Free Essay

Impact of Mobile Banking

In:

Submitted By sadiadiba
Words 16766
Pages 68
NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES

MOBILE BANKING: THE IMPACT OF M-PESA IN KENYA
Isaac Mbiti
David N. Weil
Working Paper 17129 http://www.nber.org/papers/w17129 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH
1050 Massachusetts Avenue
Cambridge, MA 02138
June 2011

We are grateful to Taryn Dinkelman, John Driscoll, Frederik Eijkman, James Habyarimana, Stephen
Mwaura, Benno Ndulu, Pauline Vaughn, Dean Yang and seminar participants at Tulane University and the NBER Africa Success Conference for helpful comments and suggestions. Emilio Depetris
Chauvin, Federico Droller, Richard Amwayi Namolo, Angeline Nguyen, Scott Weiner and Jingjing
Ye provided superb research assistance. We are grateful to the Financial Sector Deepening (FSD)
Trust of Kenya and Pep Intermedius for providing us with data. Financial support for this research was graciously provided by the NBER Africa Success Project. The views expressed herein are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the National Bureau of Economic Research.
© 2011 by Isaac Mbiti and David N. Weil. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including © notice, is given to the source.

Mobile Banking: The Impact of M-Pesa in Kenya
Isaac Mbiti and David N. Weil
NBER Working Paper No. 17129
June 2011
JEL No. E40,O16,O33
ABSTRACT
M-Pesa is a mobile phone based money transfer system in Kenya which grew at a blistering pace following its inception in 2007. We examine how M-Pesa is used as well as its economic impacts. Analyzing data from two waves of individual data on financial access in Kenya, we find that increased use of
M-Pesa lowers the propensity of people to use informal savings mechanisms such as ROSCAS, but raises the probability of their being banked. Using aggregate data, we calculate the velocity of M-Pesa at between 11.0 and 14.6 person-to-person transfers per month. In addition, we find that M-Pesa causes decreases in the prices of competing money transfer services such as Western Union. While we find little evidence that people use their M-Pesa accounts as a place to store wealth, our results suggest that M-Pesa improves individual outcomes by promoting banking and increasing transfers.

Isaac Mbiti
Department of Economics
Southern Methodist University
3300 Dyer Street
Dallas, TX 75275-0496 imbiti@smu.edu David N. Weil
Department of Economics
Box B
Brown University
Providence, RI 02912 and NBER david_weil@brown.edu 1

Introduction

M-Pesa is a money transfer system operated by Safaricom, Kenya's largest cellular phone provider. M-Pesa allows users to exchange cash for "e-float" on their phones, to send e-float to other cellular phone users, and to exchange e-float back into cash. The story of the growth of mobile telephones in Africa is one of a tectonic and unexpected change in communications technology. From virtually unconnected in the 1990's, over 60 percent of Africans now have mobile phone coverage, and there are now over ten times as many mobile phones as landline phones in use (Aker and Mbiti, 2010). Even with the story of mobile phones' growth as a background, the growth of M-Pesa is startling. Within eight months of its inception in March
2007, over 1.1 million Kenyans had registered to use M-Pesa, and over US$87 million had been transferred over the system (Safaricom, 2007). By September 2009, over 8.5 million Kenyans had registered to use the service and US$3.7 billion (equivalent to 10 percent of Kenya's GDP) had been transferred over the system since inception (Safaricom, 2009). This explosive growth was also mirrored in the growth of M-Pesa agents (or service locations), which grew to over
18,000 locations by April 2010, from a base of approximately 450 in mid-2007 (Safaricom, 2009 and Vaughan, 2007). By contrast, Kenya has only 491 bank branches, 500 postbank branches, and 352 ATMs (Mas and Ng'weno, 2009). While the mobile telephone is within sight of becoming a mature business, e-money services like M-Pesa are still in their early days and are continually evolving in response to competitive pressures and customer needs. Despite all the attention M-Pesa has received, there is little quantitative evidence on its economic and social impacts. The combination of widespread cellular communication and the ability to transfer money instantly, securely, and inexpensively are together leading to enormous changes in the organization of economic activity, family relations, and risk management and mitigation, among other things. A decade ago, family members in different parts of Kenya had a very limited scope of communicating with relatives in distant parts of the country, and they faced even greater difficulties in sending or receiving remittances. Now, in many cases, appeals for assistance and the availability of resources can be communicated, and money can be transferred almost instantaneously. Among the changes observers have noted are changes in the the nature, pattern and impact of remittances. Morawcyznski and Pickens (2009) observe that M-Pesa users sent smaller but more frequent remittances, which resulted in overall larger remittances to rural areas. They also observe that urban migrants using M-Pesa visited their rural homes less frequently, potentially weakening the social ties between migrants and their home communities.
Researchers have also noted the potential of M-Pesa to affect savings. Morawcyznski and
Pickens (2009) observe that users often keep a balance on their M-Pesa accounts, thereby using the system as a rudimentary bank account despite the fact that the system does not provide interest. In addition, Vaughn (2007) notes that some individuals stored money in M-Pesa due to safety considerations, especially when travelling across the country. Using ethnographic methods in three communities, Plyler et al. (2010) argue that M-Pesa has enabled small businesses to expand and grow and has also increased the circulation of money in these communities.

The explosive growth of M-Pesa has inevitably inspired a great deal of discussion about what the system really is and what it could grow to be. Is it simply a low-cost money transfer system competing with (or replacing) modalities such as cheques and Western Union? Is it a nascent form of electronic money that will someday largely displace cash? Can it be used as a savings account? Is it a means by which financial services can be provided to the unbanked?
Suri and Jack (2011) report that three out of four M-Pesa users indicate that they use it to save money. Recently, the potential for M-Pesa to be a savings vehicle has received even more attention, as Safaricom and Equity Bank have introduced M-Kesho, an interest-bearing savings account that is directly linked to M-Pesa.
In this paper we examine how M-Pesa is being used in Kenya. We combine data from a number of sources including micro-level survey data (the FinAccess surveys), transaction data from M-Pesa agents, price data from money transfer companies, and aggregate data from
Safaricom and the Central Bank of Kenya. We pay particular attention to the question of whether M-Pesa is solely a low-value money transfer system or a nascent form of a means of saving, providing broader financial access for people who are unbanked.
The rest of this paper is organized as follows. In Section 2, we briefly discuss the structure of M-Pesa. In Section 3, we examine M-Pesa’s role as a money transfer service. We also examine the characteristics of users, explore data on the distribution of withdrawal and deposit sizes, and analyze the effect of M-Pesa on alternative money transfer modalities. In
Section 4, we examine microeconomic evidence of how M-Pesa affects outcomes such as the propensity of individuals to use financial institutions as well as to accumulate savings. In
Section 5, we explore the monetary aspects of M-Pesa, including the velocity of e-money circulation. Section 6 addresses the question of why people do not store much value in their MPesa accounts. Section 7 concludes.

2

M-Pesa Structure

Basic Structure
There are three basic transactions that customers conduct with M-Pesa.


A customer may deposit money at an M-Pesa outlet in return for e-float (called a "cashin" transaction.) The customer is required to show a valid identification document, and his identity and the amount of the deposit are logged in a book kept at the outlet. Upon receipt of the money, the M-Pesa agent enters the customer's telephone number and deposit information into his/her cell phone, and the customer waits at the outlet window until he/she receives a confirmation text message that e-float has been deposited. Unless the system is running slowly (which happens occasionally), the whole transaction takes about a minute or less.



A customer may exchange e-float for cash at an M-Pesa outlet (called a "cash out" transaction.) Again, the customer must show a valid identification document, and the transaction is logged. The customer tells the the shop clerk how much cash he/she wants, then chooses "withdraw cash" on the M-Pesa menu on his phone, enters the amount to be withdrawn (plus the relevant fee), and enters the agent number. The agent then receives a text indicating that the transaction is complete, and the agent then gives the appropriate amount of cash to the customer. This whole transaction takes about one minute.



Finally, a user may transfer e-float from his/her phone to another phone. Our study refers to such a transfer as a “person-to-person transfer,” even though one or both of the parties may be an institution or firm. The user enters the phone number of the recipient and the amount to be transferred on his/her cellphone. The sender and recipient each receive a text message stating that money has been transferred.

These three basic transactions can be combined in a number of ways. For example, a user may deposit cash and send the full amount deposited to another user, who can then withdraw the full amount transferred. We refer to this use as "deposit-transfer-withdraw." Alternatively, a user who receives a transfer from one person may transfer the e-float to some other user instead of withdrawing cash. E-float could circulate in this manner indefinitely, like conventional cash. A third usage possibility is where a user deposits cash and then later withdraws it him/herself without having transferred it. Anecdotally, it is said that people do this for safety when they are traveling (Vaughan, 2007; Morawczynski, 2009).
The usage patterns described above can be mixed in varying ways. For example, a user may receive a transfer and withdraw some of the value while transferring some of the remaining amount elsewhere and leaving some e-float in his account for future transactions. Of particular interest to us is a pattern in which a user might receive a transfer and not withdraw it right away for several reasons: to economize on transaction fees, to economize on the effort of going to an
M-Pesa outlet, or to benefit from the safety of storing value on a phone rather than in cash. MPesa is safer than cash because a PIN is required to perform any transaction. If a phone is stolen or lost, the M-Pesa funds are safe unless the PIN has been compromised. If the PIN is compromised and funds are transfered to another account, the legitimate account holder can recover his/her funds if they have not been withdrawn by the fraudulent recipient by initiating a transfer reversal through the customer service department.
One of our goals is to better understand such patterns of use. One question in particular is how much of the use of M-Pesa is of the deposit-transfer-withdraw type. To the extent that it is used just this way, M-Pesa is primarily a simple money transfer service (which is hardly to say that it isn't economically important). By contrast, other uses of M-Pesa suggest other functions.
To the extent that e-money circulates among several users between an initial cash-in transaction and a final cash-out transaction, it can be seen as an evolving alternative to currency. Similarly, to the extent that people hold e-float balances on their phones for significant periods of time, M-

Pesa can be seen as having aspects of banking (as will be seen below, one can even view it as paying interest.)1
All M-Pesa e-float is backed 100% by deposits held at three commercial banks in Kenya.
Interest earned on these deposits is donated to a charity, which allows Safaricom to avoid being regulated as a bank. An extensive description of the arrangements between Safaricom and the network of agents who service M-Pesa users can be found in Eijkman, Kendall, and Mas (2010) and Suri and Jack (2011).

Pricing
Table 1 shows the basic pricing scheme for M-Pesa. To deposit money, a user must register with
M-Pesa at an agent location. This is a relatively short process and only requires a valid identification document such as a national ID or passport. Recipients of M-Pesa need not be registered. There is a higher fee for sending money to non-registered users, but they are not charged any fees to withdraw money and are unable to send the money onwards since they are unregistered. The overall transaction fee is far lower for sending to a registered user than to a non-registered user. In practice 70 percent of users are registered, and approximately 90 percent of transactions are conducted by registered users.2
The pricing structure of M-Pesa is simple and intuitive. However, the pricing structure has a number of "notches" in the terminology of Slemrod (2010). These are points at which incremental changes in customer behavior cause discrete jumps in costs. The incentives around notches are far stronger than those observed at "kinks" in price schedules, such as points where the marginal tax rate changes. For example, in the M-Pesa tariff schedule, the fee for withdrawing up to 1-2,500 Ksh is 25 Ksh., while the fee for withdrawing 2,501-5,000 Ksh. is 45
Ksh. Thus, a person who withdraws 2,600 Ksh. will be paying a marginal fee of 20 Ksh. (20%) on the last 100 Ksh. withdrawn compared to a fee of 1% on the first 2,500 Ksh. withdrawn. The response of users to the price notches in the M-Pesa tariff schedule should be informative about

1

As mentioned above, Safaricom and Equity Bank are now introducing a new service called M-Kesho which allows for mobile phone access to a low-cost bank account. There is no charge for opening the account, no periodic fees, and no minimum or maximum balance (M-Pesa has a maximum balance of 50,000 Ksh.) Balances from 1-2,000
Ksh (approximately 0.13-25 USD) receive 0.5% interest per year; from 2,001-5,000 KSH, 1% per year; from 5,00110,000 KSH, 2% per year; and above 10,000 KSH ($125), 3% per year. Funds can be transferred without a free from M-Pesa to M-Kesho, although transfer back to M-Pesa costs 30 Ksh. M-Kesho also offers microcredit and insurance services. Microloans can be requested for 100-5000 Ksh, with a 10% application fee. Loans are approved or rejected based on a credit score determined by looking at M-Pesa, M-Kesho, and Equity Bank account activity in the last 6 months, and must be paid back within 30 days (a penalty of 3% of one's outstanding balance is charged for every day after this 30-day period). Insurance can be obtained for 530 Ksh for a year if paid all at once, 830 Ksh for the year if paid on a monthly basis, or 1030 Ksh for a year if paid on a weekly basis. For the first year, this insurance is limited to personal accident related expenses (though this is fairly broadly defined), but after a year it is upgraded to full life insurance (150,000 ksh. death or permanent disability benefit plus 20,000 ksh. funeral expenses.) 2

Refer to the data appendix for details on the computation of this variable

the optimization problems faced by users. Below, we explore this issue by looking at data on the distribution of withdrawal sizes.

3

3.1

3.1.1

Uses and Economic Impacts of M-Pesa

M-Pesa as a Money Transfer System

Survey Results

How money was sent in 2006 and 2009
Prior to the introduction of M-pesa, individuals used a mixture of informal and formal channels to transfer money. Larger bus companies such as Akamba Bus company or Scandinavia Bus
Company offered formal money or parcel transfer services, where recipients would collect the funds at a designated bus terminal. However, smaller bus companies or independent mini-bus operators (matatus) would perform these transactions informally, and in some cases the bus driver would carry the funds with the promise to deliver them. In other cases, individuals would disguise money transfers as packages and place them on the bus for delivery to the designated terminal ( Kabbucho et al., 2003 and Morawczynski, 2009). The post office offered a variety of different money transfer products including instant money transfer (postapay) and money orders which would be delivered to the post office closest to the recipient (Kabbucho et al., 2003).
Banks and money transfer companies such as Western Union or Moneygram also offered transfer services, although their outlet or branch networks were not as extensive as the post office's. Figures 1 and 2 show the change in sending and receiving methods between 2006 and
2009. The figures show that the most common methods to send or receive money were through friends, bus companies, or the post office in 2006. Over 50 percent of people sent money using friends while close to 50 percent received money via this medium. Approximately 20 percent sent money using the post office, while close to 30 percent received funds this way. Other formal methods such as sending money through banks or money transfer companies like Western Union were less common with less than 10 percent using these methods to send or receive funds.
The inception of M-Pesa in 2007 dramatically changed the money transfer market. In less than two years since its inception, M-Pesa was the leading money transfer method with over 50 percent sending money via M-Pesa and over 65 percent receiving funds through the system in
2009 (Figures 1 and 2). The emergence of M-Pesa as the dominant money transfer mechanism virtually eliminated the use of post office products, bus companies, and formal channels such as
Western Union and banks, where between 3.5 percent and 0.4 percent of individuals now use

these methods to send or receive money (Figures 1 and 2). However, sending and receiving funds through friends remains a popular means of money transfer, where 33 percent of individuals send money via a friend and 22 percent receive funds through a friend in 2009
(Figures 1 and 2).

Uses of M-Pesa
Figure 3 summarizes the data on M-Pesa use from the 2009 Finacess Survey in descending order of frequency. Close to 42 percent of M-Pesa users reported using the system to purchase mobile phone airtime. Approximately 26 percent of users reported using M-Pesa to save money. While this is a relatively high proportion, it is much lower than the 75 percent saving rate reported in
Jack and Suri (2011). Close to 20 percent of users also report using M-Pesa while travelling, presumably for safety concerns as discussed in Vaughan (2007) and Morawczynski (2009).
Approximately six percent of users made donations via M-Pesa, and our experience in the field suggests this has grown as currently the majority of calls for donations now include an M-Pesa option. Only six percent claim to receive payments on M-Pesa, while only two percent claim to receive salaries or wages by M-Pesa. Despite these low levels, 50 percent of M-Pesa users report that they would like to receive their main income by M-Pesa, mainly due to speed and accessibility. The main reported reasons for not wanting to use M-Pesa for the receipt of income was a strong cash preference (30 percent) and a fear of losing their phone (25 percent).
Surprisingly, 17 percent of those who did not want to receive their income on M-pesa were worried they could access the money too easily and thus spend it right away, while another 14 percent claimed their salary would not fit in M-Pesa. Almost 4 percent used an ATM to withdraw cash from their M-Pesa account and 3 percent used M-pesa to buy goods or pay bills.
While the bill-paying prevalence was low in 2009, we expect this to grow as Safaricom has initiated a number of strategic partnerships where customers may now pay for goods and services using M-Pesa. For example, several hospitals, insurance companies, schools, and grocery stores now accept M-Pesa payments. As argued in Aker and Mbiti (2010), these partnerships are part of
M-Pesa’s evolution from a pure money transfer system into a payment platform and a formal
(regulated) financial service.

3.1.2 Distribution of Withdrawals and Deposits
Our data comes from three M-Pesa outlets. As described in Eijkman, Kendall and Mas (2010),
Cyber Center is an urban outlet in the city of Kisumu, which has a population of 350,000. The outlet is located near one of the city's markets. Katito is small town with a population of roughly five thousand, located in a rural area about a one-hour trip from Kisumu. It also services surrounding rural areas. Homa Bay is classified as a "district" outlet, meaning that it is in a provincial market town with a population of roughly 20,000 on a main highway.

Table 2 shows data on the distribution of withdrawal and deposit amounts at the three outlets. Figure 4 show the histograms of the distribution of withdrawals from each outlet. The most striking finding in this data is the extent to which a large part of the distribution is composed of very small withdrawals. This is most visible in Katito, the rural outlet, where the median withdrawal is only 900 Ksh. (about US $13). The 10th percentile of the distibution of withdrawals in Katito is 250 Ksh., which implies that one-tenth of users pay a commission of
10% or more.3
We can also use Figure 4 to address the issue of whether there is a large response to the price notches in the M-Pesa tariff discussed above. Although we do not perform a formal test, in most applicable cases we see remarkably little evidence of any response to these notches at all.
In the case of Katito, for example, the only price notch that is in the range of an appreciable part of the data is at 2,500 Ksh. Although there is indeed a point of mass at this level, it is not out of line with what one would expect given the similar masses at round numbers (500, 1,000, 1,500, etc.). Indeed, there were many fewer withdrawals at 2,500 Ksh. than at 3,000 Ksh. We see this for the other outlets as well. It is true that in Homa Bay, which has the largest withdrawals, there are large spikes in the distribution at 10,000 and 20,000 ksh., both of which are price notches.
Similarly, there is a spike at 10,000 at Cyber Center. This is consistent with users reacting to the incentives of the price notches, but it is also possible that these large spikes are just due to these figures being round numbers.
As another test of whether users of M-Pesa change their behavior in response to characteristics of the pricing structure, we examined data on deposit sizes. Specifically, we are interested in the extent to which people transferring money take into account the fees paid by those who withdraw money (and also the transfer fees that they pay themselves). If such a deposits are made as part of a deposit-transfer-withdraw transaction, then the total fees of the transaction will be 55 Ksh (that is, 30 Ksh. for the transfer plus 25 Ksh for the withdrawal). A depositor who wanted the recipient to end up with, say, 1,000 Ksh. would have to deposit 1,055
Ksh. We think of small deposits in amounts ending with 55 Ksh as being "fee aware." To the extent that we see deposits of such amounts, it suggests to us that there is a confluence of three factors: first, the depositor intends to transfer the full amount of his/her deposit (minus the transfer fee); second that he/she expects the recipient to withdraw the amount of the transfer received; and third that the sender wants the recipient to have access to a round-number amount of money.
Table 3 shows data on the deposits pooled from the three outlets described above. We consider only deposit amounts below 2,600 Ksh, because the withdrawal fee rises after 2,500
Ksh.4 Our sample is 6,036 deposits. We tabulate deposits based on the last two digits of the deposit size. The table shows that, not surprisingly, the biggest masses of the distribution are at
00, 50, and 25, which are simply round numbers. However, the fourth largest mass in the distribution (6.8%) is indeed at 55, which clearly corresponds to awareness of fees. Further, the
3

Although we do not have data that links withdrawals to transfers, it is likely that in most cases, someone who withdraws 250 ksh. has just received this as a transfer, which cost the sender 30 ksh. Thus the overall cost of receiving 225 ksh. after fees was 280 ksh., a loss of 19.6%.
4
The withdrawal fee itself is not counted toward the price of a withdrawal. Thus a customer with a balance of Ksh.
2525 in her account could receive Ksh. 2500 in cash

fifth largest mass in the distribution is at 30 (4.0%), suggesting that some depositors are taking into account transfer fees but not withdrawal fees. Nonetheless, our interpretation of this data is that fee-aware deposits are relatively rare. Of course it is not clear which of the three factors described above is failing in most cases.

3.1.3

The Impact of M-pesa on Money Transfer Companies

A number of papers have documented the impacts of mobile phones causing reduced price variation in markets. Jensen (2007) and Aker (2010) find that the introduction of mobile phones reduced price dispersion in fish markets in India and grain markets in Niger respectively. In these instances the mobile phone technology has increased information flows, which has resulted in price reductions. In contrast, the development and introduction of M-pesa can be viewed as a
"disruptive technology" (Bower and Christensen, 1995) or an example of "creative destruction"
(Schumpeter, 1942 and Aghion and Howitt, 1992), where M-Pesa revolutionized the money transfer industry. As Figures 1 and 2 show, M-Pesa became the dominant money transfer mechanism within 2 years of its inception. Ethnographic work by Morawczynski (2009) suggests that M-Pesa's popularity has been driven by its speed, safety, reliability, extensive network of outlets, and its price relative to the alternatives. Prior to the introduction of M-Pesa, Kabbucho et al (2003) document that the cost of instantly sending US$100 through formal channels ranged between US$12 (MoneyGram) and US$20 (bank wire transfer), while the cost slower formal channels ranged from $3 (bus companies) to $6 (postal money order). Compared to these alternatives M-Pesa offered a significantly cheaper method of instantly transferring funds, where the cost of sending US$100 to a non-registered user by M-pesa was approximately US$2.50 in early 2008, while the cost of sending to a registered user was even less (Safaricom, 2008).
The dominance of M-pesa can also be observed in the the financial statements of the competitors. Gikunju (2009) examines the financial statements of the Postal Corporation of
Kenya and finds that revenues and profits for its PostaPay money transfer service declined rapidly after the introduction of M-Pesa and suggests that Western Union’s and MoneyGram’s profits have also declined over the same period. Faced with obsolescence, money transfer companies such as Western Union and MoneyGram have responded by cutting prices, even though they are still unable to match M-pesa's superior convenience (Gikunju, 2009). Figure 5 shows the changes in the money transfer price schedule for Western Union and MoneyGram from the pre-M-Pesa period to the post- M-Pesa period. Overall, these figures show a dramatic reduction in the transaction prices of money transfers. On average, the commission (defined as price to send money divided by the amount sent) charged for money transfers fell from approximately 7% in 2003 to 3% in 2010. However, we cannot entirely attribute this decline to the competitive pressures induced by the M-Pesa revolution as other factors such as general technological changecould reduce transaction costs and thus reduce prices. Therefore, simple before-and-after comparisons of the price changes will not be sufficient to identify the competitive impact of M-Pesa on the prices of competitors.
We employ a difference-in-difference estimation strategy in order to identify the impact of
M-Pesa on competitors prices. We construct a database of prices for the main formal competitors

in Kenya: MoneyGram and Western Union.5 We obtained the pre-M-Pesa price schedules from
Kabbucho et al (2003) and the current price schedules from each provider’s website. As each firm uses different price brackets, we created consistent and comparable price schedules by examining the commissions (price/send amount) for send amounts in 100 Kshs intervals ranging from each company’s minimum send amount to each company’s maximum send amount.5 Our empirical strategy exploits the differences in maximum transaction limits between M-Pesa and its competitors. Central Bank Regulations place a maximum transaction limit of 35,000 Kshs on
M-Pesa, while the transaction limits of MoneyGram and Western Union transactions exceed
500,000 Kshs. Given these transaction limits, we would expect to see greater competitive pressures due to M-Pesa on transactions below the M-Pesa threshold of 35,000 Kshs compared to transactions above that threshold. Figure 5 provides some suggestive evidence of this effect.
Focusing on Moneygram, we see that the prices for smaller transactions decreased dramatically, while those for large transactions remained more static. A simple comparison of means above and below the 35,000 Kshs threshold and across time is shown in Table 4. This table shows that there were larger reductions in the prices of transfers below 35,000 Kshs compared to those above. We can formally examine this assertion using the following empirical specification:

p jkt = δ 0 + δ 1under 35 j + δ 2 post t + δ 3 under 35 j × post t + λ j + γ k + ε jkt

(1)

where is the commission defined as price of sending j shillings, under35 is a dummy variable that indicates whether the transaction amount j is less than 35,000 shillings, post is an indicator variable for the post M-pesa period (i.e. 2010), λ is a transaction amount fixed effect and γ is a company fixed effect. The coefficient of interest is δ 3 , which captures the impact of M-Pesa on prices. The estimates from Equation 1 are shown in Table 5. These results show that the prices of transactions below 35,000 shillings fell by six percentage points, which is approximately a 43 percent reduction in the prices of transactions under 35,000 shillings from 2003. Overall, prices in this segment fell from approximately 14 percent to four percent; thus, our estimates imply that competitive pressure from M-Pesa accounts for approximately 60 percent of the decline in prices from 2003 to 2010.
A potential concern with our estimation strategy is that we could be simply capturing falling trends in prices. Since we only have two periods of data, we cannot include company specific trends in our analysis. However, we can perform some falsification tests to ensure that our results are not spurious. We create a series of false (and arbitrary) thresholds of 100,000,
125,000 and 150,000 Kshs. and estimate Equation 1 using these fake thresholds and restrict the sample to transactions over 35,000 shillings to avoid M-Pesa effects. Table 6 shows the results of this falsification exercise. We do not find negative effects of these false thresholds, but we do find small but positive and significant impacts of this threshold suggesting that trends are not driving our results discussed above.

5

The Postal Corporation of Kenya also has an instant money transfer product called Posta Pay. However, we were unable to collect pre-M-Pesa prices. We did have early 2008 prices and we do observe the same patterns as we show in our regressions

While M-Pesa has forced money transfer companies to lower prices, M-Pesa has also induced these firms and other financial firms to improve their products and services. In some cases, firms have partnered with M-Pesa to offer an integrated service. For example, Western
Union recently partnered with M-Pesa to offer international money transfers in which migrants in the diaspora can now send remittances to their friends and family via M-Pesa with Western
Union serving as an intermediary. Pesa-Point, an independent network of ATMs, allows M-Pesa users to withdraw cash using its large network of ATMs. Commercial banks in Kenya were initially opposed to M-Pesa and lobbied the government to regulate M-Pesa and other mobile money platforms under the commercial banking regulations (Njiraini and Anyanzwa, 2008).
After these efforts failed, banks partnered with M-Pesa to offer better services to customers and in some cases became M-Pesa agents. There is also suggestive evidence that M-Pesa has increased the efficiency of the banking system. According to a 2009 newspaper article, the advent of M-Pesa has caused commercial banks to work toward speeding up the check clearing process, which took a minimum of three days.6

3.2 Characteristics of Users

We use data from the 2009 FinAccess survey to examine basic patterns and characteristics of MPesa users and their usage patterns. Overall, our data show that approximately 40 percent of
Kenyans have used M-Pesa, with close to 30 percent formally registered with Safaricom. As discussed in Aker and Mbiti (2010), M-Pesa users are more likely to be younger, wealthier, better educated, banked, employed in non-farm sectors, to own cell phones, and to reside in urban areas (Table 7).
We examine cross-tabulations of M-Pesa use by individual characteristics in Table 8.
Males, urban residents, banked individuals, the wealthy, the better-educated, and those employed in the non-farm sector were more likely to use M-Pesa. Higher socio-economic status individuals are more likely to use M-Pesa to purchase airtime, save and store money while travelling, and use M-Pesa to pay wages than their respective counterparts. Focusing on saving patterns, Table 8 shows that 35 percent of banked individuals use M-Pesa to save while only 19 percent of unbanked individuals used M-Pesa to save. Similarly, 30 percent of wealthy individuals report using M-Pesa to save, while only 15 percent of poor individuals report doing so. Similar gaps are also observed between the more-educated and less-educated individuals. When we examine the characteristics of users who use M-Pesa as a safe-keeping mechanism while travelling, we find very similar patterns to those found in savings. We find that the wealthier, more-educated, and banked individuals are each approximately 2.5 times more likely to report using M-Pesa while travelling when compared to their counterparts.

6

"Why central bank position on mobile banking attracts wrath," 2/6/2009, The Standard http://www.standardmedia.co.ke/InsidePage.php?id=1144015709&cid=457& We observe large differences in the frequency of M-Pesa use across demographic and economic groups in Table 9. Individuals with bank accounts use M-Pesa almost three times as much as those without bank accounts. Urban residents, richer individuals, the more-educated, and those in the non-farm sector use M-Pesa almost twice as often as rural residents, poorer individuals, the less-educated and those employed in the farm sector respectively. While those with mobile phone used M-Pesa three times as often as those without phones, there are much smaller differences between men and women (with men using M-Pesa 35 percent more frequently than women). As Columns (2) to (5) suggest, these disparities are mainly driven by differences in daily and weekly use, in which the banked are almost three times as likely to use
M-Pesa daily or weekly as the unbanked, and urban residents are almost twice as likely to use MPesa daily or weekly compared to rural residents. While daily and weekly users are generally more affluent, educated, and urban, they only account for 1.6 and 14.4 percent of all users respectively, while 32.7 percent of users are monthly users, and 51.3 percent are irregular users.
However, using our annualized measure of M-Pesa usage, we find that daily users (1.6 percent of users) account for 32 percent of transactions, weekly users account for 41 percent of transactions, monthly users account for approximately 21 percent of transactions, and irregular users account for only 6% of transactions.
Overall, these simple cross-tabulations of the intensity of M-Pesa use and the main uses of M-Pesa by individual characteristics reveal that the most intense users generally have higher socio-economic status. Moreover, theses higher SES individuals are also more likely to use MPesa in ways that could reap large economic gains such as savings. Taken together, these patterns perhaps suggest that more affluent members of society are among the biggest beneficiaries of M-Pesa. This, of course, does not preclude poorer and more vulnerable members of society from reaping significant economic and social benefits from M-Pesa. More research will be needed to examine the extent to which M-Pesa benefits are distributed across socioeconomic strata.

4.

Economic Impacts of M-Pesa: Micro-level evidence

Morawcyznski and Pickens (2009) find that M-Pesa has changed the patterns of remittances.
This observation is supported by the 2009 FinAccess surveys which show that almost 35 percent report that they have increased the frequency of sending transfers due to M-Pesa, while 31 percent report an increase in the receipt frequency of transfers due to M-Pesa. (Figure 6).
Surprisingly, 18 percent report a decrease in the sending frequency, while 22 percent report a decrease in the receiving frequency, with the remainder reporting no change in transfer frequency. Figure 7 shows the change in the amount of transfers received. Almost 35 percent of users claim that they sent larger transfers due to M-Pesa, while 30 percent claim to have received larger transfers because of M-Pesa. In contrast roughly 20 percent report decreases in the amount of transfers sent or received, with the remainder reporting no change in the amount of transfers received or reported. We find very strong correlations between reported changes in transfer frequency and reported changes in the amount transferred. Over 85 percent of individuals report the same effect for both changes in frequency and changes in transfer amount (for both sending and receiving). For example, 87 percent of individuals who claim to have received transfers more

frequently report that the amount of transfer has also increased, and a very small percentage report sending smaller transfers more frequently. This suggests that people do not in fact send smaller transfers more frequently as reported in Morawcyznski and Pickens (2009). However, as we have no data on the extent or magnitude of these changes, we are unable to examine the magnitude of changes in the frequency or size of transfers due to M-Pesa.
The qualititative studies on M-Pesa such as Morawczynski and Pickens (2009) have suggested that M-Pesa serves as a partial substitute for the formal banking system. Prior to the introduction of M-Pesa, most Africans were excluded from modern financial services. Using data ranging between 2001 and 2005, Beck et al. (2007) show that African countries lagged in financial access. During this period they show that Ghana had 1.6 branches per 100,000 and
Kenya had 1.3 branches per 100,000, while Uganda and Tanzania both had less than 0.6 branches per 100,000. The ATM penetration of these countries was even lower -- ranging from 1 per 100,000 in Kenya to less than 0.20 per 100,000 in Tanzania. In contrast, the U.S. had 31 bank branches and 120 ATMs per 100,000 people during that period. Perhaps partly as a result of the small banking networks in many African countries, a low proportion of individuals have a bank account. On average the FinScope surveys show that 30% of East and Southern African adults have a formal bank account (FinMark Trust, 2008). These proportions range from a high of 63% in South Africa to low of 9% in Tanzania. With the low levels of financial development in many African countries, many observers have identified the potential for systems such as MPesa to expand the reach of the financial system and provide a platform to deliver financial services to the poor and excluded. Burgess and Pande (2005) show that the expansion of rural banking in India significantly reduced rural poverty rates. While this was mainly driven by increased access to credit, mobile systems such as M-Pesa could facilitate the expansion of branchless banking, in which banks increase the financial reach using agents as intermediaries to provide services to clients in rural and remote areas where the fixed costs of opening a branch would be prohibitive (Pickens et al., 2009). This possibility, however, is contingent upon banks' willingness to serve poorer clients and upon government regulations that promote or hinder branchless banking.
A number of qualitative studies such as Morawczynski and Pickens (2009) and Mas and
Morawczynski (2009) have explored the economic and social impacts of M-Pesa in Kenya. For instance, Morawczynski and Pickens (2009) find ethnographic evidence that M-Pesa has changed the savings behavior, the pattern of remittances, and has increased rural livelihoods.
While these studies provide suggestive evidence of the impacts of M-Pesa, they are generally unable to quantify the effects of the system and are limited by their small sample sizes. An exception is Jack and Suri's (2010) empirical study that shows that M-Pesa improves the ability of households to smooth risks. We contribute to the literature by providing quantitative estimates of the impact of M-Pesa in Kenya on a variety of economic and social outcomes including financial access and usage. We combine the 2006 and 2009 Finaccess surveys and create a balanced panel of the 190 sub-locations that were surveyed in both rounds in order to examine the economic impact of M-Pesa on various outcomes pertaining to remittances, financial access, and economic livelihood.7 Sublocations are the smallest administrative unit in Kenya and consist of 2 to 3 villages in rural areas or a large neighborhood in a city. The summary statistics of this estimation sample is shown in Table 10.
7

See data appendix for more details on the construction of the estimation sample.

We examine the relationship between M-Pesa and various economic and social outcomes at the sublocation level using the following specification: y jt = β 0 + β 1 mpesa jt + X ' jt β 2 + β 3Tt + μ j + υ jt

(2)

where mpesa jt is the proportion of individuals that use M-Pesa in sublocation j at period t, X is a vector of controls including education, gender, age, marriage rate, and wealth, T is a time fixed effect, μ is the sub-location fixed effect that captures time invariant unobservable variables at the sub-location level, and υ is an idiosyncratic error term. y is a set of outcomes variables that includes frequency of sending and receiving transfers, possession of a bank account, saving methods and employment.
Simple regression estimation of equation (2) will lead to biased and inconsistent estimates if the time-invariant unobservables ( μ ) or the time-varying unobservables ( υ ) are correlated with MPesa use and our set of outcome variables. To circumvent this we employ a sub-location fixed effects instrumental variable (FE-IV) procedure to eliminate the time-invariant heterogeneity and biases due to endogenous M-Pesa adoption. Specifying Δ as the sub-location first-difference operator, we can estimate the following fixed effect regression:
Δy jt = β 0 + β 1 Δmpesa jt + ΔX ' jt β 2 + Δυ jt

(3)

While biases due to time-invariant unobservables are eliminated in equation (3), the estimates will still be biased and inconsistent if Δε is correlated with Δmpesa. We need an instrument (or a set of instruments) that predicts M-Pesa use but does not directly impact our set of outcomes. Both rounds of the data contain perceptions of the most common money transfer methods; however, we focus solely upon the 2006 perception data as the 2009 perceptions would be influenced by M-Pesa. Respondents are asked to identify the riskiest, slowest and costly money transfer method. We focus on the proportion of residents that identify sending money with a friend as the riskiest method, the proportion of residents that identify the post office as the slowest and the proportion that identify money transfer companies as the most expensive. If more respondents in a sub-location feel that their alternative means of transferring money are inefficient, they would be more likely to adopt M-Pesa. Moreover, conditional on the sublocation fixed effect, this 2006 perception should have no direct impact on outcomes (or the change in outcomes). The identification assumption is conditional on the vector of controls (such as wealth and education) and the sub-location fixed effect, the perceptions of the alternative methods will only indirectly affect the set of outcomes (such as banking) through M-Pesa adoption. We can specify the set of estimating equations for the FE-IV regression as:
Δy jt = β 0 + β 1 Δmpesa jt + ΔX ' jt β 2 + Δυ jt

(4)

Δmpesa jt = α 0 + Z ' j 0 α 1 + ΔX ' jt α 2 + Δν

(5)

where Z is the set of instruments: the proportion that rank friends as the riskiest method to transfer money in 2006, the proportion that rank the post office as the slowest method in 2006 and the proportion that rank money transfer companies as the most expensive option in 2006.
The extent to which transferring funds through friends is risky will be mostly determined by social capital and crime. In terms of financial access, the most plausible concern is that banks are less likely to locate in these areas due to security concerns. Since these areas are more likely to adopt M-Pesa then this would lead to an underestimate of the impact of M-Pesa adoption on financial access. The are a number of factors that could determine efficiency of money transfers via the post-office. First, these could reflect the motivation of post office employees. Employee motivation could be driven by the quality of supervision. If better supervisors were located in faster growing areas (which were more likely to see expansions of financial services), then this would also lead to underestimates of the impact of M-Pesa adoption. Alternatively, the speed of the post office could reflect the quality of transportation links or local infrastructure (e.g. electricity, telephone links). If financial institutions were less likely to expand to these more
“isolated” areas, then this would again lead to an underestimate of the impact of M-Pesa adoption. However, if these institutions were more likely to expand in these areas then our methodology would overestimate the impact of M-Pesa adoption. However, we feel that the costs of operating in “isolated” areas may be prohibitive for banks and thus we feel that they are unlikely to expand in these areas. Finally, the speed of the post office could reflect Since the price schedule for money transfer companies does not vary within Kenya, the perceptions of cost are likely driven by marketing and word of mouth. If these companies target their marketing in faster growing areas (which were more likely to see expansions of financial services), then this would also lead to underestimates of the impact of M-Pesa adoption.
The results from equations (2) to (3) are shown in Table 11. The estimates from the random effects specifications show a positive relationship between M-Pesa adoption and frequency of sending and receiving transfers, although only the estimate of sending transfers is statistically significant. The estimates also show a strong positive association between M-Pesa adoption and bank use, formal savings, and employment. In addition, the estimates show a negative and statistically significant relationship between M-Pesa adoption and saving money using secret hiding places. Similar patterns are observed in fixed effect specifications. The point estimates on sending remittances, bank use, formal savings, and employment are very similar when compared to the random effects specifications. However, we do observe the larger negative correlations between M-Pesa and informal savings and using a secret hiding place to save money. We estimate equations (4) and (5) in order to obtain causal estimates of the impacts of MPesa. Table 12 shows first stage relationship between our set of instruments and the endogenous variables. The estimates show that M-Pesa adoption was positively correlated with greater proportions of individuals who rank using friends as the riskiest money transfer method.
Similarly, perceived slowness of transferring funds using the post office in period 0 and the perceived cost of money transfer companies have positive and significant effects on M-Pesa

adoption. This set of instruments is highly significant, with a joint F test of 26, which is well above the weak instrument thresholds.
The FE-IV estimates of equation (4) and (5) are shown in Table 13. These estimates show that M-Pesa adoption led to increases in the frequency of sending transfers. The point estimate shows that if M-Pesa were universally adopted, individuals would send 5 more remittances per annum. Evaluating this point estimate using the mean M-Pesa adoption rate of 40 percent, we see that M-Pesa increased the frequency of sending remittances by 2, which is more than double the
2006 level. Our estimates imply that M-Pesa accounts for almost the entire increase in the sending frequency of transfers between 2006 and 2009 (Table 10). This is consistent with Figure
6, which shows that 35% report increases in the frequency of sending transfers due to M-Pesa.
While we observe significant increases in the sending frequency of transfers, we surprisingly do not find any effect of M-Pesa on the frequency of receiving transfers, even though 30% report increases in frequency of receiving transfers due to M-Pesa.
While M-Pesa has been touted for banking the "unbanked", there are no estimates on the direct impact of M-Pesa on people adopting bank accounts. Row (5) of Table 13 provides this evidence. These estimates show that increased M-Pesa adoption leads to greater bank use. The point estimates imply that universal adoption of M-Pesa would increase the proportion banked by 28 percentage points. Evaluated at the mean adoption rate of 40 percent, we see that M-Pesa has increased the proportion banked by almost 11 percentage points, which represents a 58 percent increase over the 2006 banking level. As the data was collected prior to the integration of
M-Pesa with banks, this result could be driven by increases in money (or cash) by users. It could also be driven by the complementarity between M-Pesa and banks. If M-Pesa were more valuable or useful in combination with a bank (or vice versa), then increases in demand for MPesa would also increase the demand for banking. This evidence provides some evidence that MPesa does not entirely serve as a substitute for the formal banking system, but, rather, is viewed
(or used) as a complementary tool by individuals.
Qualitative evidence from Morawczynski and Pickens (2009) suggests that M-pesa is used as a saving instrument. This notion is supported by the 2009 round of the Finaccess survey in which over 25% of individuals report using M-Pesa as a saving device. While we do not have data on the amount saved, we do have information on the methods used to save and can therefore examine the impact of M-Pesa on savings methods. Row (7) of Table 13 shows the impact of MPesa on the use of informal saving mechanisms. Informal saving mechanisms include rotating saving and credit associations (ROSCA), saving with a group of friends, savings given to a family or friend for safe-keeping, and saving by storing funds in a secret place. While the summary statistics show that the proportion of individuals using informal methods to save has increased from 52 percent to 72 percent, our estimates show that M-Pesa decreases the use of informal saving mechanisms. Evaluated at the mean M-Pesa adoption rate, M-Pesa would reduce the prevalence of informal saving by 15 percentage points, approximately a 30% reduction from the 2006 level. We observe similar effects for the use of secret hiding places to save money. Row
(8) of Table 13 shows that for the average adoption rate, M-Pesa would reduce the proportion of people saving money in secret places by 30 percentage points, which is slightly greater in magnitude than the 2006 level. Since we do not observe any changes in the use of formal savings

methods (which do not include M-Pesa), these results suggest that users are shifting savings from informal tools to M-Pesa perhaps due to the superior security of M-Pesa.
M-Pesa could also affect economic activity directly by increasing access to funds and indirectly by increasing savings and banking rates. Plyler et al (2010) argue that M-Pesa has promoted the growth rates of (small-scale) firms in the communities they studied, and they argue that this was largely driven by the increased circulation of money in these communities. Figure 7 provides some supportive evidence of the increase in funds due to M-Pesa, in which almost 35 percent of individuals report that they sent larger transfers due to M-Pesa, while close to 30 percent report that they received larger transfers due to M-Pesa.
We use employment as a measure of economic activity and examine the impacts of MPesa on employment. We use a measure of employment that incorporates farm labor (own-farm and on others farm), non-farm labor (such as civil service employment), and self-employment
(such as owning a shop). Individuals are considered employed if they are actively engaged in any of these activities. Row (12) of Table 13 shows that M-Pesa is associated with increases in any type of employment. For the average M-Pesa adoption level, M-Pesa would increase employment by 12 percentage points, approximately a 15 percent increase from the 2006 employment level. While this is encouraging, Column (7) shows no impact of M-Pesa on nonfarm employment. This suggests that the increases in employment due to M-Pesa are driven by changes in farm employment. One possible explanation is that the increased resource flows due to M-Pesa are channeled towards farming, thus boosting the demand for labor and increasing employment. Unfortunately, we do not have the data to investigate these underlying mechanisms further.
We perform some falsification tests to boost the credibility of our empirical methodology. At the time the 2009 survey was collected, the international money transfer feature of M-Pesa was not yet available. Thus, M-Pesa should have no impact on international money transfers. Rows (14) and (15) of Table 13 show that we do not find any significant impact of MPesa on international transfer patterns. This provides some reassurance that our methodology is not flawed.
An additional concern is that our results are driven by unobserved regional trends.
Ideally, with three rounds of data we would include a set of linear sub-location trends to address this concern. However, since we only have two round of data, we attempt to mitigate these concerns by including trends at the provincial level. We find that our results are robust to the inclusion of these provincial level trends (results not shown).

5

5.1

M-Pesa Velocity and the E-Money Loop

Velocity

As a measure of how people are using M-Pesa, and also for the purposes of understanding where
M-Pesa fits into a broader monetary framework, we are interested in calculating the "velocity" of
M-Pesa. In standard monetary economics, "transactions velocity" is defined as the frequency with which the average unit of money is used in transactions. Transactions velocity is different than the more frequently measured income velocity of money, which is simply nominal GDP divided by the relevant money stock.
In the case of M-Pesa, the potentially relevant transactions are deposit of money (creation of a unit of M-Pesa), transfer, and withdrawl of money (extinguishing of a unit of M-Pesa). In this respect, M-Pesa differs from cash, which, in a simple monetary system, would circulate in transactions with only rare instances in which it is created or liquidated (although a piece of cash may enter and leave the banking system many times over the course of its life) . As our measure of M-Pesa velocity, we focus only on transfers, which are the closest analogue to purchases using money in a simple monetary system -- indeed, if e-money is eventually used in a moneylike fashion, such transfers would play the role of transactions using money.
Our measure of M-Pesa velocity is thus the total value of person-to-person transfers (per unit time) divided by the average outstanding balance of e-float. For example, if 100 units of efloat are created at the beginning of month, transferred from person to person five times in the month, and extinguished at the end the month, then monthly velocity will be five. Notice that having 100 units of e-float transferred from person to person five times in the month could happen either because the people receiving transfers then transferred the e-float to someone else or because each time a transfer was received, the recipient withdrew his cash and a new user deposited cash and received e-float. We discuss this issue (the length of the "e-money loop") in the next section.
Of the two numbers required to measure velocity, the harder one to obtain is the outstanding balance of e-float. As discussed above, all money deposited to create e-float is held by a trust fund which holds deposits in commercial banks. Thus, the outstanding balance of efloat is in principle perfectly observable at any point in time, both to Safaricom and to regulators. However, Safaricom treats this quantity as confidential, and does not release any information about it. The only data that we know of on the size of outstanding e-float comes from an audit of M-Pesa conducted by the Ministry of Finance in January 2009. That audit states that "whereas the system transacted about 17 billion kshs in August 2008, the net deposit/residual value per customer (i.e. deposit less withdrawals) was kshs. 203." We assume that the Ministry of Finance figure of 203 kshs is based on observation of the trust account, divided by the number of customers. According to Safaricom figures, there were 3.73 million
M-Pesa accounts in August 2008.8 The implied total value of e-float outstanding was thus 757.2 million ksh. According to Safaricom, the volume of person-to-person transfers that month was
8.32 billion Ksh. The implied velocity of e-float is 11.0. In other words, the average unit of MPesa was transferred 11 times per month between customers. This does not include transfers between customers and M-Pesa agents. Unfortunately, we only have data with which to calculate velocity at one point in time, so we do not know how it has been trending.
8

http://www.safaricom.co.ke/fileadmin/template/main/images/MiscUploads/M-PESA%20Statistics.pdf accessed
June 28, 2010.

There is a significant ambiguity affecting this calculation, however, because it is not clear whether the figure of 203 ksh. per customer figure includes e-float that was stored on the phones of M-Pesa retailers. Conceptually, we have been thinking about the problem faced by users of the system, so we would not want to include such balances. However, from the point of view of
Safaricom's accounting, the outstanding stock of e-float includes not only what sits on the phones of customers, but also what sits on the phones (i.e. in the electronic tills) of the proprietors of MPesa outlets. For example, the deposits held at commercial banks back both the e-money of both customers and dealers. If the figure of 203 ksh. per customer were constructed by dividing the size of the commercial bank deposits by the number of customers, it would include e-float held by M-Pesa outlets. Because the audit is not explicit, we cannot be sure. We can get a feel for the size of this effect by looking at the number of outlets and their average e-float holdings. For
August of 2008, the month from which the figure of 203 ksh. was taken, there were 3,761 outlets nationwide, or roughly one per thousand customers. Eijkman, Kendall, and Mas (2010) report end of day e-float for different types of M-Pesa outlets. These range from 90,000 ksh. for rural stores to 40,000 ksh. for city stores. Rural stores have particularly high end of day float because they do a primarily cash-out business. City stores did a more balanced business, though with an excess of cash-in over cash-out. These end-of-day figures do not correspond to beginning-of-day figures, of course. Furthermore, we do not know at what point in time the measurement of 203 ksh. per phone was taken. However, if we choose a value of 50,000 ksh. per outlet, the total amount held by outlets was 188.1 million ksh. Compared to the value of 757.2 million ksh. calculated above, this is not insignificant. If we assume that the earlier figure was inclusive of dealer holdings, then e-float held on the phones of customers was 569.1 million ksh. In this case, velocity was 14.6.
Is this value of velocity high? If all activity on M-Pesa took the form of someone depositing money and transferring it, and if the recipient then withdrew the full amount, a velocity of 11 would mean that on average such transactions took slightly less than three days between deposit of cash (creation of e-float) and withdrawal of cash (extinction of e-float).
Velocity of 14.6 would mean that such transactions took on average two days. It is likely that most deposit-transfer-withdrawal events are much faster than this. In our observation, many people who deposit money (purchase e-float) at an M-Pesa outlet immediately transfer their efloat to another user. For most recipients, it would not be surprising if they then turned the efloat they received back into cash within a day. Thus, viewing M-Pesa as a money transfer system, a value of velocity of 11 or 14.6 seems unexpectedly low rather than high. On the other hand, if one thought that M-Pesa was being used as a store of value, akin to a bank account or even to money stored under a mattress, then a velocity of 11 or 14.6 would indeed be high.
Presumably -- although we have no firm evidence of this -- the observed figure represents a mix between a large number of users who keep money in the system for very short periods of time and a small number of users who keep money on for extended periods. Below, we return to the question of what this behavior reveals about the optimization problem solved by users.

5.2

The E-Money Loop

Irving Fisher defined the "cash loop" as the number of transactions that a unit of currency goes through between being withdrawn from a bank and returning to a bank. Analogously, we can think of the "e-money loop" as the number of transfer transactions that the average unit of MPesa goes through between being transferred onto a customer phone and being transferred back from a customer phone to the phone of an M-Pesa agent.

The length of the e-money loop is not necessarily related to the velocity of e-money. To see this, think about the following two scenarios:


Scenario #1: Mr. A deposits 100 ksh. into M-Pesa on January 1. He transfers the money to Mr. B on January 15. Mr. B withdraws the money on February 1. Also on February 1,
Mr. C deposits 100 ksh. into M-Pesa, and transfers it to Mr. D. on February 15. Mr. D withdraws the money on March 1. In this case, velocity is 1 transaction per month, and the length of the e-money loop is also 1.



Scenario #2: Mr. A deposits 100 ksh. into M-Pesa on January 1. He transfers the money to Mr. B on January 15. Mr. B leaves the e-float on his phone until February 15, at which point he transfers it to Mr. C. The money is repeatedly transferred on the 15th of every month, and never withdrawn. In this case, velocity is one transfer per month while the length of the e-money loop is infinite.

As with velocity, we can put together available scraps of information to get an estimate of the length of the e-money loop. The Ministry of Finance audit quoted above says that "the system transacted about kshs. 17 billion" in August 2008. What does this number mean? There seems to be little ambiguity about the 8.32 billion figure discussed above being the value of person-toperson transfers, since that is exactly what Safaricom says. It is likely that 17 billion is the volume of cash-in plus cash-out transfers. A different source (Mwangi and Ndung'u, 2009) gives the value of total transactions for August, 2008 at just under 15 billion Ksh., and in this case the phrase "monthly transactions" is explicitly defined as "deposits plus withdrawals." Given that one of the authors of this study is chairman of the central bank of Kenya, it is likely that the figure is based on the same (non-publicly available) data as the Ministry of Finance audit. Given the similarity in magnitude and the similar phrasing, we take the 17 billion to be similarly referring to the value of deposits plus withdrawals in the month.
Given this observation, what is notable is how close the total of deposits and withdrawals is to twice the value of person to person transfers. The relationship between deposits, withdrawals, transfers, and the length of the e-money loop is9

9

The key assumption required to derive this equation is that the system is in a steady state, where monthly deposits are equal to monthly withdrawals. In this case (deposits + withdrawals)/2 is just equal to the quantity of deposits.
Also, in this case, transfers made in a given month would be equal to transfers that would eventually be made with the e-money created in a given month (which in turn would be equal to that month's deposits.) The formula is not fully accurate, sinceM-Pesa was in fact growing over time. Given information on the rate of growth M-Pesa and M-

2 × transfers deposist + withdrawals

(6)

Thus the data indicate that the length of the e-money loop is roughly one. This would be true if all transactions took the form of deposit-transfer-withdraw. The total for deposits and withdrawals would be less than twice transfers, and the length of the loop greater than one, if there were some appreciable fraction of people who received a transfer and then sent the money on somewhere else without doing a withdrawal. Similarly, the total for deposits plus withdrawals would more than twice monthly person-to-person transfers if an appreciable number of people used their phone to store money without transferring it. Of course, it is possible that there was a good deal of both these activities (receiving money and transferring it onward without taking money out, on the one hand, and depositing and withdrawing without transferring, on the other), but the data are suggestive, at least to us, of the overwhelming majority of use being of the deposit-transfer-withdraw type.
Using data from Safaricom (for monthly person-to-person transfers) and from Mwangi and Ndung'u (for monthly deposits to withdrawals) we can calculate the implied length of the emoney loop for the period July, 2007-July, 2009. This is shown in Figure 8. It is interesting to note that in the data the e-money loop starts out at slightly less than one before trending up to almost exactly one. It is possible that the lower figure represents a different use of M-Pesa in the program's early days (more cash storage and fewer multiple transfers), but it is also possible that this is some sort of measurement error -- recall that the figure for total transfers given in the
Ministry of Finance audit was about 7% higher than the figure in Mwangi and Ndung'u (2009).

5.3

Implications for Measuring the Money Supply

As M-Pesa and other forms of electronic money have become more prevalent, economists have turned their attention to the implications for measurement of monetary aggregates and the relationship between money, prices, and real variables. To the extent that e-float is a form of money, failure to measure it in monetary aggregates could lead policy makers astray. For example, if the stock of e-float grew while conventional money did not, monetary policy would be looser than policy makers thought.

Pesa velocity, one could construct a better estimate, but our sense is that it would not differ significantly.

A natural initial approach to this problem would be to simply add the stock of e-money into the measures of, say, M1. This is problematic for two reasons. First, at least in the case of
M-Pesa, the existing stock of e-money is backed 100% by transactions accounts held at commercial banks. If these accounts are subtracted from M1 while M-Pesa balances are added, the net effect is zero. Secondly, however, the transactions velocity of e-money may be higher than the transactions velocity of other components of M1, such as cash. Put differently, a small amount of M-Pesa, by circulating frequently, provides the same transaction (and transfer) services as a much larger quantity of cash.
If one had estimates of the transactions velocities of M-Pesa and the other components of a monetary aggregate, it would then be possible to create a velocity-weighted index, in which those components with higher velocity received a higher weight (see Spindt, 1985, for a discussion). As shown above, getting a rough approximation of the velocity of M-Pesa is not difficult, and with better data one could get a truly precise estimate. Unfortunately, measuring the velocity of other monetary aggregates -- a problem on which monetary economists have been working since the time of Jevons -- is much harder.
For this reason, and also out of curiosity of how M-Pesa compares to other monies, we have pulled together the few estimates of transaction velocity. The estimates span a number of countries and historical eras and, therefore, pertain to a variety of institutional structures and transaction technologies. This may explain some of the vast variation in the data.
A common measure of the velocity of demand deposits is the "demand deposit turnover rate," defined as the ratio of debits to demand deposits in a period to the average value of demand deposits. In the United States, between 1919 and 1941, the annual turnover rate on demand deposits at commercial banks varied between 19.4 and 53.6 (Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System, 1976) . In more recent data, the turnover rate for banks excluding major
New York banks rose from 135 to 475 per month over the period 1980-1995 (U.S. Census
Bureau, Statistical Abstract, 1996). Engber (1965) presents data on demand deposit turnover in
East Africa between 1950-1963, over which period it rose from 4.1 to 9.9 per quarter. Using data from Cletus (2004) the demand deposit turnover rate in Gambia between 1983 and 1993 varied between 2 and 11 transactions per month. In Taiwan in 2007, the annual turnover rate on demand deposits was 328 (Republic of China, 2009). In Thailand, monthly demand deposit turnover in 2009 averaged 41.10
As far as currency goes, there are even fewer estimates of velocity. Irving Fisher's calculations for the years around the beginning of the 20th century in the United States found that transactions velocity of cash was in the neighborhood of 20 per year. Spindt (1985) applies a method suggested by Laurent (1970) to look at the velocity of circulation of currency. His estimate is that the velocity of currency in the United States ranged between 7 and 10 transactions per month over the period 1970-85. A study by the US Federal Reserve based on
10

Bank of Thailand online data query http://www2.bot.or.th/statistics/ReportPage.aspx?reportID=31&language=eng

household surveys (Avery et al., 1986) estimated the velocity of currency in 1984 at between 50 and 55 transactions per year. Feige (1987) estimates the length of the cash loop in the
Netherlands at approximately 4 transactions in data from the 1960s and 1970s.
A preliminary, and not very surprising, conclusion from this exercise is that the transactions velocity of M-Pesa (either 11 or 14.6 transactions per month) is probably higher than other monetary components that are held by households, particularly cash. M-Pesa velocity is not higher than what we see for demand deposits, although the data do not really come from comparable economies, and further we believe that demand deposit turnover is dominated by large corporations. For the present, however, even with a velocity adjustment, M-Pesa does not compare with other parts of the monetary aggregate. The average over the period January-June
2008 of currency (M0) was 85.2 billion shillings, while currency plus demand deposits (M1) was
393 billion shillings (Central Bank of Kenya, Statistical Bulletin, June 2008). By contrast, our calculated value of outstanding e-float in August 2008 was 757.2 million shillings.

6

Why Isn’t M-Pesa Used for Storing Value?

Much of the evidence presented in our paper is strongly suggestive of the conclusion that M-Pesa is only rarely used for storing value for any significant period of time. This can be seen in the low value of average M-Pesa holdings at a point in time (203 ksh, or about three dollars), in the high velocity of M-Pesa, and in the short length of the e-money loop. Although a significant fraction of users report that they use their M-Pesa accounts for storing money, such storage is of relatively small amounts of money or for relatively short periods of time.
Why don't people store more value on M-Pesa? One possible reason is that it does not pay interest. If this is the case, then the implementation of M-Kesho or some other scheme to pay interest on transactions could lead to a significant change in behavior. To gather insight into this question, we could ask: at what interest rate would M-Pesa users store significant value on their accounts?
Part of the answer to this question can be gleaned by looking at behavior with respect to withdrawals. Although M-Pesa balances do not pay explicit interest, holding money in M-Pesa does yield interest in the form of reducing transaction costs. Consider the problem of an individual who receives periodic transfers into his M-Pesa account. One strategy would be to withdraw each transfer as it is received. An alternative would be to group two or more transfers together and withdraw them all at once. The latter strategy holds money on the M-Pesa account for longer, but involves lower costs.
A general analysis of alternative withdrawal strategies would be enormously complex, given the complexity of the price schedule as well as the stochastic nature and varying sizes of transfer receipt. Here, we examine an extremely simple version of the problem to get a feel for the magnitudes involved.

Consider an individual who receives a transfer of 1,000 ksh. on the first of every month.
We will allow for only two strategies: first, she can take out the money each time she receives a transfer. Alternatively, she can wait until she has accumulated 2,000 (that is, every other month) and take the money out then. On the M-Pesa price schedule, the price of withdrawing 1,000 ksh. is the same as the price of withdrawing 2,000 (i.e. 25 ksh.).
Let W be the amount withdrawn, and C be the cost. The monthly interest rate r at which an individual would be indifferent between these two strategies is given implicitly by the equation W −C +

W − C 2W − C
=
1+ r
1+ r

(7)

where the left hand side is the present value of withdrawals net of costs using the first strategy and the right hand side is the same thing using the second strategy. The solution is

r=

C
W −C

(8)

For the example just given (W = 1,000; C = 25), the solution is r=2.6%. On an annual basis this is 36% -- certainly a high interest rate. Using a smaller value of the amount withdrawn, W, would yield a higher implicit interest rate, as would considering an individual who received transfers more frequently than every other month. For example, an individual who received and withdrew 500 ksh. every two weeks -- a scenario that seems like it might be consistent with what we see in the data -- would be demonstrating a discount rate of at least 240% per year!
The information on the distribution of withdrawal sizes can also be brought to bear here.
Although we do not solve the full scale problem, it is clear that for moderate interest rates there should be a significant amount of bunching of withdrawals at the high end of price ranges -- that is, just below the price notch. An individual who withdraws only a little more than the price notch (say, 3,000 ksh. when the price notch is at 2,500 ksh.) and who is going to be receiving another transfer in the next few months, is paying an enormous price to get his/her money early.
And yet the striking observation from our data on the distribution of withdrawal amounts is that there seems to be no bunching at all at the price notch points. There are also, obviously, a very large number of withdrawals of amounts that are far lower than, say, half of the price notch.
Unfortunately, we do not have the data to be completely formal in this analysis. Above, we described the distribution of withdrawal sizes and the frequency of withdrawals, but we do not have these data at the individual level, and so we do not know their joint distribution. We know that most withdrawals are made by individuals who withdraw frequently (every month or more frequently), and that a good fraction of withdrawals are small enough (medians around
1,000 ksh) that two or more of them would fit under the 2,500 ksh. price notch. We also know

that there is not a very large mass of withdrawals at the price notch -- at least no more than would be expected given the fact that price notches are at round numbers. From this data is seems reasonable to conclude that a significant fraction of withdrawals are made by people who are applying high time discount rates, since otherwise they would be grouping their withdrawals into more economical chunks.
We can extend this example further by considering the costs borne by the sender as well.
Although we don't have data on senders, it is a reasonable supposition that in many cases a monthly withdrawal of 1,000 Ksh is matched by a monthly transfer of the same amount. As discussed above, the fee for transfers of any size is 30 Ksh. Thus there would be the possibility that a husband or son working in the city could transfer Ksh. 2,000 once ever two months, instead of Ksh. 1,000 every month. The total cost of such a transfer and withdrawal of either
1,000 or 2,000 Ksh is 55 Ksh (30 Ksh for transfer and 25 Ksh for withdrawal). Plugging this cost figure into the equation above, the implicit interest rate at which a family would be indifferent between transferring 1,000 Ksh every month and transferring 2,000 Ksh every two months is thus 5.8% per month.
A final observation that suggests that users of M-Pesa have high financial discount rates comes from a discussion we had with an employee of Kenya Power and Light Corporation, the country's electricity supplier. Electricity customers receive monthly bills, and must pay them within a fixed time window or their power will be cut off. A bill-pay service was recently established, whereby M-Pesa users could pay their bills through their cell phones, rather than by directly visiting a KPLC office, post office, or bank, all of which involve waiting in a long line.
Despite the superior convenience of M-Pesa, the take-up of the service was relatively low; only about 12 percent of the 1.2 million customers paid by M-Pesa, and we were curious as to why.
The employee's theory was that it had to do with the delay involved in paying with M-Pesa. The
M-Pesa payments were batch processed overnight and thus required between 24 and 48 hours to clear, more time than paying in person where the payments were reflected instantly. Therefore the person paying the bill by M-Pesa would have to have the money one or two days earlier than otherwise. Evidently, this extra one or two days was, to most potential users, more valuable than the huge convenience of not having to pay the bill in person. In fact the KPLC employee stated that M-Pesa use for paying electric bills was actually declining due to this lag in processing.
This is again suggestive of very high time discount rates.
It is important to note that the high financial discount rates that households apply to cash that moves through M-Pesa do not necessarily imply that housholds highly discount the future consumption flows or utility. As in a standard Baumol-Tobin model of cash management, another reason to hold small cash balances is if there is a high cost of holding cash itself. Such a cost could be due to theft in a conventional sense, which can be viewed as a tax on cash balances. However, crime rates would have to be extremely high to justify the behavior we see.
A more likely cost of holding cash is the high implicit tax represented by the ability of other family members to request either gifts or loans from one's available cash balances. This is notion is supported by Ashraf (2009) who reports that women in Kenya often form secret saving societies to hide income from their husbands. Finally, and somewhat similarly, holdings of cash may simply raise temptations to spend that individuals find impossible to resist. The inability to save cash-holdings has been shown to be a constraint to fertilizer adoption in Western Kenya

(Duflo et al. 2010) and promotes participation in ROSCAS which can act as a commitment saving device (Gugerty, 2007). It could be that the extra transaction costs associated with holding small cash balances are a price worth paying to avoid giving in to these temptations.
These observations might be taken to suggest that the types of interest rates potentially offered through cell phone banking will do little to alter the amount of money that people store on their phones. However, recent literature on the financial lives of the poor may suggest otherwise. Collins, et al., (2009), find that the world’s poor utilize a vast range of financial instruments to meet different needs, and prioritize different qualities of these instruments based on how they use them. For instruments used to smooth day-to-day consumption, they find that it is most important to the poor that these keep their money secure and easily accessible, but pay little attention to the interest they might earn. However, when the poor seek to accumulate what
Collins, et al. refer to as “usefully large sums” to pay for life-cycle events (such as weddings or funerals) or other larger expenses, they do take into account the interest that different financial tools can offer them, along with their security, reliability, and structure (for example, requiring them to make periodic deposits to help ensure that they will succeed in building up a larger sum of money). Based on this, we might say that M-Pesa has found a niche in the former realm of day-to-day cash management, but not as much in the accumulation of larger sums. The introduction of a program encouraging saving and offering interest, might allow mobile banking to find an additional niche as a simple and secure financial tool for the accumulation of usefully large sums. One survey found that 38% of respondents said that the feature they would most like to see added to M-Pesa was the ability to earn interest on their accounts, making this the most popular response (Jack, Pulver, and Suri, 2009) This suggests that interest will be an attractive feature of M-Kesho. (As discussed above, M-Kesho will also offer insurance and micro loans, which may also be attractive features.)

7.

Conclusion

In this paper we have examined M-Pesa from a number of different perspectives. Using firmlevel data from competing money transfer services we find that the introduction of M-Pesa has led to significant decreases in the prices of competitors. In addition we examine micro-level data from the Finaccess surveys, where we find that the frequent M-Pesa users are more likely to be urban, educated, banked, and affluent. Our analysis of the 2006 and 2009 rounds of the Finacess surveys reveal that M-Pesa use increases frequency of sending transfers, decreases the use of informal saving mechanisms such as ROSCAS, and increases the probability of being banked.
This suggests that M-Pesa is complementary to banks, whereby the adoption of M-Pesa has increased the demand for banking products.
Although a significant number of survey respondents indicate that they use their M-Pesa accounts as a vehicle for saving, our analysis of aggregate data suggests that the overwhelming use of M-Pesa is for transferring money from individual to individual, with extremely little storage of value. This can be seen in many ways. Our estimates of M-Pesa velocity, the number of transactions per month for the typical unit of e-float, is either 11.0 or 14.6 transactions per month, depending on some auxiliary assumptions. We also estimate the length of the "e-money

loop," that is, the average number of person to person transactions that take place between the creation and destruction of a unit of e-float. Our estimate is quite near one. Although we cannot be certain, we take this as evidence that the vast majority of M-Pesa use is of the form of a cash deposit, followed by a single person-to-person transfer of e-float, followed by a cash withdrawal. Our analysis of data on the size and frequency of M-Pesa withdrawals also suggests that
M-Pesa users have relatively high opportunity costs of holding funds on their phones. For example, there seems to be little evidence of users bunching several transfer receipts together into a single withdrawal in order to economize on fees. This suggests that even if M-Pesa were to pay interest at the same rate as banks, there would not be a significant change in the saving behavior of users.

References

Aghion, Philippe & Howitt, Peter (1992). "A Model of Growth through Creative Destruction",
Econometrica, vol. 60(2), pages 323-51, March
Aker, Jenny C. (2010). “Information from Markets Near and Far: The Impact of Mobile Phones on Agricultural Markets in Niger.” American Economic Journal: Applied Economics
Aker, Jenny and Isaac Mbiti. (2010). "Mobile Phones and Economic Development in Africa"
Journal of Economic Perspectives.
Ashraf, Nava. 2009. "Spousal Control and Intra-Household Decision Making: An Experimental
Study in the Philippines." American Economic Review 99, no. 4, September 2009.
Avery, Robert B, Gregory E. Elliehausen, Arthur B. Kennickell, and Paul A. Spindt. 1986. "The use of cash and transaction accounts by American Families," Federal Reserve Bulletin February, pp. 87-108.
Beck, Thorsten, Asli Demirgüç-Kunt, and Soledad Martinez Peria. 2007. “Reaching Out: Access to and Use of Banking Services across countries,” Journal of Financial Economics,
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (U.S.). "Banking and Monetary Statistics
1941-1970".
Section
5.
Table
55.
September
1976,
accessed at: http://fraser.stlouisfed.org/publications/bms2/issue/60/download/106/section5.pdf
Bower, Joseph L. & Christensen, Clayton M. (1995). "Disruptive Technologies: Catching the
Wave" Harvard Business Review, January–February 1995

Burgess, Robin and Rohini Pande. (2005). "Do Rural Banks Matter? Evidence from the Indian
Social Banking Experiment.” The American Economic Review, 95(3): 780-795
Central
Bank of Kenya.
"Statistical
Bulletin,
June
2008", http://www2.centralbank.go.ke/downloads/statistics/bulletin/Junsb08.pdf accessed

at

Cletus, Agu, 2004 "Efficiency of Commerical Banking in the Gambia," African Review of
Money, Finance, and Banking
Collins, Daryl, Jonathan Morduch, Stuart Rutherford & Orlanda Ruthven, Portfolios of the Poor:
How the World's Poor Live on $2 a Day, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2009.
Duflo, Esther, Michael Kremer, and Jonathan Robinson (2010). "Nudging Farmers to Use
Fertilizer: Theory and Experimental Evidence from Kenya" American Economic Review,
Forthcoming
East African Standard Reporters "Why central bank position on mobile banking attracts wrath,"
2/6/2009, East African Standard http://www.standardmedia.co.ke/InsidePage.php?id=1144015709&cid=457& Eijkman, Frederik, Jake Kendall, and Ignacio Mas, "Bridges to Cash: the retail end of M-PESA"
2010.
Engberg, Holger L. 1965. "Commercial Banking in East Africa, 1950-1963," Journal of Modern
African Studies, Vol. 3, No. 2, pp. 175-200.
Feige, Edgard L. 1987. "The theory and measurement of cash payments: a case study of the
Netherlands" in R.D.H. Heijmans and N. Neudecker (eds.), The Practice of Econometrics:
Studies on Demand, Forcasting, Money and Income International Studies in Economics and
Econometrics, Vol. 15, Dordrecht, the Netherlands: Kluwer Academic Publishers.
FinMark Trust. (2008) Finscope In Africa, 2008. http://www.finscope.co.za/documents/2008/FSAfricaBrochure08.pdf Gikunju, Washington (2009) "Mobile money transfers edge out rival operators" Business Daily,
September 14 2009. accessed at http://www.businessdailyafrica.com/-/539552/657466//view/printVersion/-/2gufmtz/-/index.html
Gugerty, Mary Kay (2007) You Can’t Save Alone: Commitment and Rotating Savings and
Credit Associations in Kenya,” Economic Development and Cultural Change, vol. 55, pages
251-282
Jack, William, Caroline Pulver, and Tavneet Suri, "The Performance and Impact of M-Pesa:
Preliminary Evidence from a Household Survey" Power Point presentation, 2009:

http://technology.cgap.org/technologyblog/wpcontent/uploads/2009/10/fsd_june2009_caroline_pulver.pdf
Jack, William and Tavneet Suri (2010) "The Risk Sharing Benefits of Mobile Money” MIT
Working paper
Jack, William and Tavneet Suri (2011) "Mobile Money: The Economics of M-Pesa" NBER
Working Paper 16721
Jensen, Robert T. (2007). “The Digital Provide: Information (Technology), Market Performance and Welfare in the South Indian Fisheries Sector,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 122(3), p.
879 − 924
Kabbucho, Kamau, Cerstin Sander and Peter Mukwana "PASSING THE BUCK- Money
Transfer Systems: The Practice and Potential for Products in Kenya" MicroSave Africa Report.
Accessed
at http://microfinancegateway.org/content/article/detail/19594?PHPSESSID=332fab3a7849fc6358 83a38e113c62da
Kimenyi, Mwangi S., and Njuguna S. Ndung'u, "Expanding the Financial Services Frontier:
Lessons From Mobile Phone Banking in Kenya," Brookings Institution, October 16, 2009. http://www.brookings.edu/articles/2009/1016_mobile_phone_kimenyi.aspx Laurent, Robert D. 1970 "Currency Transfers by Denomination." Ph.D. dissertation, University of. Chicago.
Mas, Ignacio and Olga Morawczynski. 2009 “Designing Mobile Transfer Services: Lessons from
M-Pesa” Innovations. (Forthcoming)
Mas, Ignacio, and Amolo Ng'weno, "Three keys to M-Pesa's success: Branding, channel management and pricing," mimeo, Bill and Melinda Gates Foundation, December 2009.
Ministry of Finance of Kenya, "Ministry of Finance Audit Findings on M-Pesa Money Transfer
Services" 26 January, 2009, accessed at http://kenyapolitical.blogspot.com/2009/01/ministry-offinance-audit-findings-on-m.html
Morawczynski, Olga. 2009. “Exploring the usage and impact of “transformational” mobile financial services: the case of M-PESA in Kenya.” Journal of Eastern African Studies.
3(3):509-525.
Morawczynski, Olga and Mark Pickens. 2009. “Poor People Using Mobile Financial Services:
Observations on Customer Usage and Impact from M-PESA” CGAP Brief Online http://www.cgap.org/gm/document1.9.36723/BR_Poor_People_Using_Mobile_Financial_Services.pdf Mwaura, Stephen, "Kenya's Payments System" powerpoint presentation from Mobile Banking
Conference 2009: Balancing Innovation and Regulation, 25-26 May, 2009, Kenya School of
Monetary Studies, Nairobi, Kenya, http://www.ksms.or.ke/index.php/conferences-andseminars/doc_download/49-kenya-payments-system
Njiraini, John and James Anyanzwa (2008). "Unmasking the Storm Behing M-Pesa" East
African Standard, December 2008
Pickens, Mark, David Porteous, and Sarah Rotman. 2009. “Scenarios for Branchless Banking in
2020.” Focus Note 57. Washington, D.C.: CGAP.
Plyler, Megan, Sherri Hass and Geetha Nagarajan. 2010 "Community-Level Economic Effects of
M-PESA in Kenya: Initial Findings" IRIS Center Report, University of Maryland. http://www.fsassessment.umd.edu/publications/pdfs/Community-Effects-MPESA-Kenya.pdf Republic of China,
"Monthly
Bulletin of Statistics"
August
http://eng.dgbas.gov.tw/public/data/dgbas03/bs7/bulletin_eng/PDF/eng-month9808.pdf

2009,

Safaricom, 2007. M-Pesa Update. Press Release. December 7, 2007
Safaricom. 2009. Industry Update. March 12, 2009. http://www.safaricom.co.ke/fileadmin/template/main/downloads/investor_relations_pdf/Industry %20Update%20120309.pdf
Schumpeter, Joseph A (1942). Capitalism, Socialism, and Democracy. New York. Harper and
Brothers
Slemrod, Joel, "Buenos Notches: Lines and Notches in Tax System Design," mimeo, University of Michigan, 2010.
Spindt, Paul A. 1985. “Money Is What Money Does: Monetary Aggregation and the Equation of
Exchange,” The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 93, No. 1, pp. 175-204.
U.S. Census Bureau , "Statistical Abstract, 1996, Section 16, Banking, Finance, and Insurance", accessed at http://www.census.gov/prod/2/gen/96statab/finance.pdf
Vaughan, Pauline. 2007. “Early lessons from the deployment of M-PESA, Vodaphones’s own mobile transactions service” In The Transformational Potential of M-transactions, Vodaphone
Policy Paper Series, No.6. Online http://www.vodaphone.com/m-transactions

Data Appendix:

A.1 FinAccess surveys:
The FinAcess surveys, conducted in 2006 and 2009, are nationally representative household surveys that were designed to measure financial access in Kenya. The surveys were collected by
Financial Sector Deepening Trust Kenya (FSD Kenya), with financial and technical support from a variety of partners including the Central Bank of Kenya, donors and a number of commercial banks in Kenya.The 2006 round consisted of approximately 4,400 individuals, while the 2009 round consisted of close to 6,600 individuals. A unique feature of this data is that it aimed to capture access to a wide range of both formal and informal financial tools. Moreover, the consistency of the surveys enable reliable comparisons across time of the changing nature of financial access. Using sampling weights we can aggregate the data to the sublocation level.
Sublocations are the lowest administrative unit in Kenya and consist of 2 to 3 villages in rural areas or a large neighborhood in a city. We combine the 2006 and 2009 FinAcess surveys and create a balanced panel of the 190 sub-locations that were surveyed in both rounds.
We constructed the measure of transfer frequency as follows. We converted the categorical responses into annual numerical values as follows. Daily = 365 times a year, Weekly
- 52 times a year, Monthly = 12 times a year, Irregularly/once in a while= 1 times a year. We then used these conversion factors to change categorical responses on transfer sent and received frequencies as well as M-Pesa use frequencies into annualized numerical values.
Our wealth measure is constructed by using principal component analysis on the household assets and durable goods such as televisions and refrigerators. We then create wealth quantile dummies based on the principal component analysis.
A.2 Transfer Prices:
Kabbucho et al. (2003) document the prices of various money transfer methods. We use their data from 2003 as the baseline and compare it to current (2010) prices of Moneygram and
Western Union. The Moneygram fee schedule is documented online, while the Western Union rates were collected in person by research staff. These fees are converted into a database that contains prices for a series of transfer amounts in 100 Kshs intervals. This allows us to compare the prices across comparable set of prices.
A.3 M-Pesa Transaction data:
We collect M-Pesa transaction data from an agent in Kisumu. These data contained transaction type and transaction amount over a three month period in 2010 for three M-Pesa shops. The first show Katito is in a rural area, while; Homa Bay is in a small town while Cyber is in an urban environment. Further details of these stores can be obtained from Eijkman et al (2010).

Table 1: M-Pesa Fee Schedule

source: Safaricom 2010.

Table 2: Summary Statistics of Transactions at M-Pesa Agents
Withdrawals

N
Mean
Std. dev.
Skewness
10th
25th
Median
75th
90th

Cyber Center
3,477
2,757
4,799
4.03
300
500
1,000
2,850
6,370

Katito
6,401
1,402
1,854
5.27
250
475
900
1,680
3,000

Deposits
Homa Bay
2,787
5,762
8,671
2.17
390
700
1,970
6,500
18,500

Cyber Center
3,544
3,773
5,949
3.07
300
578
1,500
4,000
10,001

Katito
2,524
3,425
6,598
3.21
200
390
1,000
3,000
10,000

Homa Bay
3,716
5,240
6,790
2.29
500
1,000
2,500
6,475
14,000

Table 3: Distribution of Final Two Digits of Deposit Amounts
Final Digits

Percentage

00
05
10
15
20
25
30
35
40
45
50
55
60
65
70
75
80
85
90
95
other

58.6
0.3
0.4
0.1
1.1
9.5
4.0
0.1
0.3
0.1
11.7
6.8
2.6
0.1
2.2
1.2
0.4
0.1
0.1
0.0
0.2

Note: M-Pesa Deposit data from an Agent in Kisumu. Deposits smaller than Ksh. 2,600. N=6,036

Table 4: Average Prices of Transfers as a Pct of Transfer Amount

Pre -Mpesa

Transfer Amount
Less than or equal to 35000
Greater than 35,000
0.1401
0.0468
(0.0047)
(0.0001)

Difference
-0.0934***

Post-Mpesa

0.0431
(0.0023)

0.0112
(0.0002)

-0.0319***

Difference

-0.097***

-0.0356***

-0.0703***

Notes: Standard Errors in Parentheses. P values of the T-Test for the difference of means
*** p

Similar Documents

Free Essay

“Evaluating Customer Perceived Value in Mobile Banking Apps Using Technology Acceptance Model (Tam)”

...“Evaluating Customer Perceived Value in Mobile Banking Apps using Technology Acceptance Model (TAM)” Date: 15th May’15 Introduction Mobile banking is a result of the development of mobile technology used in the commercial domain. Mobile banking combines information technology and business applications together. Thanks to the mobile banking, customers can use it to get banking services 24 hours a day without having to visit a bank branch for personal transactions. Suoranta, M. (2003) conclude that Mobile banking is a relatively new service offered by banks to customers, and because of the convenience and features that save time and customers appreciate the services. Compared to other e-banking services, the development of mobile banking (m-banking) regarded the fastest. This development is due to the presence of m-banking services to answer the needs of a modern society that is promoting mobility. With one touch, creates convenience m-banking banking services in one hand. Benefit of mobile banking services will increase customer satisfaction. Furthermore, mobile banking creates "value" for the bank as a customer transaction service delivery channel access (wireless). Birch D and Young, M. A, (1997) conclude that the rapid advanced of technology in banking technologies, Customers want the convenience and flexibility on products and services that suit their needs and easy to use which cannot be offered by traditional banks. In the future of e-banking will be an important strategic...

Words: 2961 - Pages: 12

Free Essay

Intention to Use M-Banking

...Faculty of Business and Information Science Faculty of Business and Information Science A coursework completed as part of the requirement for SUBJECT NAME: BUSINESS RESEARCH METHODS SUBJECT CODE: BB204 LECTURER/TUTOR: Ms. YEOH SOK FOON Entitled ASSIGNMENT TITLE : INTENTION TO USE MOBILE BANKING AMONG UCSI STUDENTS Submitted on DATE OF SUBMISSION : 21st July 2015 DUE DATE : 21st July 2015 Words count: 2618 Produced by STUDENT NAME & ID: Name | Student ID | Programme | Signature | Mohammad Syafiq Mohammad Suferi | 1001336037 | BA (Hons) Business Administration | | Fadhilah Amalina Firman | 1001334557 | BA (Hons) Business Administration | | Md Monzurul Masuk | 1001335506 | BA (Hons) Business Administration | | Chin Khee Zhao | 1001232877 | BA (Hons) Accounting | | Muhammad Usman | 1001333957 | BA (Hons) Business Administration | | TABLE OF CONTENTS CHAPTER 1 INTRODUCTION 1.1 Introduction……………………………………………………………………..4-5 1.2 Problem Statement…………………………..…………………………………5-6 1.3 Significance of Study………………………..………………………………….6 1.4 Research Questions…………………………..…………………………………7 1.5 Research Objectives…………………………..…...……………………………7 1.6 Hypotheses………………………………….………………………………......7 1.7 Definition of Selected Variables………………………………………………..8 CHAPTER 2 LITERATURE...

Words: 4029 - Pages: 17

Premium Essay

Case Analysis of Bank of America: Mobile Banking

...Case Analysis of Bank of America: Mobile Banking Marcus J. Durr Professor Trittipo AMBA 650 Section 9047 January 31, 2012 Abstract During the tough time for the banking industry when many banks have gone into bankruptcy or have began add numerous fees to their service in order to stay afloat; Bank of American (BoA) has also experienced some of the effects of the financial crisis. In an effort to weather the storm BoA began to incorporate mobile banking. While its competitors were implementing their own mobile banking through mobile apps, mobile web, and short message system (SMS), BoA focused on the mobile app and mobile web only. This case analysis takes a look at some of the major strategic issues and problems, such as BoA leaving out a portion of their target market by opting out of using SMS, which left a portion of their market base outside in the cold. However there are some positives, that BoA realized and took swift action to capitalize on the fast emerging market of mobile banking. In the conclusion, recommendations are given on what BoA can do to keep a stable position in the future, as mobile banking will have a huge impact on the banking industry. Case Analysis of Bank of America: Mobile Banking In the banking industry Bank of America has grown to become a household name and evidence of their marketing efforts through all channels can be seen just about everywhere you go. Over the past few years the banking industry has surly gone through some turbulent...

Words: 1301 - Pages: 6

Premium Essay

Mobile Banking Literature Review

...INTERNATIONAL REVIEW Mathew et al. (2005) analyzed the use of banking technology in United Kingdom by ranking of importance of selected technology on consumer perception of service delivery performance and found that the importance-performance grid demonstrates two factors and their underlying attributes that fall into the “Keep up the good work” quadrant and the other two factors fall into the “Low priority” quadrant. The first two were the areas the organization needs to allocate resources in order to maintain the level of service they provided...

Words: 6235 - Pages: 25

Premium Essay

Amazon.Com: an E-Commerce Retailer

...middle businesses, corporations and Governments with their banking, investing, asset management and other financial products and services 1. The company is headquartered in Charlotte, North Carolina. The company has huge presence in America spanning across 40 states. It serves approximately 54 million consumers in US and its foot print covers 80 % of the population. The bank is being led by Brian Moynihan who succeeded Ken Lewis as the President and CEO effective January 1, 2010. Some of the key highlights of Bank of America are: As of 2010, it is the second largest bank holding company behind JP Morgan Chase in United States by assets which stood over US$ 2 trillion As of 2010, the company is the fifth largest company in United States by revenue which is over 111.4 billion2 The company was also the 3rd largest non-oil company in the US after Wal-Mart and General Electric In 2010, Forbes listed Bank of America as the third largest company in the world 3 The bank has over 5500 branches along with approximately 16300 ATMs and an online banking with 30 million active users 4 The major competitors of Bank of America are JP Morgan Chase, Citi Group and Wells Fargo Bank. 1 http://www.forbes.com/companies/bank-of-america/ 2010 Bank of America Annual Report 3 http://www.forbes.com/companies/bank-of-america/ 4 http://investor.bankofamerica.com/phoenix.zhtml?c=71595&p=irol -homeprofile#fbid=W6HlSIbzfcd 2 4 Bank of America: Mobile Banking Case Report Financial Snapshot 5 Company History The company...

Words: 4633 - Pages: 19

Premium Essay

Bank of America

...payment of credit card bills. It should also allow users to take benefit of mobile banking service regardless of being online user. Instead of concentrating on binding people to use both mobile and online banking they should concentrate more on customer satisfaction. Mobile banking is a very convenient channel to interact with clients as compared to other channels, as it is fast and can be accessed at any time from any place around the globe. BOA might have an adverse effect on its market share as compared to its peers/ competitors who are dominating the mobile banking market by providing more features/ functionality to the mobile applications. BOA can reduce operational and transaction costs in long run by providing more functionality in its mobile application and promoting its unique features. Moreover the cost of development of the application is very expensive. Second, it should classify its market segments based on Exhibit 3b (Global Consumer and Small Business Banking, Global Corporate and Investment Banking, Global Wealth and Investment Management) then designs a specialized application based on the needs of the target market. The advantage is that it would step ahead of its competitors in providing customized solution for each market listed above. In turn, it will increase customer satisfaction and that would lead to expand its current market in each segment. This will result in increasing mobile banking by integrating BOA’s business line spreading its platform to increase...

Words: 1584 - Pages: 7

Free Essay

Discussion of the Change of Customers’ Attitudes Towards and Expectations and the Ways Organisations Respond

...and the importance of organisations recognizing the influences of the external environment and how the developments in these influences can have a substantial impact on organisational success. The second part gives the theoretical framework of business external environment and contextual environment, and especially concentrates on the influence of the social environment on customer attitudes and expectations. In addition, it reveals customers and financial services sector are not isolate parts to each other, whereas they are in a two-way interaction process. The third part provides an example in particular to illustrate the ways in which organisations have recognised changes and how to respond in terms of products and services in order to achieve customer satisfaction and maintain their competitive position. With the development of economic globalization, the number and cooperation of countries’ financial organizations are getting larger and closer, so the competition is increasingly fierce. Competition here includes not only the firms that produce same product but also those firms which compete for the income of the consumers the competition here among these products may be said as desire competition as the primary task here is to fulfill the desire of the customers. Competitiveness increasingly has a significant impact on the overall financial structure of the financial sector, and it is vital for financial institutions to...

Words: 1618 - Pages: 7

Premium Essay

The Bank of America Case

...become very important during the global recession of 2007 and thereafter with its decision to embark on mobile banking. Strategic issues and problems The introduction of mobile banking by Bank of America was necessitated by the global recession which dwindled its retail section as customers increased the use of their money at the bank, with and the banks losses in other areas of the bank’s operations due to miscalculated acquisitions and bad lending practices (Gupta & Herman, 2010, p. 3). Mobile banking was one of management’s strategic approaches to rejuvenate the bank’s financial fortunes, maintain or increase its customer base and remain profitable. Management must make a decision on how to package the mobile banking program to the market considering cost and coverage to differentiate itself among competitors, and benefit from the various profit opportunities offered by mobile banking. The strategic issues facing BofA are the consideration of the extent mobile banking coverage, type of mobile system to use, timeline for the implementation and the combination of the mobile banking with the other channel mix and programs of the banks to create a balance effort. The major problems are the cost associated with program delivery, competition and uncertainties related to customer's reactions. Also, there is the need for considerations of internal branch demands for mobile...

Words: 1679 - Pages: 7

Premium Essay

Internet Banking

...Impact of E-Banking on Capital Bank and local area banking industry in India Coursework- Technology in Business and Society Shahbaz Singh Samra - B022337   Executive Summary The task commissioned was to assess the application of a technology to support organizational change. This report concentrates on how electronic banking (e-banking) has contributed to Capital Local Area Bank (CLAB) and the local area banking industry in India. Focus lies upon CLAB’s operations and how the bank incorporated e-banking to revolutionize and set standards for transparent and efficient banking in the state of Punjab. E-Banking gives strategic value to the organization and the industry because it adds a new dimension to the bank to offer its products and services. It gives the organization a comparative advantage over its rivals. However, local area banks might have to suffer loss of business done through their physical branches especially in urban and more developed areas. This, however, would be a positive for CLAB as the overall business generated would be higher and it gives its customers a facility that is yet to be provided by its competitors. E-Banking t is very cost effective for the bank. A bank, in order to expand efficiently, would be better off investing in e-banking rather than expanding its customer outreach through increasing the number of physical branches. Inevitably, e-banking does have some issues and challenges than an organization would have to overcome to...

Words: 3369 - Pages: 14

Premium Essay

Case Analysis of Bank of America: Mobile Banking

...Case Analysis of Bank of America: Mobile Banking Marcus J. Durr Professor Trittipo AMBA 650 Section 9047 January 31, 2012 Abstract During the tough time for the banking industry when many banks have gone into bankruptcy or have began add numerous fees to their service in order to stay afloat; Bank of American (BoA) has also experienced some of the effects of the financial crisis. In an effort to weather the storm BoA began to incorporate mobile banking. While its competitors were implementing their own mobile banking through mobile apps, mobile web, and short message system (SMS), BoA focused on the mobile app and mobile web only. This case analysis takes a look at some of the major strategic issues and problems, such as BoA leaving out a portion of their target market by opting out of using SMS, which left a portion of their market base outside in the cold. However there are some positives, that BoA realized and took swift action to capitalize on the fast emerging market of mobile banking. In the conclusion, recommendations are given on what BoA can do to keep a stable position in the future, as mobile banking will have a huge impact on the banking industry. Case Analysis of Bank of America: Mobile Banking In the banking industry Bank of America has grown to become a household name and evidence of their marketing efforts through all channels can be seen just about everywhere you go. Over the past few years the banking industry has surly gone through some...

Words: 344 - Pages: 2

Premium Essay

Bank of America

...of America: Mobile Banking Introduction Bank of America is one of the largest U.S. bank holding companies; it was founded in 1904 and expanded with several acquisitions. Mobile banking was launched in 2007 and within three years Bank of America had 4 million active customers using this service. Mobile banking may be the single biggest innovation the global banking industry has seen. From smart phones to tablets and laptops, banking customers are pushing their institutions to develop more mobile services. This success prompted line-of-business managers to request more functionality in the bank's mobile application that was specific to their businesses such as credit cards and mortgages and to determine how this change would affect their clients. Bank of America offers applications for over 800 devices, which include smart phones and BlackBerry devices. Bank of America was struggling to position their mobile banking service in the continuously changing industry. “The banking industry was fragmented, with thousands of banks offering retail and wholesale banking services.” (Gupta & Herman, 2010, p.2) Recognizing the potential impact mobile technology could have on the entire banking industry, Bank of America must decide on how to position itself within the mobile banking industry. This paper will identify the strategic issues, the benefits of mobile banking to customers and attempt to explain why some consumers have not adopted mobile banking. I will then...

Words: 272 - Pages: 2

Premium Essay

Case Analysis: Bank of America: Mobile Banking

...of America: Mobile Banking Introduction Bank of America is one of the largest U.S. bank holding companies; it was founded in 1904 and expanded with several acquisitions. Mobile banking was launched in 2007 and within three years Bank of America had 4 million active customers using this service. Mobile banking may be the single biggest innovation the global banking industry has seen. From smart phones to tablets and laptops, banking customers are pushing their institutions to develop more mobile services. This success prompted line-of-business managers to request more functionality in the bank's mobile application that was specific to their businesses such as credit cards and mortgages and to determine how this change would affect their clients. Bank of America offers applications for over 800 devices, which include smart phones and BlackBerry devices. Bank of America was struggling to position their mobile banking service in the continuously changing industry. “The banking industry was fragmented, with thousands of banks offering retail and wholesale banking services.” (Gupta & Herman, 2010, p.2) Recognizing the potential impact mobile technology could have on the entire banking industry, Bank of America must decide on how to position itself within the mobile banking industry. This paper will identify the strategic issues, the benefits of mobile banking to customers and attempt to explain why some consumers have not adopted mobile banking. I will then...

Words: 321 - Pages: 2

Premium Essay

Bank of American

...senior vice president, Mobile Product Development, were discussing the bank’s mobile strategy. BoA launched mobile banking in 2007, and within three years, it had 4 million active customers. This success prompted line-of-business (LOB) managers to ask McDonald and Brown to include more functions in the bank’s mobile app that were specific to their businesses, such as credit cards and mortgages. McDonald and Brown had to decide how to leverage the mobile platform for various businesses of the bank without creating confusion or increasing complexity for the consumers. Recognizing the potential impact mobile technology could have on the entire banking industry, they also had to decide how to position BoA’s mobile banking in the long run. Refer to the complete case, which is enclosed, to answer the following questions Questions: (Answer ALL questions) 1. What benefits does mobile banking provide to consumers? Why haven’t many consumers adopted mobile banking yet? 2. What is BoA’s motivation to offer mobile banking to its customers? What are the associated costs and risks to the bank? 3. What lessons can the bank learn from its online banking operations? What are the costs and benefits of having customers migrate to online banking? 4. How is mobile technology likely to influence the banking industry in the future? 5. How should McDonald and Brown respond to the LOB managers’ request to include more functions in the bank’s mobile...

Words: 252 - Pages: 2

Premium Essay

Mobile

...The penetration of Mobiles can be used to leverage to extend banking to the unbanked. - Its challenges and solutions. Today a portable telephone device called as “Mobile” has taken away physical mobility in our lives and we cannot think our life without it. In fact the world has become stationary by holding this instrument as it provides all sorts of facilities to the human being on its figure tips. Mobile phone is a common technology device that has became part of every individual in the information era. As the device is being used to cater various services in our life, we can also think of using it for our day to day banking services. As a result, today mobile plays as an important role in banking sector and Mobile banking has become an emerging alternative channel for providing banking services. However, mobile banking still has not become the choice of millions of people. The main objective of this study is to understand the technology behind it and the rules and regulations, security aspect, problem areas, and also identify the solutions and strategies to popularize the mobile banking among every banking customer in India. Introduction of Mobile Banking Technology Mobile Banking refers to provision and benefit of banking and financial services with help of mobile telecommunication instrument. The services may include facilities to carry out bank and other financial transactions, to manage accounts and retrieve personalised information. The last time that technology...

Words: 896 - Pages: 4

Premium Essay

Mobile Money Services in Kenya

...THE IMPACT OF MOBILE MONEY SERVICES ON THE PERFORMANCE OF SMALL AND MEDIUM ENTERPRISES IN AN URBAN TOWN IN KENYA BY KENNETH M. NYAGA A DISSERTATION SUBMITTED IN PARTIAL FULFILLMENT OF THE REQUIREMENTS FOR THE AWARD OF MASTER OF BUSINESS ADMINISTRATION (CORPORATE MANAGEMENT) IN THE SCHOOL OF BUSINESS AND PUBLIC MANAGEMENT AT KCA UNIVERSITY NOVEMBER, 2013 DECLARATION I declare that this dissertation is my original work and has not been previously published or submitted anywhere for award of a degree. I also declare that this contains no material written or published by other people except where due reference is made and author duly acknowledged. Student Name: ______________________ Sign: __________________________ Registration Number: ________________ Date: ___________________ I do hereby confirm that I have examined the master’s dissertation of: Kenneth Miriti Nyaga And have certified that all revisions that the dissertation panel and examiners recommended have been adequately addressed. Signed _______________________________ Date ___________________ Dr. Okonga-Wabuyabo, Brigitte M. Dissertation Supervisor ii ABSTRACT Since the launch of mobile money services in Kenya in 2007, the number of subscriptions has grown to approximately 48% of entire the Kenyan population. This overwhelming uptake has been attributed to the affordability and accessibility of the service, especially among low income earners. The main challenges of mobile money...

Words: 20382 - Pages: 82