0.521 Pr¼0.823 Pr¼0.053 Pr¼0.000 Pr¼0.787

Table 4

Percentage (and frequency) of offshore implementations by industry and offshore location

Product development implementations Industry Business/IT services FMCG Financial services Health/biotech/pharma Manufacturing Other services Professional services Software and programming Technology Total Country India China Latin America Philippines Western Europe Other Asian regions Eastern Europe Canada Mexico Other regions Total

Non-product development implementations

Percentage of product development implementations

14% 1% 7% 4% 20% 7% 3% 10% 34% 100%

(31) (1) (16) (10) (45) (17) (8) (23) (79) (230)

10% 4% 21% 4% 14% 16% 1% 4% 26% 100%

(64) (27) (136) (25) (90) (106) (4) (25) (173) (650)

33 4 11 29 33 14 67 48 31

43% 19% 6% 3% 6% 8% 6% 3% 2% 4% 100%

(100) (43) (13) (7) (14) (18) (13) (7) (4) (11) (230)

41% 8% 9% 10% 6% 6% 6% 5% 5% 4% 100%

(266) (55) (61) (64) (41) (36) (38) (33) (31) (25) (650)

27 44 18 10 25 33 25 18 11 31

dependent variable reflects the type of function offshored – whether PD (R&D, engineering services, or product design) or not. The environment in which firms operate influences their offshoring decisions in many ways. In

this paper we study the effect of the supply of technical talent in the US, consisting of US S&E graduates and foreign workers on H1B visas, on the decision to offshore innovative work and services. In order to take into account the declining

Journal of International Business Studies

Offshoring of innovation and global race for talent

Arie Y Lewin et al

912

supply of highly skilled scientists and engineers, possibly leading to increasing PD offshoring, we use the number of S&E Master and PhD degrees and the level of the H1B visa quota on the year the offshore implementation was initiated, in logarithm (ln SEH1B).6 Data on graduates and visa quota come from the US National Science Foundation and the US Citizenship and Immigration Services, respectively. We expect the variable of the supply of technical talent to have a negative impact on PD offshoring decisions: that is, the larger the pool of technical talent available in the US, the lower the probability of offshoring PD. To test for the effect of MI as a determinant of the probability to offshore PD, we use the ORN survey responses related to the strategic drivers that led companies to initiate their various offshore projects.7 We selected seven MI strategic drivers on the basis of their importance for offshoring PD and non-PD implementations (see Table 3, which also reports the chi-square test, and the probability that the proportions of 4 and 5 answers for PD and nonPD are significantly different) and on the basis of previous research reported in extant literature. The seven strategic drivers are: (1) access to qualified personnel offshore (QUAL_PERS); (2) realization of labor cost savings (COST_LABOR); (3) realization of other types of cost savings (COST_OTHER); (4) contribution to firm business growth plans (GROWTH); (5) contribution to firm global strategy (GLOBAL); (6) accelerating speed to market (SPEED); and (7) response to competitive pressures (COMPETITION) We expect all strategic drivers to have a positive impact on the probability to offshore PD work, except for labor cost savings and competitive pressures, which involve short-term strategies as compared with longer-term innovation strategies offshore. We also expect the probability of offshoring PD to depend on the number of PD projects the company has already offshored in the past (PAST_EXP_PD). The learning process of offshoring involves overcoming crucial coordination and knowledge flow challenges central to effective innovative activities. Firms that have already offshored PD activities are

assumed to have developed managerial and coordination competences that increase the probability of deciding to offshore more innovation-related projects. Another important aspect of offshoring strategies is the choice of delivery model for undertaking activities outside the domestic boundaries. The mode of entry in an international market has been extensively discussed in the literature (e.g., Dunning, 1993). A firm basically has four choices when establishing new R&D facilities abroad: establish a greenfield site; build up new capabilities in a subsidiary not previously involved in R&D; make an acquisition; or enter into a joint venture. Caves (1996) argues that MNEs will refrain from FDI through joint ventures when the protection of intangible assets is important to the firm. Mansfield (1984) found that firms are more hesitant to transfer process technology abroad than product technology, because it is more difficult to protect process technology from appropriation by local entities, and because process technology often manifests unique firm capabilities whereas product technology represents only the outcome of these capabilities. On the other hand, acquisitions or captive facilities bring a high risk of attrition of assets, such as human assets, which are highly mobile. The ORN survey includes questions about the delivery model used for each project that was offshored: captive, outsourced to various service providers (local, same nationality, international), or joint venture. Quinn (2000) argues that tapping the knowledge and capabilities of external organizations has become crucial for firms to stay ahead of the innovation race, leading them to outsource more and more elements of their innovation value chain. The externalization of PD is increasingly being extended to offshore destinations. However, the ORN survey reveals that, owing to concerns about a possible loss of control over strategically important activities, most companies offshoring PD activities favor offshoring through a fully owned subsidiary – what is also referred to as the captive model of offshoring – over the offshore outsourcing model. But not all firms have the resources and scale to launch a captive organization offshore, which can influence the decision to offshore PD or not. To control for this possible effect we introduce in the model a dummy variable that takes the value 1 if the offshore implementation is a captive organization, and 0 otherwise (Captive).

Journal of International Business Studies

Offshoring of innovation and global race for talent

Arie Y Lewin et al

913

Table 5

Construction of variables

Variable Dependent PD

Construction

Dummy ¼1 for product development implementations (R&D, product design, and engineering services), 0 for other offshore implementations.

Explanatory ln SEH1B PAST_EXP_PD QUAL_PERS COST_LABOR COST_OTHER SPEED GROWTH GLOBAL COMPETITION

Logarithm of sum of number of US nationals science and engineering graduates (Masters and PhDs) and of H1B visa quota in year offshore implementation is launched. Number of existing product development offshore implementations of the company when the new offshore implementation is launched. 1–5 score attributed to ‘‘Access to qualified personnel’’ as a strategic driver of offshore implementation, as reported in ORN survey. 1–5 score attributed to ‘‘Labor cost savings’’ as a strategic driver of offshore implementation, as reported in ORN survey. 1–5 score attributed to ‘‘Other cost savings’’ as a strategic driver of offshore implementation, as reported in ORN survey. 1–5 score attributed to ‘‘Increasing speed to market’’ as a strategic driver of offshore implementation, as reported in ORN survey. 1–5 score attributed to ‘‘Growth strategy’’ as a strategic driver of offshore implementation, as reported in ORN survey. 1–5 score attributed to ‘‘Part of a larger global strategy’’ as a strategic driver of offshore implementation, as reported in ORN survey. 1–5 score attributed to ‘‘Competitive pressures’’ as a strategic driver of offshore implementation, as reported in ORN survey.

Controls ln Empl Captive D2003 Industryp (p ¼ 1 to 7)

Countryq (q ¼ 1 to 9)

Logarithm of number of employees in the company in year offshore implementation is launched. Dummy ¼ 1 for captive offshore implementations, 0 otherwise. Dummy ¼ 1 for offshore implementations launched in 2003 or after, 0 otherwise. Seven dummy variables representing industry of operation of the company: business/IT services, financial services (reference group), health/biotech/pharma, manufacturing, other services, professional services, software and programming, and technology. Nine dummy variables representing the location of the offshore implementation: India, China, Latin America (reference group), Philippines, Western Europe, Other Asian regions, Eastern Europe, Canada, Mexico, Other regions.

In the model, we also control for firm size and industry, and for the region where the offshore implementation is located. The size of the firm and the industry in which it operates is assumed to influence the relevance of pursuing a PD offshoring strategy, as well as the feasibility of such a strategy given the organizational challenges associated with operating geographically dispersed innovation teams. Size is expressed as the logarithm of the number of employees (ln Empl). Seven industry dummies (Industryp) are used as control variables in the regressions. Moreover, some countries are more likely than others to attract innovation offshoring projects. As discussed above, the offshoring decision is influenced by location advantage, such as national investments by offshore countries in the

development of pools of qualified workers. But offshore countries are not equally interested in making such investments, or equally effective in developing such talent pools. ORN survey data reveal important differences in the proportion of PD projects across countries (see Table 5), which will be controlled for in the regressions using nine country dummies (Countryq). The last control variable accounts for a possible change in the decisions to offshore innovation activities starting in 2003, and which is not accounted for by the other variables of the model. Starting in 2003, some companies are making changes in their sourcing strategy compared with earlier years for two reasons. First, the new H1B visa regulation saw the quota decreased from 195,000 to 65,000; and

Journal of International Business Studies

Offshoring of innovation and global race for talent

Arie Y Lewin et al

914

ProbðPDÞ ¼ a þ b ln SEH1B þ cPAST EXP PD þ dQUAL PERS þ eCOST LABOR þ f COST OTHER þ gSPEED þ hGROWTH þ iGLOBAL þ jCOMPETITION þ k ln Empl þ lCaptive þ mD2003 X þ np Industryp p¼1!7 q¼1!9

Table 5 provides a detailed explanation of the construction of the variables. Descriptive statistics and correlations between the explanatory variables are reported in Table 6.8

RESULTS Table 7 reports the estimation results for Eq. (1). Column 1 shows estimated coefficients for the control variables, followed by odds ratios in column 2. The coefficients of the full model with control variables and explanatory variables are in column 3, followed by odds ratios (column 4). Of the three types of factors included in the model – supply of S&E graduates, past experience with offshoring PD, and the set of variables representing MI – only the third is statistically significant. In particular, among the strategic drivers of offshoring, access to qualified personnel, increase speed to market and reducing other costs (non-labor costs) have a positive impact on the probability of offshoring PD, whereas concerns about labor cost savings and offshoring for growth objectives decrease the probability of offshoring PD. Offshoring as part of a global strategy and responding to competitive pressure have the expected sign but not a very high probability of impacting on the probability of offshoring PD (column 3). The negative and significant coefficient of labor cost savings and the positive and significant coefficient of other cost savings clarify the role of labor arbitrage opportunities in explaining offshoring of technical and administrative work. The

Descriptive statistics and correlations for explanatory variables

1 Obs. Mean s.d. Min. Max.

2

3

4

5

6

7

þ

X

oq Countryq þ e

ð1Þ

880 0.261 0.440 0 1 487 12.172 0.311 11.82 12.56 487 0.585 1.509 0 10 649 3.823 0.980 1 5 652 4.471 0.823 1 5 475 3.844 1.099 1 5 651 3.218 1.310 1 5 650 3.851 1.054 1 5 471 3.446 1.379 1 5 648 3.650 1.140 1 5 913 8.397 3.252 0 12.74 808 0.490 0.500 0 1 487 0.581 0.494 0 1 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 PD ln SEH1B PAST_EXP_PD QUAL_PERS COST_LABOR COST_OTHER SPEED GROWTH GLOBAL COMPETITION ln Empl Captive D2003

1.00 À0.08 1.00 0.08 À0.19* 1.00 0.10* 0.03 À0.03 1.00 À0.08 0.09 À0.23* À0.05 1.00 0.38* 1.00 0.11 0.14 À0.07 À0.04 0.13* À0.05 0.05 0.09 À0.14* 0.01 1.00 0.07 0.09 À0.13* 0.23* 0.12* 0.27* 0.21* 1.00 0.11 0.12 0.13 0.21* 0.02 0.27* 0.43* 0.32* 1.00 0.10 0.028 À0.13* 0.11* 0.12* 0.30* 0.06 0.20* 0.26* 1.00 À0.20* 0.05 0.17* 0.10 0.19* À0.01 0.04 À0.01 0.24* 0.01 1.00 0.12* 0.14* 0.10 0.04 À0.07 0.10 0.05 0.18* 0.24* 0.09 0.12* 1.00 À0.02 À0.43* 0.23* 0.07 À0.12 À0.14 À0.02 À0.07 À0.03 À0.00 À0.04 À0.14* 1.00
*Significance level: o1%.

second, the American economy resumed its economic growth after 2 years of economic recession that followed 9/11. The estimated equation is shown below, where a is the constant intercept and e is the error term:

Journal of International Business Studies

Table 6

Variable

8

9

10

11

12

13

Offshoring of innovation and global race for talent

Arie Y Lewin et al

915

Table 7

Estimation results of logit model and odds ratios. Dependent variable: probability of offshoring product development projects

Coefficient (1) ln SEH1B PAST_EXP_PD QUAL_PERS COST_LABOR COST_OTHER SPEED GROWTH GLOBAL COMPETITION Controls ln Empl Captive D2003 Business/IT services Health/biotech/pharma Manufacturing Professional services Other services Software and programming Technology China India Canada Mexico Philippines Eastern Europe Western Europe Other Asian regions Other regions Constant N LR w2 Prob.4w2 Log likelihood McKelvey and Zavoina R2 McFadden’s R2 Adj. McFadden’s R2

Odds ratio (2)

Coefficient (3) À0.202 0.051 0.514** À0.475* 1.075*** 0.548*** À0.443** 0.145 À0.194 (0.684) (0.134) (0.214) (0.245) (0.266) (0.151) (0.198) (0.177) (0.169)

Odds ratio (4) 0.817 1.052 1.672** 0.622* 2.931*** 1.730*** 0.642** 1.156 0.824 (0.559) (0.141) (0.357) (0.152) (0.779) (0.261) (0.127) (0.205) (0.139)

À0.145*** 0.755*** À0.192 2.053*** 1.289* 1.641*** 2.319*** 0.546 1.615*** 1.056*** 1.623*** 0.587 0.774 À0.146 À1.959* 0.024 0.806 1.184* 0.116

(0.038) (0.263) (0.258) (0.463) (0.673) (0.469) (0.813) (0.488) (0.538) (0.402) (0.546) (0.482) (0.752) (0.916) (1.127) (0.698) (0.612) (0.632) (0.878)

0.865*** 2.127*** 0.826 7.793*** 3.630* 5.163*** 10.164*** 1.726 5.028*** 2.875*** 5.066*** 1.798 2.169 0.864 0.141* 1.025 2.239 3.266* 1.118

(0.000) (0.004) (0.4579) (0.000) (0.055) (0.001) (0.004) (0.263) (0.003) (0.009) (0.003) (0.224) (0.303) (0.873) (0.082) (0.972) (0.188) (0.061) (0.899)

À0.112* (0.063) 0.928** (0.390) À0.184 (0.460) 2.656*** (0.685) 2.547*** (0.907) 1.756** (0.773) — 1.507** (0.721) 4.359*** (1.203) 1.802*** (0.663) 0.712 (0.761) 0.056 (0.668) 0.853 (1.154) À0.844 (1.349) À2.009 (1.293) 0.115 (0.922) 0.265 (0.878) À0.039 (0.910) 0.149 (1.096) À4.184 (8.575) 315 107.94 0.0000 À123.440 0.540 0.3042 0.146

0.894* (0.075) 2.530** (0.017) 0.832 (0.689 14.237*** (0.000) 12.767*** (0.005) 5.792** (0.023) — 4.514** (0.037) 78.143*** (0.000) 6.064*** (0.007) 2.039 (0.349) 1.058 (0.933) 2.346 (0.460) 0.430 (0.532) 0.134 (0.120) 1.122 (0.901) 1.304 (0.761) 0.962 (0.966) 1.160 (0.892)

À1.827*** (0.572) 476 103.64 0.0000 À221.205 0.369 0.1898 0.117

Standard errors in brackets. Significance levels: ***o1%, **o5%, *o10%, +o15%. The dummy for professional services has been dropped owing to collinearity.

analysis indicates that offshoring is a strategy for increasing cost efficiency also for PD activities, but not through labor arbitrage. Combined with the result of a positive and significant coefficient for the access to qualified personnel variable, our analysis suggests that labor costs savings and the need to offshore in order to access qualified personnel are two distinct strategies that companies do not confuse. Cost-savings opportunities are an important driver for many offshore

implementations, but when firms need to support their PD strategies in the face of talent scarcity, labor cost considerations are less important relative to accessing talent anywhere. The significant negative coefficient of the growth strategy variable indicates that although some companies (smaller ones in particular) offshore PD work to support their expansion plans, offshoring of innovation activities is a separate strategy from firm growth strategies. One possible explanation is

Journal of International Business Studies

Offshoring of innovation and global race for talent

Arie Y Lewin et al

916

that growth strategies require a shorter time investment than innovation projects, especially basic research, which requires more time. Innovative processes and activities normally have longerterm time horizons, whereas growth is more likely to have shorter time horizons. Therefore, if companies are focusing on shorter-term growth objectives, it is less likely that they will attend to offshoring PD activities. The positive and significant coefficient of speed to market validates the hypothesis that companies offshore PD activities as a way of speeding up their innovation process and introducing products on the market quicker, by means of higher flexibility to scale PD efforts up and down and of around-theclock PD processes. In order to interpret the results better and discuss the magnitude of the estimated effects, we included the odds ratio calculations (column 4). The significant ratios can be interpreted as the increase/ reduction in the likelihood of offshoring PD over other non-PD projects when the importance of a particular strategic driver increases by one point on the five-point scale. We therefore expect a onepoint increase in importance attributed to labor cost savings objectives to result in a 38% reduction in the probability of offshoring PD over other types of function. However, efficiency improvements (other cost savings) are significant in explaining offshoring of PD, since higher non-labor cost savings objectives are associated with a massive increase in the probability of offshoring PD (odds ratio of almost 300%). Similarly, a one-point increase in access to qualified personnel or in increasing speed to market objectives increases the probability of offshoring PD over other types of functions by 67 and 73%, respectively. Finally, a one-point increase in the importance of growth objectives diminishes the likelihood of offshoring PD over other functions by 36%. The negative effect of firm size indicates that smaller firms have a higher probability of offshoring PD projects, suggesting that offshoring enables smaller, more agile companies to augment their innovation capabilities (HBA) more than larger and less flexible companies. The dummy for captive model of offshoring is positive and highly significant. The odds ratio clearly shows that captive operations are much more likely to be involved in PD projects than outsourced operations. This result supports the argument that innovative activities require a higher degree of coordination and stronger governance structure

that facilitates knowledge flow and integration and reduces the risk of IP leakage, all of which is made easier in fully owned subsidiaries compared with outsourcing. The sector dummies indicate that, compared with financial services, all other sectors have a higher probability of offshoring PD, with the exception of other services. In terms of destinations, there is some evidence that, compared with Latin America, PD projects are more likely to be offshored to China and other Asian regions, but less to the Philippines. The diagnostics at the bottom of Table 7 indicate that, overall, the model is meaningful (LR w2). Consistent with a co-evolutionary framework, a possible reason for the lack of significance of the other independent variables may be that each variable explains a different level of influence in the decision to offshore PD. MI is measured at the level of the specific project that is offshored (our unit of analysis). Past experience is a company-level variable, and the supply of S&E graduates is an exogenous environmental level factor. However, all three elements are relevant to the model that we specified, and are consistent with understanding offshoring as a multilevel phenomenon. In order to explore further the role of the two other variables (supply of S&E graduates and company experience with offshoring PD), we re-ran the regressions and omitted the MI variables (Table 8). From a methodological point of view, regressing the probability of offshoring PD on company experience and the exogenous supply of S&E also overcomes the common method problem of using only samesurvey items (MI items). Table 8 shows that the domestic supply of scientists and engineers (US citizens with postgraduate degrees in S&E, and foreign workers with H1B visas) has a significant negative effect on the probability of offshoring PD (column 1), supporting our conjecture that the lower the supply of skilled and experienced workers in the US, the higher the probability of offshoring R&D, engineering services and product design. Furthermore, consistent with the importance of cumulative learning and acquisition of idiosyncratic knowledge as a consequence of implementing and managing PD activities offshore, past experience with offshoring PD increases the probability that companies will further offshore PD (column 2). When supply of S&E and past experience variables are simultaneously introduced in the model (column 3), the results for the main variables and controls are maintained. However, the structural dummy for 2003 becomes significant with a

Journal of International Business Studies

Offshoring of innovation and global race for talent

Arie Y Lewin et al

917

Table 8

Estimation results of logit model. Dependent variable: probability of offshoring product development projects

1 ln SEH1B PAST_EXP_PD Controls ln Empl Captive D2003 Business/IT services Health/biotech/pharma Manufacturing Professional services Other services Software and programming Technology China India Canada Mexico Philippines Eastern Europe Western Europe Other Asian regions Other regions Constant N LR w2 Prob.4w2 Log likelihood McKelvey and Zavoina R2 McFadden’s R2 Adj. McFadden’s R2 À0.759* (0.4566) [0.468]

2
+

3 À0.668 (0.463) [0.513] 0.177* (0.094) [1.194]

0.192** (0.0934) [1.212]

À0.146*** 0.768*** À0.397 1.938*** 1.083+ 1.574*** 2.219*** 0.477 1.577*** 1.039*** 1.665*** 0.599 0.800 À0.142 À1.984* 0.114 0.794 1.170* 0.028

(0.038) (0.265) (0.289) (0.469) (0.683) (0.472) (0.826) (0.490) (0.540) (0.404) (0.550) (0.484) (0.750) (0.920) (1.128) (0.698) (0.617) (0.638) (0.887)

À0.156*** 0.669** À0.352 2.025*** 1.286* 1.474*** 2.3441*** 0.570 1.560*** 1.060*** 1.536*** 0.563 0.737 À0.103 À2.320** 0.009 0.726 1.151* 0.019

(0.038) (0.267) (0.272) (0.467) (0.680) (0.481) (0.816) (0.493) (0.543) (0.407) (0.548) (0.483) (0.752) (0.915) (1.161) (0.704) (0.617) (0.635) (0.892)

À0.156*** 0.683** À0.523* 1.925*** 1.100+ 1.425*** 0.506 2.250*** 1.533*** 1.042** 1.581*** 0.576 0.767 À0.102 À2.303** 0.094 0.721 1.144* À0.050

(0.038) (0.268) (0.299) (0.472) (0.690) (0.483) (0.494) (0.826) (0.545) (0.408) (0.552) (0.485) (0.751) (0.918) (1.158) (0.704) (0.620) (0.641) (0.898)

7.560 (5.666) 476 106.47 0.0000 À219.792 0.379 0.1950 0.118

À1.652*** (0.575) 476 107.95 0.0000 À219.050 0.387 0.1977 0.121

6.592 (5.740) 476 110.07 0.0000 À217.993 0.393 0.2016 0.121

Standard errors in brackets. Odds ratios in square brackets. Significance levels: ***o1%, **o5%, *o10%, +o15%.

negative sign, indicating that projects implemented in 2003 and the following years have a 41% lower probability (the odds ratio is 0.593) to be focused on PD relative to other functions. Considering the trends observed in Figure 1 and this last result, the sample was divided into two subsamples and the equations for implementations launched between 1990 and 2002, and for implementations launched between 2003 and 2006, were estimated separately.9 Recall that the US Congress changed the H1B quota in 2003 (a decrease from 195,000 to 65,000) and the US economy began to rebound after 2 years of stagnation. These two factors represent significant exogenous changes affecting the environment within which US firms operate. The results for the model estimated over the two subperiods, pre- and post-2003, are

reported in Table 9. Owing to the limited size of the two subsamples, the number of industry and country dummies was reduced to control for differences between the two most important locations of offshore implementations (India and China) and other possible offshore regions, and for differences between technological and nontechnological industries. The supply of S&E graduates and company past experience with offshoring are not significant in the subperiod analyses (same results as for the full model). However, with regard to the central question of this paper – the effect of accessing qualified personnel and sourcing skilled workers offshore – a striking difference between the two subsamples emerges. Although this strategic objective was not an important driver of firms’ decisions to offshore PD up to 2002, it becomes

Journal of International Business Studies

Offshoring of innovation and global race for talent

Arie Y Lewin et al

918

Table 9 Estimation results of logit model (pre- and post-2003 subsamples). Dependent variable: probability of offshoring product development projects

1990–2002 ln SEH1B PAST_EXP_PD QUAL_PERS COST_LABOR COST_OTHER SPEED GROWTH GLOBAL COMPETITION Controls ln Empl Captive India China tech_ind Constant N LR w2 Prob.4w2 Log likelihood McKelvey and Zavoina R2 McFadden’s R2 Adj. McFadden’s R2 À0.220 À0.093 À0.124 À0.780** 0.679** 0.678*** À0.514* À0.181 À0.316 (1.042) (0.319) (0.272) (0.360) (0.329) (0.260) (0.308) (0.250) (0.231)

Odds ratio 0.803 0.912 0.883 0.458** 1.973** 1.969*** 0.598* 0.834 0.729 (0.833) (0.771) (0.648) (0.030) (0.039) (0.009) (0.095) (0.470) (0.172)

2003–2006 À0.872 0.096 1.527*** À0.373 0.917*** 0.402** À0.452* 0.633*** À0.219 (0.877) (0.134) (0.353) (0.279) (0.311) (0.184) (0.251) (0.234) (0.245)

Odds ratio 0.418 1.101 4.603*** 0.688 2.502*** 1.495** 0.636* 1.883*** 0.803 (0.320) (0.475) (0.000) (0.180) (0.003) (0.029) (0.072) (0.007) (0.372)

À0.214** 1.314** 0.722 1.275+ 2.089***

(0.106) (0.586) (0.664) (0.781) (0.733)

0.807** 3.723** 2.058 3.577+ 8.076***

(0.043) (0.025) (0.277) (0.103) (0.004)

À0.250*** À0.147 0.134 0.947 0.347

(0.074) (0.528) (0.506) (0.730 ) (0.545)

0.779*** 0.863 1.143 2.577 1.415

(0.001) (0.781) (0.791) (0.195) (0.524)

3.557 (12.816) 125 45.98 0.0000 À49.1610 0.531 0.3186 0.111

1.445 (10.445) 190 70.17 0.0000 À70.0790 0.617 0.3336 0.191

Standard errors in brackets. Significance levels: ***o1%, **o5%, *o10%, +o15%. tech_ind: dummy variable ¼1 for health/biotech/pharma, manufacturing, software and programming, technology; 0 otherwise.

highly positive and a significant determinant of the probability to offshore PD projects that are initiated as of 2003. Offshoring as part of the company global strategy is another determinant of the probability to offshore PD that becomes significant, beginning in 2003. Conversely, the negative effect of labor cost savings loses significance in the post2002 subperiod, suggesting that in recent years labor arbitrages objectives lost in importance as a differentiator between PD and non-PD offshoring decisions. Finally, three changes in the significance of control variables should be noted. First, China used to have a location advantage for offshoring PD projects, probably because companies had a preference for locating engineering and PD capabilities in close proximity to existing manufacturing plants (Kenney & Florida, 1994; Murtha et al., 2001), consistent with an HBE offshoring strategy. However, the findings suggest that China’s profile in terms of the type of offshoring it attracts is converging with that of other regions. This can be due to two dynamics developing simultaneously: China is diversifying its economy and making

national investments in human capital, and other regions are also improving their technical skills. Second, offshoring of PD in the post-2002 period is expanding to non-technological industries. The importance of controlling PD activities through captive organizations is declining in later years (post 2002). This is the result of companies adopting globally flexible organizational structures for organizing and managing PD projects, and at the same time of service providers (especially smaller ones) offering innovation outsourcing specializations. Finally, as in the case of the full sample, we ran the regressions with only the supply of S&E and company past offshoring experience as independent variables (Table 10). We find that they do affect the probability of offshoring PD, but only in the first subperiod up to 2003. Our results suggest that, between 1990 and 2003, offshoring of PD projects was driven by the objective of reducing costs (but not through labor arbitrage) and by the need to increase speed to market. In the post-2003 period, access to qualified personnel emerges as the

Journal of International Business Studies

Offshoring of innovation and global race for talent

Arie Y Lewin et al

919

Table 10 Estimation results of logit model (pre- and post-2003 subsamples). Dependent variable: probability of offshoring product development projects

1990–2002 ln SEH1B PAST_EXP_PD Controls ln Empl India China tech_ind captive Constant N LR w2 Prob.4w2 Log likelihood McKelvey and Zavoina R2 McFadden’s R2 Adj. McFadden’s R2 À1.839** (0.744) 0.604** (0.301)

Odds ratio 0.159 (0.118) 1.830 (0.551)

2003–2006 À0.591 (0.544) 0.112 (0.084)

Odds ratio 0.554 (0.301) 1.119 (0.094)

À0.222*** 1.022** 2.085*** 0.900** 1.108***

(0.059) (0.428) (0.582) (0.403) (0.407)

0.801 2.778 8.042 2.459 3.028

(0.047) (1.188) (4.678) (0.992) (1.232)

À0.174*** 0.115 1.089** 0.008 0.531+

(0.045) (0.331) (0.447) (0.317) (0.328)

0.841 1.122 2.971 1.008 1.701

(0.038) (0.371) (1.328) (0.319) (0.558)

21.464 (9.134) 201 54.01 0.0000 À90.9499 0.379 0.2289 0.161

6.852 (6.529) 275 28.12 0.0002 À140.8552 0.144 0.0908 0.039

Standard errors in brackets. Significance levels: ***o1%, **o5%, *o10%, +o15%. tech_ind: dummy variable ¼1 for health/biotech/pharma, manufacturing, software and programming, technology; 0 otherwise.

strongest driver of offshoring PD projects. In other words, regardless of the domestic supply of S&E, companies are learning that workers offshore are highly qualified, and they are adopting strategies and organizational capabilities to recruit talent any place in the world. Early anecdotal evidence suggests that innovation offshoring strategies are evolving to a new configuration that we define as flexible globally distributed (FGD) innovation activities and capabilities. This seems to be the case for large MNEs, such as pharmaceutical companies, which, despite adopting offshoring later than other MNEs, have started experimenting with new R&D organizational configurations designed to simultaneously decrease the fixed footprint of R&D and increase the rate of new PD activities.

DISCUSSION: THE GLOBAL RACE FOR TALENT AND OFFSHORING INNOVATION Consistent with internationalization research, we show that firms’ strategy to search for and access talent globally is a further manifestation of firms internationalizing their operations by seeking assets or capabilities outside their national boundaries (Caves, 1998; Wesson, 1993). Offshoring is a new variation of FDI, or international joint ventures, or partnerships for building firm-specific, location-specific or internalization advantages

(Dunning, 1980). Dunning (1993) has identified market seeking, resource seeking, efficiency seeking, and strategic asset seeking as motives for developing foreign operations. Within this framework, seeking and accessing talent globally is another example of seeking resources (i.e., knowledge and qualified workers) and also of seeking efficiency (i.e., cost reduction). However, in this paper we argue that talent is a different type of asset, and the search for talent globally is emerging as a new phenomenon. Companies are not just diversifying their sources for talent, but are entering an era in which they must compete for talent (see The Economist special report of 5 October 2006). Consistent with the resource-based view of the firm, unobservable and inimitable organizational knowledge and processes are sources of firm competitive advantage and account for much of the variation in firm performance (Barney, 1991; Wernerfelt, 1984). Talent is to a great extent an intangible resource that is embodied in individuals, groups and social networks, and learning to organize and manage talent globally becomes an idiosyncratic capability that is unobservable and difficult to imitate. Talent is an integral element of the knowledge base of the firm, and consists of a wide range of highly specialized technical skills and knowledge (e.g., process knowledge). The realization that the absence of a specific

Journal of International Business Studies

Offshoring of innovation and global race for talent

Arie Y Lewin et al

920

skill or expertise is critical for proceeding with a project often becomes evident only during the process of undertaking specific projects, especially in the case of product innovation. In comparison with typical physical assets, talent is characterized by a different kind of obsolescence (e.g., embedded in geographic knowledge clusters or networks). It is also highly mobile, and must be renewed on an ongoing basis by managing variation and through appropriate HR strategies such as training and retraining. Furthermore, the dynamics of the supply of engineering and science talent are changing. In addition to the effect of the aging of the population, for reasons that are not well understood, fewer young people in Western economies are selecting advanced degrees for entering careers in S&E. It is beyond the scope of this paper to review the many factors that affect this change in preferences, except to note that this trend affects all the industrialized countries in the Triad (US, EU, and Japan). At the same time, Asian countries such as India and China, and certain countries in Eastern Europe and Latin America, are becoming recognized as suppliers of highly qualified engineering and science talent. If companies are realizing, as The Economist special report of October 2006 argues, that they are facing a race for talent because of a growing shortage of talent, then the phenomenon under investigation is about companies competing for talent globally, and not only about seeking engineering and science resources in low-cost countries (e.g., Belderbos & Heijltjes, 2005; Khanna & Palepu, 2004). The rise in the frequency of companies citing access to global pools of qualified personnel and expertise as strategic drivers for offshoring PD applications and for selecting certain country locations may be indicative of companies recognizing the growing shortage of technical talent in the US. In this context, the increase in the H1B visa quota (between 1998 and 2002) can be understood as a response by policy-makers to the lobbying by companies for relief from the growing engineering and science talent shortage. The empirical analyses presented in this paper support our argument that the drastic decrease in H1B visa quota in 2003 impacted on the ability of many companies to execute their innovation strategies. In order to adapt to this significant change in their environment, companies entered a global search for talent (most likely unaware that they were entering a global race for talent) that led them to offshore PD activities to countries and cities where they could find sufficient

pools of qualified personnel and expertise for increasingly advanced and complex PD projects. Our conclusion is consistent with recent work on the growth of offshoring innovation by Ernst (2006) and Thursby and Thursby (2006), who argue that the US should remove obstacles to the immigration of highly skilled workers, and should enlarge the pool of knowledge workers by creating national incentives for entering careers in S&E. The relation between constraints on accessing talent and innovation-sourcing decisions had already been recognized by Quinn (2000), who recommends outsourcing innovation to attract talent because companies may have difficulties attracting the most qualified people for their non-core activities. These workers are likely to prefer working for specialist companies where their expertise will be best recognized, used and rewarded. Today, a similar argument can be made about the offshoring of innovation, as Ernst (2006) notes when he concludes that companies offshore exciting R&D projects to ‘‘attract the best and brightest of the local talent pool,’’ instead of falling back on ‘‘second-choice’’ workers at home. Interestingly, Florida (1997) finds that R&D FDI into the US is also driven by the desire of companies offshore to access scientific and technical human capital. Although improving the efficiency of innovation processes is a major objective of firms offshoring PD, the results from our models support our argument that accessing global talent pools and reducing labor costs are two separate and different strategies driving offshoring decisions by companies. Accessing talent is linked to companies involved in product-development-centered innovation, whereas labor cost savings are associated with companies seeking to replace high-cost workers (mostly lower skilled) with lower-cost workers. Cost savings from labor arbitrage are an important contingency driving the growth in adoption of offshoring practices that the ORN study documents. Nevertheless, the pattern of offshoring activities by American companies that emerges from the ORN study does not fit the traditional notion of companies simply trading non-core, lowlevel workers in the US for low-cost labor offshore. First, offshoring increasingly involves core and technical activities performed by highly trained workers (university graduates from S&E schools, in particular). Second, on the basis of ORN data, less than one out of 10 offshore implementations of technical activities have resulted in job losses in the US. Offshoring of product- and process-centered

Journal of International Business Studies

Offshoring of innovation and global race for talent

Arie Y Lewin et al

921

innovations has enabled companies, large and small, to increase the scale and scope of resources dedicated to their innovation efforts, with no consequential impact on the employment of domestic engineering and R&D staffs. In other words, in the face of a global race for talent, when it comes to offshoring PD work necessary for a firm to maintain its technical leadership and increase its speed to market with new and improved products, labor cost is not the determining variable. Many other strategic considerations are involved, and this paper shows that sourcing skilled workers and talent offshore is definitely a key element. The results reported in this paper have to be placed in the context of the broader phenomenon of increased globalization of human capital (Florida, 2005; Friedman, 2005) and emerging global talent pool (Levin Institute, 2005). In the industrial economy, workers used to migrate from less developed regions towards more industrialized regions to seek jobs. In the knowledge, IT-enabled economy, entire segments of companies’ value chains are relocated to where the requisite human capital is located as a necessary condition for executing certain business functions and processes. In one sense, offshoring creates the experimental basis through which companies are transforming themselves to create flexible global organizations that locate entire functions in the strategically most advantageous locations.

CONCLUSIONS The co-evolutionary framework of the empirical study reported in this paper brought together arguments of MI, path dependence, and environmental effects to explain the strategic decisions of firms to offshore PD work. The results confirm that access to qualified personnel offshore is a strong determinant of such decisions, driven partly by the decreasing supply of S&E graduates in the US. The idea of cumulative experience building is also validated, although MI seems to be a stronger determinant of PD offshoring decisions than firms’ past experience with offshoring. Among the managerial strategic objectives that lead firms to offshore PD projects, speed to market is a key factor underlying decisions to offshore various elements of their innovation process. Finally, the study offers a clarification of the role of cost savings in explaining innovation offshoring. Firms see PD offshoring as a unique opportunity to reduce the cost of their innovation activities, but mainly through new FGD strategies and only partly through HBR strategies,

with labor arbitrage becoming a secondary driver. For small companies, access to lower-cost S&E talent globally enables them to augment their limited in-house R&D resources (HBA strategies). This paper contributes to the debate on the growing shortage of technical talent and globalization of human capital, by providing empirical support for the argument of an impending global race for S&E talent, triggered in part by such events as the 2003 cutback in the H1B visa quota from 195,000 to 65,000 visas annually and the diminishing interest in entering S&E careers, as indicated by the decline in the number of US nationals earning advanced degrees in S&E. However, competing for S&E talent is unlike seeking markets or production platforms through FDI. Talent is different from other assets because it is highly mobile, and because of its high obsolescence. Accessing and managing talent in globally dispersed locations requires new recruiting and retention strategies, as well as new organizational forms for locating talent (e.g., in emerging geographic functional knowledge clusters; Manning et al., 2008), managing, sharing, and exploiting knowledge. Although this paper sheds light on a few important questions regarding the determinants of the decision by firms to offshore innovation activities, we wish to acknowledge some limitations and future extension of the present research. First, although this paper provides an analysis of the influence of three types of factor on companies’ decisions to offshore PD, it is likely that these factors do not impact on firms’ decisions independently of one another. Interaction effects cannot be ruled out. For instance, firms with a low level of previous experience with offshoring may focus more on labor cost reduction objectives, even for PD work, while the effect of access to qualified personnel may be even stronger for more experienced firms. Offshoring PD as a means to increasing speed to market may also be more important for smaller firms, especially in knowledge-driven industries (Murtha, 2004). However, testing for all possible interaction effects in an appropriate way would have significantly complicated the model and the interpretation of the results (Hoetker, 2007). So as a first attempt to bring together MI, path dependence, and environmental factors for explaining firm offshoring decisions, we chose to focus on a simpler and cleaner model. Moreover, mimetic isomorphic pressures (DiMaggio & Powell, 1983) may also influence decisions by firms to offshore innovative work. As an additional possible

Journal of International Business Studies

Offshoring of innovation and global race for talent

Arie Y Lewin et al

922

path dependence effect, industry-level offshoring experience or even diffusion of offshoring practices at the function level should also be tested for. Second, the impact of these variables may evolve over time, which would call for a panel data approach instead of a cross-section. At this stage, the main constraint for investigating this limitation is a lack of data. But as the data collection effort of the ORN progresses we should be able to respond to that issue as well. Finally, there is an opportunity for better accounting for the role of the developing pool of talent offshore using data on the availability and quality of S&E professionals in offshore locations. Unfortunately, such data are not readily available, and would require a significant effort to construct. Indeed, the widely held assumption that China and India combined offer a seemingly unlimited supply of talent may need to be reexamined as there seems to be a growing shortage of high-quality (A and B level) S&E graduates in these countries. Moreover, the low level of English language competency in China is a recognized barrier to offshoring innovation work. In sum, it is clear that understanding the dynamics of offshoring innovation, the implications for firm strategy and for national competitive advantage is still in its early phases, and research in these areas is expected to grow in the coming years. NOTES Our interpretation of the word ‘‘talent’’ throughout this paper is that of highly qualified individuals with advanced university degrees. Particularly relevant to this study is the concept of technical talent, referring to Master and PhD graduates in Science and Engineering (S&E), and experienced workers. 2 The H1B is a non-immigrant visa category for temporary (3 þ 3 years) workers in specialty occupations requiring the theoretical and practical application of a body of specialized knowledge if a US citizen or resident is not available. H1B applicants must hold a bachelor’s degree or the equivalent in the specific specialty (e.g., engineering, mathematics, physical sciences, computer sciences, medicine and health care, education, biotechnology, business specialties). Each fiscal year, the US Congress sets a cap on H1B
1

admissions. The H1B visa is the main channel for US companies to employ foreign S&E workers in the US. 3 For a report on policy proposals intended to increase the supply of engineers and scientists in the US, and a discussion of the consequences of a continued shortage of engineering and science talent in the US, see Rising above the gathering storm: Energizing and employing America for a brighter economic future (Committee on Prospering in the Global Economy of the 21st Century, 2005). 4 The 2004 and 2005 surveys were supported by the Duke CIBER and Archstone Consulting LLC. In 2006 the ORN lead corporate sponsor was Booz Allen Hamilton, the global management consulting firm. As of 2007, The conference Board and PriceWaterhouseCooper are lead collaborators of the ORN Project. 5 Partner Universities include Copenhagen Business School (covering Scandinavian countries), Wissenschaftliche Hochschule fur Unternehmensfuhrung ¨ ¨ (Germany), RSM Erasmus University (Netherlands), IESE (Spain), Manchester Business School (UK), ULB – Solvay Brussels School of Economics and Management (Belgium), and Bocconi University (Italy). 6 Alternative measures were tested in the model, including rates of growth and discounting for GDP/pro capita GDP. We chose the operationalization that showed the best performance. 7 The survey question was: ‘‘For each function, please evaluate the importance of the following strategic drivers in your decision to offshore,’’ to be evaluated on a five-point Likert scale ranging from 1¼ not important at all to 5 ¼ very important. 8 Three correlation coefficients, between Speed and Global, between overall supply of S&E and D2003, and between Cost of labor and Other costs, present high values (respectively 0.43, 0.43, and 0.38) and are statistically significant at 1%. However, when we entered the two variables involved separately, the regression results differed only marginally, indicating these correlations do not affect the regression model. 9 We tested the models also for pre-2003 and post2004 subsamples, and obtained very similar results. The correlation tables for the two subperiods are very similar to those of the whole period, and therefore are not reported. Results are available from the authors.

REFERENCES
Amiti, M., & Wei, S.-J. 2005. Fear of service outsourcing: Is it justified? Economic Policy, 20(42): 308–347. Apte, S., McCarthy, J. C., & Furstoss, R. J. 2006. Offshore product development has arrived, Market Overview, Forrester Research, August. Barney, J. B. 1991. Firm resources and sustained competitive advantage. Journal of Management, 17(1): 99–120. Bartlett, C. A., & Ghoshal, S. 1990. Managing innovation in the transnational corporation. In C. A. Bartlett, Y. Doz, & G. Hedlund (Eds), Managing the global firm: 215–255. London: Routledge.

Journal of International Business Studies

Offshoring of innovation and global race for talent

Arie Y Lewin et al

923

Belderbos, R. A., & Heijltjes, M. G. 2005. The determinants of expatriate staffing by Japanese multinationals in Asia: Control, learning and vertical business groups. Journal of International Business Studies, 36(3): 341–354. Buchanan, L. 2006. The thinking man’s outsourcing. Inc. Magazine, May. Buckley, P., & Casson, M. 1976. The future of the multinational enterprise. London: Macmillan. Buckley, P., & Lessard, D. R. 2005. Regaining the edge for international business research. Journal of International Business Studies, 36(6): 595–599. Bunyaratavej, K., Hahn, E. D., & Doh, J. P. 2007. International offshoring of services: A parity study. Journal of International Management, 13(1): 7–21. Butz, W. P., Bloom, G. A., Gross, M. E., Kelly, T. K., Kofner, A., & Rippen, H. E. 2003. Is there a shortage of scientists and engineers? How would we know? Science and Technology Issue Paper, RAND Corporation. Calantone, R. J., & Stanko, M. A. 2007. Drivers of outsourced innovation: An exploratory study. Journal of Product Innovation Management, 24(3): 230–241. Cantwell, J. 1991. The international agglomeration of R&D. In M. Casson (Ed.), Global research strategy and international competitiveness: 104–132. Oxford: Blackwell. Cantwell, J. 1995. The globalisation of technology: What remains of the product cycle model? Cambridge Journal of Economics, 19(1): 155–174. Caves, R. E. 1996. Multinational enterprise and economic analysis. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Caves, R. E. 1998. Industrial organization and new findings on the turnover and mobility of firms. Journal of Economic Literature, 36(4): 1947–1982. Chanda, R., & Sreenivasan, N. 2005. India’s experience with skilled migration. In C. Kuptsch & E. F. Pang (Eds), Competing for global talent: 215–256. Geneva: ILO International Institute for Labour Studies. Clark, K. B., & Fujimoto, T. 1991. Product development performance: Strategy, organization, and management in the world auto industry. Boston, MA: Harvard Business School Press. Coase, R. 1937. The nature of the firm. Econometrica, 4(16): 386–405. Cohen, M. S., & Zaidi, M. A. 2002. Global skill shortages. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar. Committee on Prospering in the Global Economy of the 21st Century. 2005. Rising above the gathering storm: Energizing and employing America for a brighter economic future. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. Cyert, R., & March, J. G. 1963. A behavioral theory of the firm. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall. Delios, A., & Henisz, W. J. 2003. Policy uncertainity and the sequence of entry by Japanese firms, 1980–1998. Journal of International Business Studies, 34(3): 227–241. DiMaggio, P. J., & Powell, W. W. 1983. The iron cage revisited: Institutional isomorphism and collective rationality in organizational fields. American Sociological Review, 48(2): 147–160. Doh, J. P. 2005. Offshore outsourcing: Implications for international business and strategic management theory and practice. Journal of Management Studies, 42(3): 695–704. Dossani, R., & Kenney, M. 2003. Went for costs, stayed for quality? Moving the back office to India, Working Paper, AsiaPacific Research Center, Stanford University. Dossani, R., & Kenney, M. 2004. Offshoring: Determinants of the location and value of services, Working Paper, Asia Pacific Research Center, Stanford University. Dossani, R., & Kenney, M. 2006. Reflections upon ‘‘Sizing the emerging global labor market’’. Academy of Management Perspectives, 20(4): 35–41. Dossani, R., & Kenney, M. 2007. The next wave of globalization: Relocating service provision to India. World Development, 35(5): 772–791.

Dunning, J. H. 1980. Towards an eclectic theory of international production: Some empirical tests. Journal of International Business Studies, 11(1): 9–31. Dunning, J. H. 1993. Multinational enterprises and the global economy. Wokingham: Addison-Wesley. Dunning, J. H. 1998. Location and the multinational enterprise: A neglected factor? Journal of International Business Studies, 29(1): 45–66. Dunning, J. H. 2000. Regions, globalization and the knowledgebased economy. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Dunning, J. H., & Narula, R. 1995. The R&D activities of foreign firms in the United States. International Studies of Management & Organization, 5(1–2): 39–74. The Economist. 2006. The battle for brainpower, Special Report, 5 October. Ernst, D. 2002. Global production networks and the changing geography of innovation systems: Implications for developing countries. Economics of Innovation and New Technology, 11(6): 497–523. Ernst, D. 2006. Innovation offshoring: Asia’s emerging role in global innovation networks, East–West Center Special Report Number 10. Honolulu: East–West Center. Farrell, D., Laboissiere, M. A., & Rosenfeld, J. 2006. Sizing the emerging global labor market: Rational behavior from both companies and countries can help it work more efficiently. Academy of Management Perspectives, 20(4): 23–34. Feinberg, S. E., & Gupta, A. L. 2004. Knowledge spillovers and the assignment of R&D responsibilities to foreign subsidiaries. Strategic Management Journal, 25(8–9): 823–845. Flier, B., Van den Bosch, F. A. J., & Volberda, H. W. 2003. Co-evolution in the strategic renewal behaviour of British, Dutch and French financial incumbents: Interaction of environmental selection, institutional effects and managerial intentionality. Journal of Management Studies, 40(8): 2163–2187. Florida, R. 1997. The globalization of R&D: Results of a survey of foreign-affiliated R&D laboratories in the USA. Research Policy, 26(1): 85–103. Florida, R. 2005. The flight of the creative class: The new global competition for talent. New York: Harper Business. Freeman, R. B. 2005. Does globalization of the scientific/ engineering workforce threaten US economic leadership? Working Paper No. 11457, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA. Friedman, T. L. 2005. The world is flat: A brief history of the twenty-first century. New York: Farrar, Straus and Giroux. ˚ Granstrand, O., Hakanson, L., & Sjolander, S. 1992. Technology ¨ management and international business: Internationalization of R&D and technology. Chichester: John Wiley & Sons. Grant, R. M. 1996. Toward a knowledge-based theory of the firm. Strategic Management Journal, 17(Winter Special Issue): 109–122. ˚ Hakanson, L. 1990. International decentralization of R&D: The organizational challenges. In C. A. Bartlett, Y. Doz, & G. Hedlund (Eds), Managing the global firm: 256–278. London: Routledge. ˚ Hakanson, L., & Nobel, R. 1993. Foreign research and development in Swedish multinationals. Research Policy, 22(5–6): 373–396. Hayes, R. H., Wheelwright, S. C., & Clark, K. B. 1988. Dynamic manufacturing: Creating the learning organization. New York: Free Press. Henley, J. 2006. Outsourcing the provision of software and IT-enabled services to India: Emerging stratergies. International Studies of Management and Organization, 36(4): 111–131. Hirschman, A. O. 1970. Exit, voice, and loyalty: Responses to decline in firms, organizations, and states. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Hirshfeld, S., & Schmid, G. 2005. Globalisation of R&D. TEKES Technology Review, 184. Finland: Tekes, http://www.tekes.fi/ eng/publications/julkaisuarkisto.asp. Hoetker, G. 2007. The use of logit and probit models in strategic management research: Critical issues. Strategic Management Journal, 28(4): 331–343.

Journal of International Business Studies

Offshoring of innovation and global race for talent

Arie Y Lewin et al

924

Horst, T. 1972. Firm and industry determinants of the decision to invest abroad: An empirical study. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 54(3): 258–266. Howells, J. 1990. The location and organisation of research and development: New horizons. Research Policy, 19(2): 133–146. Howells, J. 1995. Going global: The use of ICT networks in research and development. Research Policy, 24(2): 169–184. Hutzschenreuter, T., Pedersen, T., & Volberda, H. 2007. The role of path dependency and managerial intentionality: A perspective on international business research. Journal of International Business Studies, 38(7): 1055–1068. Hymer, S. 1976. The international operations of national firms. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Kenney, M., & Florida, R. 1994. The organization and geography of Japanese R&D: Results from a survey of Japanese electronics and biotechnology firms. Research Policy, 23(3): 305–323. Khan, H., & Islam, M. S. 2006. Outsourcing, migration, and brain drain in the global economy: Issues and evidence, Working Paper 004/2006, U21Global. Khanna, T., & Palepu, K. G. 2004. Globalization and convergence in corporate governance: Evidence from Infosys and the Indian software industry. Journal of International Business Studies, 35(6): 484–507. Kshetri, N. 2007. Institutional factors affecting offshore business process and information technology outsourcing. Journal of International Management, 13(1): 38–56. Kuemmerle, W. 1999a. The drivers of foreign direct investment into research and development: An empirical investigation. Journal of International Business Studies, 30(1): 1–24. Kuemmerle, W. 1999b. Foreign direct investment in industrial research in the pharmaceutical and electronics industries: Results from a survey of multinational firms. Research Policy, 28(2–3): 179–193. Lall, S. 1979. The international allocation of research activity by US multinationals. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 41(4): 313–331. Lee, J. 1986. Determinants of offshore production in developing countries. Journal of Development Economics, 20(1): 1–13. Levin Institute. 2005. The evolving global talent pool: Issues, challenges and strategic implications. New York: The Levin Institute. Levy, D. L. 2005. Offshoring in the new global political economy. Journal of Management Studies, 42(3): 685–693. Lewin, A. Y., & Couto, V. 2007. Next generation offshoring: The globalization of innovation, Durham, NC: Duke University CIBER/Booz Allen Hamilton Report. Lewin, A. Y., & Peeters, C. 2006a. Offshoring work: Business hype or the onset of fundamental transformation? Long Range Planning, 39(3): 221–239. Lewin, A. Y., & Peeters, C. 2006b. The top-line allure of offshoring. Harvard Business Review, 84(3): 22–24. Lewin, A. Y., & Volberda, H. W. 1999. Prolegomena on coevolution: A framework for research on strategy and new organizational forms. Organization Science, 10(5): 519–534. Lewin, A. Y., Long, C. P., & Carroll, T. N. 1999. The coevolution of new organizational forms. Organization Science, 10(5): 535–550. Lieberthal, K., & Lieberthal, G. 2003. The great transition. Harvard Business Review, 81(10): 70–81. Manning, S., Lewin, A. Y., & Massini, S. 2008. The globalization of innovation: A dynamic perspective on offshoring. Academy of Management Perspectives, 22(3): 35–54. Mansfield, E. 1984. R&D and innovation: Some empirical findings. In Z. Griliches (Ed.), R&D, patents and productivity: 127–154. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. March, J. G., & Simon, H. A. 1958. Organizations. New York: Wiley. Maskell, P., Pedersen, T., Petersen, B., & Dick-Nielsen, J. 2007. Learning paths to offshore outsourcing: From cost reduction to knowledge seeking. Industry & Innovation, 14(3): 239–257.

Mehta, A., Armenakis, A., Mehta, N., & Irani, F. 2006. Challenges and opportunities of business process outsourcing in India. Journal of Labor Research, 27(3): 323–338. Murmann, P. J. 2000. Knowledge and competitive advantage: The coevolution of firms, technology, and national institutions. New York: Cambridge University Press. Murray, J. Y., & Kotabe, M. 1999. Sourcing strategies of US service companies: A modified transaction-cost analysis. Strategic Management Journal, 20(9): 791–809. Murtha, T. P. 1991. Surviving industrial targeting: State credibility and public policy contingencies in multinational subcontracting. Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, 7(1): 117–143. Murtha, T. P. 1993. Credible enticements: Can host governments tailor multinational firms’ organizations to suit national objectives? Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 20(2): 171–186. Murtha, T. P. 2004. The metanational firm in context: Competition in knowledge-driven industries. Advances in International Management, 16: 101–136. Murtha, T. P., & Lenway, S. A. 1994. Country capabilities and the strategic state: How national political institutions affect multinational corporations’ strategies. Strategic Management Journal, 15(Summer Special Issue): 113–130. Murtha, T. P., Lenway, S. A., & Hart, J. A. 2001. Managing new industry creation: Global knowledge formation and entrepreneurship in high technology. Stanford: Stanford University Press. National Science Board. 2004. Science and engineering indicators 2004, Vol. 1. Arlington, VA: National Science Foundation. Nelson, R. R. 1991. Why do firms differ, and how does it matter? Strategic Management Journal, 12(Winter Special Issue): 61–74. Nelson, R. R., & Winter, S. 1982. An evolutionary theory of economic change. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Nonaka, I., & Takeuchi, H. 1995. The knowledge-creating company: How Japanese companies create the dynamics of innovation. New York: Oxford University Press. Oliver, C. 1991. Strategic responses to institutional processes. Academy of Management Review, 16(1): 145–179. Patel, P., & Pavitt, K. 1991. Large firms in the production of the world’s technology: An important case of ‘‘non-globalisation’’. Journal of International Business Studies, 22(1): 1–21. Pearce, R. D. 1999. Decentralized R&D and strategic competitiveness: Globalized approaches to generation and use of technology in multinational enterprises. Research Policy, 28(2–3): 157–178. Pedersen, T., & Jensen, P. D. O. 2007. Offshoring of advanced activities, Paper presented at European Academy of Management (EURAM) Annual Conference Current Management Thinking: Drawing from Social Sciences and Humanities to Address Contemporary Challenges? Paris, 16–19 May, Paris. Brussels, Belgium: EURAM. Pisano, G. P. 1990. The R&D boundaries of the firm: An empirical analysis. Administrative Science Quarterly, 35(1): 153–176. Porter, M. E. 1985. Competitive advantage. New York: Free Press. ´ Quelin, B., & Duhamel, F. 2003. Bringing together strategic outsourcing and corporate strategy: Outsourcing motives and risks. European Management Journal, 21(5): 647–661. Quinn, J. B. 2000. Outsourcing innovation: The new engine of growth. Sloan Management Review, 41(4): 13–28. Rangan, U. S., & Schumacher, P. 2006. Entrepreneurial globalization: Lessons from the experiences of European small and medium enterprises, Paper presented at IIM-B Management Review Conference on Global Competitiveness Through Outsourcing: Implications for Services and Manufacturing, Bangalore, 13–15 July. Rugman, A. M., & Verbeke, A. 2004. A perspective on regional and global strategies of multinational enterprises. Journal of International Business Studies, 35(1): 3–18. Sako, M. 2002. Modularity and outsourcing: The nature of coevolution of product architecture and organisation architecture in the global automotive industry, Working Paper, Templeton College, University of Oxford.

Journal of International Business Studies

Offshoring of innovation and global race for talent

Arie Y Lewin et al

925

Takeishi, A. 2002. Knowledge partitioning in the interfirm division of labor: The case of automotive product development. Organization Science, 13(3): 321–338. Thursby, J., & Thursby, M. 2006. Here or there? A survey of factors in multinational R&D location, Report to the Government– Industry Research Roundtable. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. Vernon, R. 1966. International investment and international trade in the product cycle. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 80(2): 190–207. Volberda, H. W., & Lewin, A. Y. 2003. Co-evolutionary dynamics within and between firms: From evolution to co-evolution. Journal of Management Studies, 40(8): 2111–2136. Von Hippel, E. 1988. The sources of innovation. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Wernerfelt, B. 1984. A resource-based view of the firm. Strategic Management Journal, 5(2): 171–180. Wesson, T. 1993. An alternative motivation for foreign direct investment, Unpublished Dissertation, Harvard University, Cambridge, MA. Williamson, O. E. 1975. Markets and hierarchies: Analysis and antitrust implications. New York: Free Press. Witt, M., & Lewin, A. Y. 2007. Outward foreign direct investment as escape response to home country institutional constraints. Journal of International Business Studies, 38(4): 579–594. Zweig, D. 2005. Learning to compete: China’s efforts to encourage a ‘‘reverse brain drain’’. In C. Kuptsch & E. F. Pang (Eds), Competing for global talent: 187–214. Geneva: ILO International Institute for Labour Studies.

Fuqua School of Business. He is the Lead Principal Investigator of the international Offshoring Research Network (ORN), which was launched in 2004. He is the founding editor of Organization Science (1989–1999) and was Editor-in-Chief of the Journal of International Business Studies (2002–2007). Dr Silvia Massini is Senior Lecturer in Economics and Technology Management at Manchester Business School, which she joined in 2000 after conducting research in the adoption and diffusion of technological and organizational innovations at the Italian National Research Council (Rome), SPRU, and Warwick University. She is the partner of the Offshoring Research Network for the UK. Dr Carine Peeters, after a 2-year post-doc at Duke University, became FNRS/Belspo senior research fellow at ULB – Solvay Brussels School of Economics and Management, where she had earned a PhD in Management Sciences in 2004. She is the partner of the Offshoring Research Network in Belgium. Her research centers on the strategic and organizational dimensions of offshoring, with a particular focus on innovation.

ABOUT THE AUTHORS Arie Y Lewin is Professor of International Strategy, and Director of the Center for International Business Education and Research (CIBER), Duke University

Accepted by Martin Kenney and Silvia Massini, Guest Editors, 6 August 2008. This paper has been with the authors for three revisions.

Journal of International Business Studies

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.

Similar Documents

Premium Essay

Hr Research Paper

...“Outsourcing-Offshore” Outsourcing is said to have emerged a few thousand years ago with the production and sales of food, tools, and other household appliances. As soon as small communities and societies began to form, people with specialized professions began to trade with each other for goods and services. It can be said that each worker was outsourcing some activities to others. Research shows that even in the industrial age, a few thousand years later, very few companies outsourced any of their operations. Companies in the 1800s and 1900s were vertically integrated organizations, taking care of their own production, mining, and manufacturing from raw materials to finished goods as well as then shipping the goods to company owned retail outlets. These companies often handled their own taxes, employed their own lawyers, as well as designed and built their own buildings without outside assistance. This model does not apply to all companies during that time period, but it gives a general idea of the time. The history of outsourcing portrays that as onshore outsourcing continued manufacturing outsourcing of low-tech items such as toys, shoes and apparel goods began to take place. After this manufacturing higher value items like high-tech components and consumer electronics began to appear. In fact outsourcing history demonstrates that manufacturing was the first activity that began to move to offshore destinations in a quest for lower costs. Globalization began during...

Words: 3150 - Pages: 13

Premium Essay

Literature Review

...the recent years, there have been social, political and economic pressures on corporate management to pay attention on social and environmental consequences of corporate activities. These pressures motivated the corporate management to actively participate in a wide range of social welfare activities. CSR now-a-days covers almost all issues like the use of child labor; inequality of employment; environmental impact; involvement in local community; products’ safety; company cultures; brand image and reputation. Apart from this, companies are now disclosing these activities in their annual reports, and one of the parameters to judge the performance of a company is CSR reporting. Corporate Social Responsibility CSR is defined by Naylor (1999) and mentioned in the work of Douglas et al. (2004) as “the obligation of managers to choose and act in ways that benefit both the interests of the organization and those of society as a whole.” Commission of the European Communities defines CSR as a concept by which “companies decide voluntarily to contribute to a better society and a cleaner environment”. It...

Words: 28706 - Pages: 115

Free Essay

Offshore Outsourcing Jobs in the United States

...Offshoring, also known as offshore outsourcing, is the term that is used to describe the practice among companies located in the United States on contracting businesses beyond U.S borders to perform services that would otherwise have been provided by in-house employees in white-collar occupations. The term can be applied to U.S. firms that are offshoring the jobs of blue-collar workers on textile and auto assembly lines, for example, which has been taking place for decades. The extension of offshoring from U.S. manufacturers to facilitate providers has heightened public policy concerns about the extent of job loss and foregone employment opportunities among American workers. This concern was especially relevant to policymakers because of the national unemployment rate persistently exceeding 9% despite the end of the Great Recession in June 2009 . The outsourcing of service sector jobs from the United States was a response to the early 1980s recessions when employers narrowed their focus to the company’s core mission and contracted peripheral activities (e.g., janitorial duties) to other U.S. businesses. The 2001 recession caused employers to seek further efficiencies by tapping into the global supply of labor. U.S. businesses were able to outsource overseas the jobs of white-collar workers in some service providing industries as a result of widely disseminated technological advances that permit low cost, good quality, and high speed transmission of voice and data communications...

Words: 2569 - Pages: 11

Premium Essay

Offshoring of Us Jobs

...Abstract Outsourcing is the agreement of diverse functions, such as data entry, programming, facilities management, disaster recovery, and telecommunications management, to outside providers of services. The main reason why organizations implement outsourcing is cost reduction, to leverage themselves ahead of their competitors, and as a means to increase their adaptability to changes in the business world. Outsourcing also provides the ability to benefit from the advances in information technology, while focusing on core business activities of the organization. Not only does outsourcing information technology functions enable increased concentrated efforts toward the organizational mission, but if skillfully planned and properly managed, contributes to healthy growth in the company’s fiscal bottom line. The implementation of offshoring has affected the competition and the expansion of the business service industry in an increasingly accessible and competitive global world. The effect of Outsourcing Within The Business Services Industry The business service industry has been impacted with intense pressures of reducing costs while also increasing new customers and introducing new products to create a center of attention to those customers. Lately, more companies are implementing offshoring strategies (i.e. outsourcing of operations to foreign countries) to cut costs. However there is some empirical evidence that the business service industries are increasingly offshoring operations...

Words: 2478 - Pages: 10

Free Essay

Outsourcing Jobs

... This would be the outsourcing of jobs that Americans would be willing to accept if the corporations were not so adamant about improving their bottom line for their stockholders. So, what is outsourcing and offshore outsourcing? By definition, “outsourcing (or contracting out) is often defined as the delegation of non-core operations or jobs from internal production within a business to an external entity (such as a subcontractor) that specialized in that operation. Outsourcing is a business decision that is often made to lower costs or focus on competencies” (Miller, 2010). A good example of outsourcing is janitorial services. Instead of a company training several people for the position, they can outsource these tasks to another organization that specializes in recruitment services. This way they can save the time from hiring and training, and the work output should be of the highest quality. Offshore outsourcing is referred to as, “work done for a company by people in another country that is typically done at a much cheaper cost” (Miller, 2010). These services are outsourced elsewhere to countries other than where the goods and services are actually consumed. A good example of this would be call centers. If you were to call one of your credit card companies, you are more than likely going to speak to a representative from overseas, such as India, Central America, or maybe the Philippines. The general assumption of the American public is that jobs, money, skills,...

Words: 2350 - Pages: 10

Premium Essay

Outsourcing by Nike, Telstra and Boeing

...Executive summary: Outsourcing allows company to reduce their cost and gain a competitive advantage and this idea is strongly adopted by companies all over the world. Outsourcing is an agreement in which one company contracts-out a part of their existing internal activity to another company. Outsourcing benefits company because it maximizing company’s resources, more efficient output and make legal agreement for performance guarantees. Telstra is Australia’s leading telecommunications and information service company (telco). Telstra has been using BPO (Business Process Outsourcing) which creates substantial business across Asia, North America and Europe. For home country, owners earn cost & saving efficiency and diversity of intellectual talent, hence, government face unemployed labor force and manager loss their ability to control as the disadvantages. For the host country, employees improve their life standart and there are economic growth. But, there’s higher social gap and inflation for the host country. Nike is a major publicly traded sportswear and equipment supplier based in the United States. They outsourced Customers services, manufacturing, advertising, promotion, charity, and society impact. For the home country, it cut their cost and expand international market, hence, it also bring negative social impact and mislead reputation. For the host country, it make lower unemployment rate and financial & risk reduction. Meanwhile, market monopoly and legal/ethic...

Words: 1368 - Pages: 6

Premium Essay

Eco 550

...ECO 550 Week 3 Discussion Questions Week 3 DQ 1 "Managing in the Global Economy" Please respond to the following: * *Answer the following discussions based on the Katrina’s Candies scenario: * From the scenario for Katrina’s Candies, assuming the absence of quantitative data, determine the qualitative forecasting techniques that could be used within this scenario. * Now, assume you have acquired some time series data that would enable you to make short, medium, and long term forecasts. Ascertain the quantitative technique that will provide you with the most accurate forecast. Provide a rationale for your responses. Answer: From the scenario for Katrina’s Candies, assuming the absence of quantitative data, determine the qualitative forecasting techniques that could be used within this scenario. Quantitative data are anything that can be expressed as a number, or quantified. Examples of quantitative data are scores on achievement tests, number of hours of study, or weight of a subject. These data may be represented by ordinal, interval or ratio scales and lend themselves to most statistical manipulation. Qualitative data cannot be expressed as a number. Data that represent nominal scales such as gender, socieo economic status, and religious preference are usually considered to be qualitative data.  Both types of data are valid types of measurement, and both are used in education journals. Only quantitative data can be analyzed statistically, and thus...

Words: 2436 - Pages: 10

Premium Essay

Keppel Corp. Analysis

...infrastructure and investment businesses. Although it is well-developed and has promising prospects of becoming more influential globally, a recent underperformance reflected in its annual report and relevant negative news regarding the profit decline indicate that there are some factors interfering with its sustainability and profitability. Keppel’s Offshore and Marine sector is facing certain risks, which might hamper the overall growth of the corporation as this sector accounts for 65% of total revenue generated by Keppel. This report provides a brief overview of Keppel’s main businesses. The focal point of interest would be on the offshore and marine industry. Multiple industry and strategy analysis frameworks will be used to analyze the factors affecting the sustainable development of Keppel Corporation in order to determine underlying reasons for its dilemmas and to provide recommendations for mitigation. Foundations of Strategic Management Final Project for Group 6: Shreya Garg Rohit Tatineni Guo Yao Huang Xingyu Tan Choon Long Martin Table of Contents 1. Keppel Corporation- A Brief History 3 2. Offshore and Marine Industry in Singapore 4 Strategic positioning of Singapore 4 Existing opportunities and threats in the industry 5 Industry outlook 6 3. Analysis of Keppel O&M’s business philosophy 7 Potential risks and challenges 8 4. The Business Dilemma 8 Underlying Reasons of the Dilemma 9 Geographic over-concentration 9 Fluctuating oil...

Words: 5820 - Pages: 24

Premium Essay

America

...IT Association Of America ukessays.com /essays/america/it-association-of-america.php Introduction: Information Technology has been defined as “the study, design, development, implementation, support or management of computer-based information systems, particularly software applications and computer hardware” by the Information Technology Association of America (IITA). Information Technology has been one of the fastest growing industries in the last three decades. With a growth rate of 5.6%, information technology sector is now more than a $1.6 trillion (Nasscom) industry from what was merely an industry of few millions in 1980s. Today almost all electronic devices have a chip programmed to run the device efficiently. Information technology does not just support the internet and computers; it has grown to almost every sector today, from computers to mobile phones, from banking to automobiles, from education systems to Business process, information technology is involved in improving the system performance everywhere. Information technology played an important role in improving process and performance of businesses. Globalisation had an important role in kicking off the demand for information technology. But this was not the only reason for high demand of software products and services, strong technological advances were being pursued in all sectors. Heeks and Nicholson (2004) identified that According to them the developed economies had significant growth in...

Words: 5459 - Pages: 22

Premium Essay

Michal3

...INTERNATIONAL TRADE & INVESTMENT Prof. Dr. Natalia Ribberink World Trade Center, Seoul, South Korea (Picture: Ribberink) INTERNATIONAL TRADE & INVESTMENT Preliminary Notes World Trade Center, Seoul, South Korea (Picture: Ribberink) Preliminary notes • Combination of lecture, seminar, group work and other forms of learning as appropriate; • Grading: working paper 60%, case studies 40% • Communication: natalia.ribberink@haw-hamburg.de © Prof. Dr. Natalia Ribberink 3 Agenda Chapter 1: Chapter 2: Chapter 3: Chapter 4: Chapter 5: International trade and investment environment International trade policy and instruments Forms of international trade FDI theories, patterns and forms FDI policy instruments For details s. Syllabus (will be provided in class on Nov 10, 2015). © Prof. Dr. Natalia Ribberink 4 Message icons Further reading Question for group discussion Case study Int. Trade & Investment Vocabulary © Prof. Dr. Natalia Ribberink 5 Online sources: AuslandsGeschäftsAbsicherung des Bundes: www.agaportal.de Außenwirtschaftsportal: www.ixpos.de Berne Union: www.berneunion.org.uk Kreditanstalt für Wiederaufbau: www.kfw.de OECD: www.oecd.org Statistisches Bundesamt Deutschland: www.destatis.de The Economist: www.economist.com UNCTAD: www.unctad.org World Trade Organisation: www.wto.org © Prof. Dr. Natalia Ribberink 6 CHAPTER 1: International trade & investment environment Westside Market...

Words: 5898 - Pages: 24

Premium Essay

Offshoring Effects

...Offshoring by United States Multinationals Bad for the United States Economy? Offshoring or offshore labor outsourcing is when a company relocates all or part of its production or services such as accounting or human resources to another country. There is no doubt that this has an effect on the U.S. economy. This paper will discuss the reasons that U.S. multinationals choose to offshore as well as the positive and negative effects this has on our economy. The downside of offshoring is the unemployment that occurs domestically when a U.S. company sends some or all of its production abroad. The disruption caused by this unemployment may lead to lower consumer spending by the laid-off workers which can in turn cause a reduction in economic growth overall. Additionally, unemployment caused by offshoring may necessitate a major effort to retrain the affected workers for new jobs which may be quite costly. Another problem with offshoring is the risk that products manufactured abroad pose because they are made without proper oversight. This can lead to dangerous and unhealthy imported goods such as toys tainted with lead and pet food laced with toxic substances. The positive side of offshoring is the money that a company saves on labor costs. They also avoid costly regulatory or environmental laws, and experience lower tax rates. Additionally, offshoring can be beneficial when certain company responsibilities can be done more efficiently overseas because this frees up time and enables...

Words: 3666 - Pages: 15

Premium Essay

Strategy 10/11

...hand, Matsushita based its global strategy on a centralized and efficient operation through Japan. As they developed and reorganized their international strategies, each company was forced to undertake its strategic posture and restructuring as its competition position fell. During the 1990s, each company experienced specific difficulties to their market share. Both companies struggled to reestablish themselves in the global consumer electronics world. As the year 2000 came around, new CEOs at both companies came up with even more complicated initiatives and reorganizations. Outsiders wondered how each company’s internal changes would affect their endless competitive battle in the industry. The case illustrates how global competitiveness depends on the organizational capability, the difficulty of overcoming deeply rooted administrative heritage, and the limitations of both classic multinational and global models. Study Questions 1. How did Philips become the most successful company in its business during an era when scores of electrical engineering companies were being formed? What impediments and disabilities did Philips' strategic and organizational capabilities bring with them? Philips made a strong push to developing new technologies starting in the 1950s and 1960s. Upon doing so, the company also wanted to translate these technologies into products while adapting, producing, and selling these products within individual national markets....

Words: 1811 - Pages: 8

Premium Essay

Berluchi

... let’s talk about the implications it implies. Taking what Claudia has introduced, offshoring is a possible way out of outsourcing and the most controversial one. To clear your mind; the biggest difference is that while outsourcing can be (and often is) offshored, offshoring may not always involved outsourcing. Both may save company money, but only offshoring specifically means sending jobs out of the country, typically to a cheaper location. It includes both to the setup of a subsidiary abroad, or to the outsource activities of a company. So the question is, not just when to outsource, but when to do it through offshoring? 1. It depends on the quality you want to ensure to the client? Ultimately, the best solution for your business depends on your needs. If you need a high level of quality and communications, outsourcing locally may be best. If you need low costs and a systematized business, offshoring is often a better solution. 2. Or maybe it depends on the relationship you must have with the client? Activities which can be precisely specified can be offshored effectively. This is why software coding is often done in an offshore location. On the contrary, activities that require direct customer interaction, deep domain knowledge, or deep cultural knowledge should be onshored. Thus, customer service is usually conducted onshore because of the need to be close to customers that is, to meet with them and talk to them in their own language. Finally, activities...

Words: 1370 - Pages: 6

Premium Essay

Offshoring Impact on U.S. Software Engineers

...Offshoring Impact on U.S. Software Engineers for Leadership and Organizational Behavior Thesis: In my workplace, we have been outsourcing some technical work to Mexico. It has been interesting the feedback we are getting from our programmers. Although we’re outsourcing only when the work exceeds our capacity, they’re rightly concern about their jobs; they are concern about offshoring. I would like to write a feasibility analysis of offshoring work for my class project. I would like to be specific to “offshoring impact to software engineers”. April 17, 2011 Contents Offshoring Impact on U.S. Software Engineers 1 Contents 2 1 Introduction 3 1.1 Definitions 3 1.2 Summary 3 2 Data Section 4 2.1 Offshoring from a political perspective 4 2.2 Offshoring from a business perspective 7 2.3 Offshoring from software engineers perspective 9 3 Conclusion 11 3.1 Summary of Findings 11 3.2 Recommendations 11 4 Appendices 13 4.1 2008 Projected Base Salary Increases 13 5 Bibliography 14 1 Introduction 1.1 Definitions According to United States Department of Labor, software engineers (job 15-1031) develop, create, and modify general computer applications software or specialized utility programs. Analyze user needs and develop software solutions. Design software or customize software for client use with the aim of optimizing operational efficiency. May analyze and design databases within an application area, working individually or coordinating database...

Words: 2446 - Pages: 10

Premium Essay

Paper

...necessarily reflect the views of the Sloan Foundation or the National Science Foundation. Abstract This article analyzes the distribution of value from innovation in the global supply chains of the Apple iPad and iPhone. We find that Apple continues to capture the largest share of value from these innovations. While these products, including most of their components, are manufactured in China, the primary benefits go to the U.S. economy as Apple continues to keep most of its product design, software development, product management, marketing and other high-wage functions in the U.S. China’s role is much smaller than most casual observers would think. A key finding for managers is that they need to beware of relying too heavily on single customers. With its control over the supply chain, Apple has the power to make and break the fortunes of many of its suppliers. A key finding for policymakers is that there is little value in electronics assembly. Bringing high-volume electronics assembly back to the U.S. is not the path to “good jobs” or economic growth. Capturing Value in Global Networks: Apple’s iPad and iPhone In an earlier article in Communications of the ACM [7], we conducted a micro-level economic analysis of Apple’s iPod as a way of better understanding who captures the value in global innovation networks in the information and communications...

Words: 3262 - Pages: 14