Free Essay

Rebate Coupons

In:

Submitted By royarpit001
Words 10009
Pages 41
Who should practice price discrimination in an asymmetric duopoly?
Kutsal Dogan Ernan Haruvy University of Texas at Dallas June 2008 Ram C. Rao

Abstract Price discrimination is generally thought to improve firm profits by allowing firms to extract more consumer surplus. In competition, however, price discrimination may also be costly to the firm because restrictive incentive compatibility conditions may allow the competing firm to gain market share at the discriminating firm’s expense. Therefore, with asymmetric competition, it may be the case that one firm would let the other firm assume the burden of price discrimination. We investigate optimal segmentation in a market with two asymmetric firms and two heterogeneous consumer segments that differ in the importance of price and product attributes. In particular, we investigate second-degree price discrimination under competition with explicit incentive compatibility constraints thus extending prior work in marketing and economics. Focusing on the managerial implications, we explore whether it would be profitable for either or both firms to pursue a segmentation strategy using rebates as a mechanism. We identify conditions under which one or both firms would want to pursue such segmentation. We find that segmentation lessens competition for the less price-sensitive consumer segment and that this results in higher profits to both firms. A key to understanding this result is the customer remixing that segmentation leads to. We establish the key result that if firms are asymmetric in their attractiveness to consumers, the disadvantaged firm in our model is more likely to pursue a segmentation strategy than its rival in equilibrium. We then ask whether this result obtains in practice. To this end, we explore competitive segmentation empirically and are able to verify that disadvantaged firms indeed pursue segmentation through rebates with greater likelihood. Key Words: Segmentation; Competition; Game Theory; Pricing, Rebates; Printers

1. Introduction In this paper we investigate the role of segmentation under competition. In particular we are interested in studying competition among asymmetric firms and exploring the consequences of segmentation for customer remixing-- changing the clientele mix that each firm serves-- for firms’ profits and for equilibrium prices. To this end, we explore a market with two firms that compete for two types of consumers. The two types are heterogeneous in how they make a trade-off between their desired combination of attributes and price. We capture the competition between the firms in a Hotelling framework. We then ask if it would be profitable for both firms to segment the market. Specifically, we assume that segmentation can be implemented by the mechanism of rebates, although our model would apply equally to the case of coupons. We solve for equilibrium pricing and rebate strategies and then derive the profits with segmentation by one firm, both firms, or neither firm. In other words, either, both or neither firm can implement a segmentation mechanism based on rebates. We obtain an interesting insight into how segmentation affects competition. It softens competition for one segment of consumers that values attributes more than price, while simultaneously increasing the competition for the other segment. In sum, this allows firms to charge higher prices for the segment of consumers that values attributes more than price, as we might expect given the attendant price discrimination. What is more interesting is that the net effect of segmentation is higher profits for both firms, despite their asymmetry. In their pioneering work, Shaffer and Zhang (1995) demonstrated that targeting in competition can be a dominant strategy (if costs of targeting are low) but Pareto inferior in equilibrium—i.e., prisoner’s dilemma. They discuss second degree price discrimination by symmetric firms in a two-stage setting and find that it is always profitable, for example through mass distribution of coupons. Nevertheless, their work mainly focuses on targeting and the difference between targeted and mass distributed coupons. We extend their work on second degree price discrimination by focusing on mass distribution of rebates by asymmetric firms in a simultaneous-move game with explicitly modeled incentive compatibility constraints. These three modeling differences allow us to identify when untargeted second degree price discrimination may or may not be profitable in an asymmetric duopoly. We find that under some

2

conditions, unrelated to costs but rather related to incentive compatibility constraints; second degree price discrimination may not be profitable for one or both firms. Finally, we also establish which of the two firms in an asymmetric duopoly has greater incentive to engage in second degree price discrimination through untargeted rebates. Segmentation, whether pursued by one or both firms, leads to customer remixing, resulting in each firm’s clientele being different from what would have occurred without segmentation. Indeed, this remixing is central to firms’ ability to garner higher profits, thus providing new insights into the strategic consequences of segmentation under competition. Given our focus on competition between asymmetric firms, we also find that the firm whose attractiveness is lower is more likely to pursue a segmentation strategy, through the use of rebates, than its rival. We then investigate competitive rebate offerings empirically. There are few studies that have explored this in the context of product markets, an exception being Nevo and Wolfram (2002) who studied competitive segmentation based on coupons in the cereal market. Their main focus was to verify that coupons were indeed acting as price discrimination mechanisms. Similarly, other empirical works investigated the existence of second degree price discrimination in various markets with a specific emphasis on the effects of competition. These include Shepard (1991) (gasoline sales), Seim and Viard (2006) (cellular phone services), and Borzekowski, Thomadsen and Taragin (2006) (mailing lists). Lal and Rao (1997) studied competitive segmentation but in grocery retailing with the focus being on positioning and pricing. We are interested in examining the role of rebates in competitive segmentation with particular emphasis on which among asymmetric firms would find such a strategy more profitable. Several interesting questions come up in light of firm asymmetry. Do stronger brands employ segmentation mechanisms more often? What is the relationship between brand price and extent of segmentation? Even within a product category, are high-end or low-end sub-categories more likely to engage in segmentation? Our analytical model provides some guidance in examining these issues. For the empirical analysis, we use data from the printer market to see if the firm whose attractiveness is lower is more likely to pursue a segmentation strategy.

3

The rest of the paper is organized as follows. In section 2 we provide an extensive review of the literature that positions our work in context relative to the large body of prior work. We then describe our consumer model and how firms compete both on segmentation strategy and pricing strategy in section 3. In section 4 we analyze our model and derive the equilibrium segmentation and pricing strategies. We present our central result contained in propositions 2-4. In section 5 we analyze the printer market and present our empirical results. We end with concluding comments in section 6.

2. Review of Literature Market segmentation has been studied extensively, with particular emphasis on making differentiated offerings to markets with heterogeneous consumers. For example, if consumers are heterogeneous in how they value quality, a firm would want to offer a product line with vertically differentiated products rather than a single product to cater to the different types of customers. This would allow the firm to charge differential prices and earn higher profits (see, for example, Moorthy, 1984). In general, segmentation involves price discrimination entailing different offers to different groups of consumers. For example, segmentation based on price sensitivity can be accomplished often by the use of coupons if price sensitive consumers also happen to have a low cost of time (Narasimhan, 1984). Thus, coupons serve as a mechanism to engage in price discrimination and segment the market based on price sensitivity. The usefulness of coupons in this context has been explored by numerous researchers: Gerstner and Hess (1991), Shaffer and Zhang (1995), Moraga-Gonzalez and Petrakis (1999), and Krishna and Zhang (1999). Of course, what makes price discrimination and the resulting segmentation profitable is consumer heterogeneity. Turning to competition, the challenge of lessening it can be met in different ways. For example, Kim, Shi and Srinivasan (2001), following the arguments of Klemperer (1987), show that frequency based loyalty programs, effectively segmenting the market into heavy and light users, can soften price competition by introducing endogenous switching costs. In product markets in which some consumers are brand loyal and others willing to switch, competitive pricing often leads to price promotions (Narasimhan,

4

1988; Raju, Srinivasan and Lal, 1990; Rao, 1991). These temporary promotions, arising from mixed strategies, do not involve a constant low price targeted at switchers because that would leave money on the table for loyal consumers whose brand choice is unaffected by price promotions. In this way price promotions can be seen as a way to lessen price competition for a segment of consumers. Segmentation under competition has also been addressed by Coughlan and Soberman (2005) and Lal and Rao (1997) in the context of retailing. In the absence of segmentation, consumer types that are willing to pay more for a product end up paying less, in essence receiving a subsidy. Segmentation can have the beneficial consequence of lessening or eliminating this subsidy. This has been shown to be the case by Kumar and Rao (2006) who find that complete retail segmentation by offering rewards eliminates subsidy to one segment of consumers when segments are heterogeneous in their shopping baskets. Economists have also studied third-degree price discrimination under competition and the obvious implications for segmentation. Borenstein (1985) studied price discrimination in monopolistic competition using simulations and found that such discrimination can increase profits for firms by lessening competition for one segment. Holmes (1989) provided a rigorous analytical framework for a similar setting in a duopoly and Corts (1998) extended the work of Holmes and relaxed some of the assumptions to provide additional insights. Corts (1998) modeled third degree price discrimination in order to determine when price discrimination1 would have unambiguous price and welfare effects. One of his concerns was with preventing prisoner’s dilemma, an equilibrium in which all firms are worse off relative to some other outcome but in which all firms choose their dominant strategies. This is an important feature since price discrimination is a dominant strategy in the third degree price discrimination as Corts modeled it. As we will show, seconddegree price discrimination is not a dominant strategy given explicit incentive compatibility constraints. Corts (1998) remains focused on how firms can strategically commit to not price discriminate when price

Corts introduces the concept of ‘best-response-asymmetry” that arises when firms rank their best market segments differently; i.e., firms have different “strong” and “weak” markets. The best-response-asymmetry is the necessary condition to have what Corts calls “all-out-competition” where prices fall for all consumer groups with third degree price discrimination.

1

5

discrimination leads to prisoner’s dilemma, perhaps through the use of some mechanisms such as every day low price. We show that the decision not to price discriminate can occur in a natural way when incentive compatibility must be explicitly considered. In contrast to Holmes (1989) and Corts (1998), we are able to make less ambiguous predictions and provide sharper insights into the effects of asymmetry. Prior work on price discrimination in competitive environments has made use of targeting, third-degree price discrimination or second-degree price discrimination with implicit incentive compatibility constraints that allows firms to target without fear of leakage2. Our investigation is a useful contribution because it is often difficult or impossible to offer different coupons and prices to different consumers (third-degree price discrimination). Competitive second degree price discrimination between symmetric firms is often found in works concerned with product line design (Armstrong and Vickers, 2001; Locay and Rodriguez, 1992; SchmidtMohr and Villas Boaz, 2008; Desai, 2001; Champsaur and Rochet, 1989). The closest settings to ours were investigated in Desai (2001) and Schmidt-Mohr and Villas-Boas (2008) in the context of product line design. In these works, as in the present work, consumers are distributed on a continuum with both horizontal and vertical preferences. As in the present work, firms face two-dimensional decisions—price and a second variable. Incentive compatibility and individual rationality are the key considerations in these works as well. The difference between these works and ours is on the focus and generality. In Desai (2001) and Schmidt-Mohr and Villas-Boas (2008) symmetry is crucial for tractability, whereas in the present work asymmetry is the focus. In the above two works, product line design allows the firms to serve segments with different quality valuations, whereas here the segments differ in their price saliency—more appropriate for coupon and rebate problems. While this does not change the basic tradeoff between the desire for discrimination and the desire to lessen competition (see Champsaur and Rochet, 1989), it drastically changes the solution concept. Finally, whereas the focus of Schmidt-Mohr

For example, in Coughlan and Soberman (2005), consumers with a high cost of time, who also have lower price sensitivity and higher value for service than low cost of time consumers, are assumed to find the outlet mall too far for convenience. This allows for perfect segmentation since the incentive compatibility constraints are assumed to be met.

2

6

and Villas-Boas (2008) is to establish the sufficient conditions for the existence of a pure strategy Nash equilibrium outcome and in Desai (2001) to characterize the conditions under which the markets provide complete or incomplete coverage, the present work is concerned with characterizing the equilibria, primarily mixed strategy equilibria, in an asymmetric environment. Even though our work focuses on untargeted distribution of rebates, it is useful to relate it to the prior work on “targeted-promotions” by Shaffer and Zhang (1995, 2000 and 2002) and Chen, Narasimhan and Zhang (2001). Shaffer and Zhang (1995) employ a two-stage coupon targeting game by two symmetric firms and report that a single-stage simultaneous-move game does not have pure strategy Nash equilibrium. Our work suggests that explicitly incorporating incentive compatibility constraints can provide equilibrium in a simultaneous-move promotion game. Shaffer and Zhang (1995) also conclude that coupon targeting leads to a prisoner’s dilemma outcome for two symmetric firms. Like Shaffer and Zhang (1995) we feel that asymmetry is critical in settings with price discrimination. Often the insights obtained by explicitly considering asymmetry turn out to be important. Shaffer and Zhang (2000) solve a simultaneous-move game of third-degree price discrimination model to study when a firm would target its own or its competitor’s customers. They find that when demand is asymmetric both firms can benefit from coupon targeting. Shaffer and Zhang (2000) further report that price discrimination favors the firm with the smaller market share. Our finding for untargeted promotions that the disadvantaged firm benefits more that the advantaged rival is similar to this. In Shaffer and Zhang’s (2000) work, the firm that can price discriminate does so at the expense of its rival. In contrast, we show that when only one firm employs a segmentation strategy (the disadvantaged firm) it is not necessarily at the expense of its rival. Shaffer and Zhang (2002) find that when customers are individually addressable and customer preferences are known, one-to-one promotions would favor the firm with larger or more loyal customer base. They show that the asymmetry in customer loyalty and firm size could help firms avoid prisoner’s dilemma outcome. Similarly, if the targeting was less than perfect, the prisoner’s dilemma outcome could be avoided for low targeting accuracy levels even when the firms are symmetric (Chen, Narasimhan, and Zhang, 2001).

7

3. The Model FIRMS: In our model there are two firms, A and D. The two firms offer products that are differentiated. Differentiation is based on two factors. The first is a combination of attributes, represented by a onedimensional space. We posit a spatial model of differentiation in a one dimensional space a la Hotelling, following Shaffer and Zhang (1995) among others. The two firms are assumed to be located at the ends of a line segment DA of unit length, as shown in Figure 1. The second basis of differentiation is the brand itself. This might capture “inimitable” characteristics that consumers might value.3 In particular, we assume that all consumers agree that one of the brands is superior on this second factor. The firm that is superior in this sense is called the advantaged firm (A) and the other firm is called the disadvantaged firm (D). Finally, firm i, i =A, D, is assumed to incur a constant marginal cost Ci on its product.

Figure 1: A spatial depiction of the competitive environment CONSUMERS: In the spirit of the Hotelling model, we assume that consumers are located on the line segment DA. The location of a consumer defines the ideal combination of attributes desired by her. The utility of a product to a consumer τ then consists of three components: the utility for his or her ideal product, v; the disutility of a non-ideal product by virtue of its location far away from the consumer’s ideal point at a distance dτi, i = A, D; and a brand value bi for firm i’s product arising from the inimitable characteristics of firm i. Note that v and bi are assumed to be the same for all consumers, and as a result consumer heterogeneity arises purely from considerations of location in the product space. We assume that the disutility due to a product’s non-ideal location is linear in the distance of the product from the consumer’s ideal point. Specifically, we model the disutility of a consumer τ, located at a distance τ from D and (1-τ) from A, as dτD = α τ and dτA = α (1-τ).
3

As an example, vitamin tablets shaped like the Flintstones would possess an inimitable characteristic. Reputation, in the short run, would also be inimitable.

8

If α is high, consumers are less willing to sacrifice their desired attribute combination and we say that the product is more salient to consumers. On the other hand if α is low, price is more salient to consumers. Define the valuation of each brand as Vi = v + bi. Then the utility of brand i to consumer τ is (Vi - dτi). Finally, we assume that consumers are distributed uniformly over DA. CONSUMER SEGMENTS: In our model, we assume that there are two segments of consumers, each distributed uniformly over DA. We denote the location at which consumers of type k are indifferent over the two firms by τ k , k = 1, 2. The two segments differ in whether the product is more salient to them or price is more salient. Specifically, we assume that α1 > α2. This implies that for consumers in segment 1 the product is more salient while for those in segment 2, price is more salient. One way to interpret this is to say that consumers in segment 2 are more price oriented than consumers in segment 1, as in Corts (1998), Coughlan and Soberman (2005), Lal and Rao (1997) and Shaffer and Zhang (1995). This, in turn, would imply that consumers in segment 2 would also value rebates more than consumers in segment 1. To capture this, we assume that consumers in segment 1 incur a high cost of effort in redeeming rebates while consumers in segment 2 incur a lower cost of redemption. These redemption costs are exogenous to the firm4. Thus, denoting ek to be the redemption cost for consumers in segment k, we assume e1 > e2. Given this inequality of redemption costs, a rebate would represent a higher value to consumers in segment 2. We refer to consumers in segment 1 as high type consumers and to consumers in segment 2 as low type consumers.5 We assume that there is a discount associated with redeeming a rebate, denoted by

Redemption costs may be influenced by the firm’s decision and as such could be treated as endogenous. However, the difference among consumers is still exogenous and we therefore treat e1 and e2 as exogenous.
5

4

Note that in our model, redemption cost and price sensitivity are perfectly correlated. The assumption of perfect correlation is consistent with different consumer segments having different costs of time (Coughlan and Soberman, 2005; Winter, 1993). This assumption could be relaxed. As long as there is a positive correlation between low effort cost and price sensitivity, our results will hold.

9

δ.6 The high type segment (segment 1) is of size γ and the low type segment (segment 2) is of size (1-γ), where 0 < γ < 1. DYNAMICS: We assume that there is a time lag between purchase and rebate payment. This time lag is assumed to be specified exogenously, reflecting the technology of rebate processing. Thus, the time to redemption is not a strategic variable in our model. We denote time by t. Finally, we assume that both firms discount future cash flows by a discount factor δF. To keep the exposition simple, we assume that the firm’s discount rate is the same as the consumer’s discount rate, so δF = δ. This is not a crucial assumption and has no effect on the generality of our results.7 GAME: Firms decide simultaneously on their prices and rebate amounts that maximize their respective profits. The profit functions are:

Π D = γ PDτ 1 + (1 − γ )( PD − δ t RD )τ 2 Π A = γ PA (1 − τ 1 ) + (1 − γ )( PA − δ t RA )(1 − τ 2 )

(1) (2)

The first term in (1) and (2) is the profit from high types and the second term is the profit from the low types. Note that the firm can offer any rebate amount, but not any rebate will effectively segment the population. If a firm decides to offer an effective rebate, it must satisfy incentive compatibility (IC) and individual rationality (IR) constraints such that consumers of each type pick the offering targeted at them. When a rebate does not meet the IC and IR conditions, the firm does not offer an effective rebate; in this case we say, without loss of generality, that the firm offers zero rebate. Rebates are not targeted at high type consumers in segment 1, so we require that the value of the rebate be less than the cost of obtaining it for these consumers, which implies the following inequality:

δ t Ri ≤ e1
6

(3)

A higher discount factor is associated with a lower discount rate. We assume that the discounting is constant across consumers. One could alternatively let this discount factor vary in the consumer population. We chose to let the consumers’ costs of effort vary and keep this discount constant, but we did work out the alternative formulation and the results are qualitatively unchanged.

7

One could allow all three discount rates to differ. This would make the problem less tractable with little or no additional insight. Alternatively, one could have δF = δ1 and leave type 2 as the “unusually patient” type. This would result in one or both firms targeting that type with rebates that mature at t ∞.

10

And the rebates must yield positive surplus to low type consumers in segment 2.

δ t Ri ≥ e2

for all Ri > 0

(4)

Consumers of each type must also obtain non-negative surplus if they decide to purchase the product. For the marginal consumer the two products must yield equal surplus. Therefore, for the marginal consumer who is indifferent to the two products, we have, for consumers in each segment the following conditions:

VD − α 1τ 1 − PD = V A − α 1 (1 − τ 1 ) − PA ≥ 0

(5) (6)

VD − α 2τ 2 − PD + δ t RD − e2 = VA − α 2 (1 − τ 2 ) − PA + δ t RA − e2 ≥ 0

In equation (6) we assume that both firms offer effective rebates. If one firm, say firm i, does not offer an effective rebate, the corresponding value of δ t Ri − e2 drops out of equation (6). Thus, the constraints change depending on whether one firm, both or neither firm offer effective rebates. To solve the problem, we characterize the best response functions for each firm and then search for the profit maximizing decisions over the full strategy space.

4. Equilibrium Outcomes and Analysis Since the firms in our model make their rebate and price decisions simultaneously, there are discontinuities in the solution space. Each firm needs to decide whether or not to offer a rebate and determine the rebate amount and the price. There are four possible pure strategy outcomes: (1) Neither firm rebates, (2) only firm D rebates, (3) only firm A rebates and (4) both firms rebate. Under each outcome, the two firms simultaneously maximize profits subject to incentive compatibility and participation constraints. The solution procedure and the results for pure strategy equilibrium outcomes are provided in the appendix. We next examine the entire strategy space. We do this by noting that the four outcomes are more than a mere convenient solution approach. Instead, they are real discontinuities in the payoff functions for both firms. Below a certain rebate amount, the firm is essentially not offering a rebate at all. This discontinuity affects not only the firm’s payoff function but its rival’s payoff function as well. When the firm does not offer a rebate, the rival’s incentives change in a discontinuous way.

11

Note that none of these four outcomes by itself constitutes an equilibrium. The procedure merely lists all feasible pure strategy solutions to the firms’ maximization problems. To characterize the pure strategy equilibria for the firms, we verify whether a solution is an equilibrium by calculating the additional profit a firm can achieve by deviating from the given solution. Since the decisions are done simultaneously, when a firm deviates it is not constrained to move to another feasible solution but is free to change its decision variables, e.g. a firm that is offering a rebate in a given solution may deviate by ceasing its rebate offer and changing its price. Similarly, a firm who is not offering a rebate in a given solution may deviate to a positive rebate. We first find all feasible solutions. Then – in the appendix – characterize all pure strategy equilibria by deriving the cutoffs. The equilibrium cutoffs are reported in the appendix as conditions in terms of the valuation difference, VA – VD Our main results are organized as follows. We start with a technical result to show that the disadvantaged firm D generally charges a lower price. This is Proposition 1. In section 4.2 we show in Proposition 2 that as the valuation difference increases, the advantaged firm is less attracted to pure strategy equilibria where it offers a rebate while the disadvantaged firm is more attracted to pure strategy equilibria where it offers a rebate. We use this result to develop the main intuition for the role that rebates play in our model. We then show that there exists no pure strategy equilibrium in which firm A offers a rebate but firm D does not. This is Proposition 3. Furthermore, in any mixed strategy equilibrium, firm D has a higher probability of offering a rebate. This is Proposition 4. Taken together, Proposition 3 and Proposition 4 suggest that in practice we are likely to see rebates offered by disadvantaged firms rather than advantaged ones. This will be the basis for our examination of data in section 5. 4.1. The pricing strategy Note that in most equilibria, the advantaged firm’s price is higher than its rival. The following proposition states this finding formally. Proposition 1: In any pure strategy equilibrium where firms are asymmetric in consumer valuations, the disadvantaged firm’s price is always lower than its rival’s unless only the disadvantaged firm offers a

12

rebate. When only the disadvantaged firm offers a rebate, its price is lower only if the difference between the firms’ consumer valuations is higher than a threshold value (u*), given by

u* =

α1 (1 − γ )[3(α1 − α 2 ) − e2 ] . 4[(1 − γ )α1 + γα 2 ]

Let (q, w) be a mixed strategy equilibrium profile, where q (w) is the probability that the disadvantaged (advantaged) firm will offer a rebate in a given mixed strategy equilibrium. In any mixed strategy equilibrium, the disadvantaged firm’s price is lower than its rival’s only if the difference between the firms’ consumer valuations is higher than a threshold value (u**), given by

u ** =

α1 (1 − γ )( q − w)[6(α1 − α 2 ) − (2 + qw)e2 ] . 2(4 − qw)[(1 − γ )α1 + γα 2 ]

Proof: All the proofs are relegated to the appendix.

4.2. Rebating and Segmentation in Asymmetric Duopoly

It is clear that the equilibrium depends on the model parameters . To compare all possible equilibria,, we find it useful to examine “equilibrium attraction”. Attraction, or basins of attraction, is a concept often used in game theory in analysis of games with multiple equilibria (Ellison, 1993; Fudenberg and Levin, 1998). It allows the us to gauge the strength of one equilibrium relative to another. The attraction of an equilibrium can be described as the best response region of the simplex that corresponds to that particular equilibrium. We specifically want to see how asymmetry in firm valuations affects the attraction of rebates. We find that the attraction of offering a rebate increases for the disadvantaged firm as it becomes more disadvantaged vis-à-vis its rival. Therefore, offering a rebate becomes more attractive for the disadvantaged firm. At the same time, the exact opposite result is observed for the advantaged firm. The advantaged firm benefits less from offering rebates if its advantage is higher. As the difference between

13

consumer valuations for the two firms widens we can expect rebates to be provided by the disadvantaged firm rather than the advantaged one. The above result seems to suggest that the basin of attraction of a rebating equilibrium is asymmetric for the two firms in a predictable manner. Using the equilibrium cutoffs, we can state the attraction to a rebating equilibrium by each firm. Proposition 2: As the relative advantage of the advantaged firm increases, the attraction of the advantaged firm to a pure strategy equilibrium where it offers a rebate decreases while the attraction of the disadvantaged firm to a pure strategy equilibrium where it offers a rebate increases. What is Proposition 2 telling us? When only the disadvantaged firm D offers a rebate (to the low type consumers), in effect its pricing is determined by its desire to compete for the high type consumers. Since the high types are not as price oriented as the low types, moving competition away from the low types leads to higher prices, benefiting both firms even if only one firm offers a rebate. Clearly, when only D offers a rebate, some low type consumers would still consider (the unrebated) product A, depending on the location of their ideal product. In this case, the non-zero rebate by D does not completely separate the two types of consumers, but changes the customer mix more towards high types so that “average” price salience is lower. This separation of the two types of consumers is a segmentation strategy. Under competition, firms would like to compete separately for the two segments. In particular, price is more salient for the low types, and so competing for them lowers prices for the high types. This can be avoided if the low types could be addressed using a tool other than price – rebates in this case. When only one firm offers a rebate, segmentation is partial and prices are higher relative to the no rebate case. When both firms offer rebates, segmentation is complete, and prices are highest. Thus we can see that segmentation, whether partial or full, benefits both firms by enabling them to extract higher surplus from the high type consumers. Many interesting insights emerge from the pure strategy equilibrium cutoffs. First note that the cutoffs depend critically on the value of the redemption cost for the low type consumers (e2). We find that, given the asymmetry level, the attractiveness of a pure strategy equilibrium where one or both firms

14

offer rebate is higher as the redemption cost asymptotically approaches to zero. However, whether or not a given solution constitutes equilibrium depends on both the redemption cost and the asymmetry level. For instance, if the redemption cost is high enough even at low valuation difference levels the advantaged firm may not want to offer a rebate. This is because the firm that offers a rebate incurs a cost to make the second-degree price discrimination through consumer self-selection work. The redemption cost along with the asymmetry between the two firms determines the pure strategy equilibria. Clearly, this feature of our model does not exist in third-degree and other price discrimination models where consumer segments are assumed to be perfectly separable. We can get a clear picture of how the equilibria change with the extent of asymmetry between the firms by investigating the equilibria cutoffs. Figure 2 depicts a numerical example of how the pure strategy equilibria change. The results shown in this figure can be generalized using the equilibrium cutoffs given in the appendix. We present one such generalization in Proposition 3 and discuss other interesting ones later in this section. With this in mind, we computed the equilibria by varying u = VA - VD over the interval [0, 20]; holding all other parameters constant8. Even though the figure shows that pure strategy equilibrium exists for all the valuation differences, this is not true for other parameter values. It is possible that we may not have pure strategy equilibrium for a range of valuation difference levels. For low values of asymmetry (region I) we observe multiple equilibria. In region I, both firms offering rebates is equilibrium as also neither firm offering rebates. There is also a mixed strategy equilibrium in this range and we derive it in the next section. The equilibrium in which both firms offer rebates results in higher profits than the other two equilibria for low values of asymmetry. So, it is preferable for both firms, and so firms face a coordination problem. For high values of asymmetry (region III), on the other hand, both firms improve their profits if only firm D offers a rebate as Proposition 2 suggests. Thus, in this example, it is equilibrium for both firms to offer rebates for small asymmetries, and only firm D offering a rebate for larger asymmetries. In the intermediate range of asymmetry (region II), neither firm offering a rebate emerges as the unique equilibrium. This is because firm A prefers only
8

We set VA = 100, α1 = 10, α2 = 7.5, δ = 0.9, γ = 0.4, e2 = 0.2, e1 = 5 t = 8.

15

firm D to offer a rebate in this intermediate range; however, firm D prefers both firms to offer rebates. Even though both firms rebating is a better outcome for both firms than neither firm rebating, it is not in equilibrium.
Profit

Equilibrium 3: Only D Rebates Equilibrium 2: Both Rebate Equilibrium 1: Neither Rebates

5 u1*

10

15 u2*

20

u = VA - VB 0 5 u1* 10 15 u2* 20

Figure 2: Equilibria with changing asymmetry in consumer valuations (u)

In the above numerical example, we see no equilibrium in which only firm A offers a rebate. Is this result generalizable? The answer is yes and presented as Proposition 3. The result makes intuitive sense; with its higher valuation the advantaged firm (A) prefers to focus on the high types. Proposition 3: There is no pure strategy Nash equilibrium outcome where the advantaged firm rebates and the disadvantaged firm does not rebate. The figure also exhibits other results that can be generalized. Note that the asymmetric equilibrium wherein the disadvantaged firm rebates alone does not coincide with a symmetric equilibrium where neither firm rebates, so the two types of equilibria cannot co-exist. The proof is provided in the appendix under generalization 1. We next examine how the sizes of the consumer segments affect the uniqueness of equilibrium in region III. We set the value of asymmetry equal to 17.5 (to see all possible equilibria) and vary the size of the high type segment over the interval [0, 1]. Figure 3 shows the

16

equilibria. We see that only one firm offering a rebate emerges as the unique equilibrium when the size of the high type segment is intermediate (region II). When the proportion of high type consumers is moderate, both firms will have much to gain by separating the segments. However, partial segmentation entails one firm taking the less lucrative low type segment. Though both firms benefit from segmentation relative to no segmentation, each firm would like to be the one with the high type segment. That is, each firm would like the other firm to offer the rebate. Even when it is profitable for a firm to offer a rebate, it is more attractive if the other firm offers a rebate as well.9 In equilibrium, the advantaged firm, who would win out in the competition for the high type segment, has less to gain from offering a rebate. Hence, whenever only one firm offers a rebate in equilibrium (only one firm finds the benefit from segmentation to exceed the cost of foregoing the lucrative high type segment), it will be the disadvantaged firm. When the size of the high type segment is small (region I), i.e. the size of the low type segment is large, the firms once again face a Prisoners’ Dilemma. Each firm prefers the other to offer rebates. Even though both firms would profit if they both offered rebates, it is not in equilibrium. Finally, when the size of the high type segment is large (regions III and IV), both firms offering rebates is in equilibrium. We find that for a given value of asymmetry in the interval [u2*, 20], the sizes of segments impact the nature of the equilibrium.

A similar strategic complementarity is shown in Kumar and Rao (2006), where a firm benefits more from a dataanalytics program that allows it to segment the market if the competing firm also obtains the data-analytics program.

9

17

Profit

V
Equilibrium 3: Both Rebate Equilibrium 2: Only D Rebates Equilibrium 1: Neither Rebates

0

0.2

γ1*

0.4

γ2*

0.6

0.8

γ3*

γ
1.0

Figure 3: Equilibria with changing proportion of high type consumers (γ )

4.3 The Mixed Strategy Equilibrium

Under certain conditions, the equilibrium for the full space is in mixed strategies over rebating and not rebating (recall that not rebating includes all rebate amounts that do not satisfy the IC and IR conditions), in addition to equilibria in pure strategies. Given our interest in examining data on rebates, it is useful to characterize the mixed strategy equilibrium also, since in practice many firms in the same industry offer rebates.10 Since rebates are temporary price reductions, they are properly viewed as promotions. And many kinds of promotions have been identified by mixed strategies in prior analytical work by Varian (1980) and Narasimhan (1984), and in empirical work by Rao, Arjunji and Murthi (1995) and Villas-Boas (1995). Indeed, Rao, Arjunji and Murthi offered the generalization that competitive promotions are mixed strategies based on empirical findings in many product categories. The solution procedure for mixed strategy equilibrium outcomes is provided in the appendix. In our model, we find that that the disadvantaged firm would rebate more frequently than its advantaged rival in any mixed

10

In fact we will see in the next section that in the printer market we observe rebate promotions by virtually all manufacturers and these promotions appear to be uncorrelated, with the exception of seasonal promotion such as end of year sales. This seems to indicate that the mixed strategy equilibrium would be a good candidate to describe empirical observation.

18

strategy Nash equilibrium. This is consistent with proposition 3 that shows that the disadvantaged firm will never find itself in a pure strategy Nash equilibrium outcome not offering a rebate in response to a competitor’s rebate. The mixed strategy finding is formalized in the following proposition. Proposition 4: In any mixed strategy Nash equilibrium, the disadvantaged firm offers a rebate with a probability as high, or higher, than the advantaged firm.
5. Analysis of Rebates in the Printer Category

We next examine some data on rebates in the printer category. The printer category is a dynamic category, with firms continually devising pricing, promotion and new product initiatives as part of their competitive strategy (Shankar, 2005). There are three major subcategories in the printer category: Inkjet, Laser, and Multi-function (printer with other functions such as photo printing, copying, and fax functions) with a handful of firms dominating each sub-category. While Hewlett-Packard has long established itself as the leader in all printer categories, there is fierce competition for second place. Given our interest in rebates, we want to ensure that rebates occur with sufficient frequency in the product category we choose to examine. In the printer category, looking at all brands, in any given week 30% of SKU’s carry a rebate on average. For all these reasons, we chose to study the printer category.

5.1 Description of Data

We collected data on printers from the website of a major retailer specializing in office equipment. The time period for the data is November 2004 to August 2005. We gathered daily price and rebate information for each SKU that the store carries. We can identify the brand name for each SKU. For purposes of analysis we decided to aggregate daily data over a week. The reason for this is that most rebates run for a week. Table 1 gives a frequency distribution of the duration of rebates. We can see that over 75% of the rebates are offered for one week. The price variable was the average price in the week. In addition we gathered data on 2004 market share for each brand in the laser sub-category from International Data Corporation (IDC).

19

Rebate length

1
(weeks) Frequency %

2 28

3 8

4 5 1.90

5 14 5.32

6 6 2.28

8 1 0.38

10 1 0.38

11 1 0.38

199

75.67 10.65 3.04

Table 1: Rebate length distribution

5.2 Hypotheses

We want to test our main result that the disadvantaged firm is more likely to offer rebates. One thing to note in our data is that all brands and most SKU’s offer a rebate. This might suggest a mixed Nash strategy equilibrium as in our model. As a first step, we wanted to see if the retailer might act in such a way as to coordinate the rebates across brands (Lal, 1990). We tested for independence of rebate offers across pairs of brands using a Chi-squared test. This test is conservative for our purpose. 11 Table 2 contains the test statistics for pair-wise independence of rebates. We find that in all but four cases, the hypothesis of independence cannot be rejected at the 5% level. Given the conservative nature of the test, we would be justified in rejecting any coordination of rebate offers by competitors. We will therefore assume that rebates result from mixed strategies. Now, invoking Proposition 4 of our analysis, we should expect that the disadvantaged firm would offer rebates with greater probability than the advantaged firm. This is what we wish to test next. To render this into a specific hypothesis it is necessary to map a firm’s advantage to observable variables. This is challenging because in practice it is not easy to determine who exactly is an advantaged (or disadvantaged) firm. We met this challenge by conducting our analysis using several proxies.

11

See Rao (1996), for example.

20

Firm Brother HP Konica Lexmark Okidata Xerox

Brother
0 0.01 0.68 0.003 0.12 0.49

HP

Konica

Lexmark

Okidata

Xerox

Number of Rebates12 26

0 0.20 0.02 0.09 0.39 0 0.88 0.39 0.18 0 0.01 0.46 0 0.46 0

22 14 13 13 1

Table 2: Test statistics (p-values) from tests for independence

We analyzed the laser printer market at the brand level using two proxies: market share and price. A firm with a higher market share in equilibrium can reasonably be argued to have greater brand equity, and so would be the advantaged firm. Turning to price, a brand with a higher consumer valuation would charge a higher price (by Proposition 1). As such, a brand that is priced higher in equilibrium would be the advantaged firm. In addition to the brand level analysis, we examined the relationship between price and the likelihood of a rebate at the SKU level in each of the three sub-categories. Finally, we also conducted an analysis across sub-categories relating price to rebate frequency. The inkjet category is the most disadvantaged and the laser category the most advantaged. As such the laser category should carry rebates least often and inkjet the most13. In this way, we want to see how robust our findings are at the brand level, SKU level and sub-category level. We now formally state our hypothesis, corresponding to each proxy for the advantaged firm:
Hypothesis 1a: Brands with higher market share will offer rebate less frequently. Hypothesis 1b: Brands and/or SKUs with higher average price will offer rebate less frequently. Hypothesis 1c: Subcategories with higher price will rebate less frequently.

12 13

To be precise, this is how often at least one SKU in the brand carries a rebate in a given week. In theory, we could use features to assess quality. The problem there is that the number of features is large relative to the number of SKU’s and these features are highly correlated with each other as well as with brand names.

21

5.3 Results and Discussion

Our first analysis is at the brand level in the laser sub-category. The brands are ordered, from highest to lowest, by market share as follows: HP, Xerox, Konica, Brother, Lexmark. The ordering, by price, is: Xerox, HP, Konica, Lexmark, and Brother. We can see in the histogram in Figure 4 that displays the frequency of rebates along with market share and price. Rebate frequency is operationalized as the proportion of SKU’s promoted each period by the brand given that our analysis is at the brand level.

1 0.9 Price/Rebate Freq/Mkt Share 0.8 0.7 0.6 0.5 HP 0.4 0.3 Brother 0.2 0.1 0 Brand Lexmark Konica

Xerox

Rebate Frequency Price Market Share

Figure 4: Price, Rebate Frequency and Market Share Data for Laser Printer Category

As we can see there is a negative relationship between price and rebate frequency. There is also a negative relationship between market share and rebate frequency, with the possible exception of Xerox. The brand with the highest market share and the second highest price, HP, has the lowest rebate frequency, while the brand with the lowest price and the second lowest market share, Brother, has the highest rebate frequency. To get a better feel for this data we conducted paired comparisons for these brands. The t-test results for these comparisons are shown in Table 3. In the first column, each pair is ordered with the first brand being the advantaged brand relative to the second with two exceptions: HP-Xerox and Brother-Lexmark. Our proxies have different predictions for these two pairs. The dependent variable is the difference in the

22

rebate frequencies of the first and the second brands in any given week. Therefore, according to our hypothesis this difference should be negative for all but two aforementioned cases. In those two cases, our prediction is positive for one of the proxies whereas it is negative for the other. The number of observations for each hypothesis is the number of weeks in our sample. In the two right-most columns, we provide the predictions of hypothesis 1a and 1b. In the last row, we display a count of the number of predictions which are inconsistent with our hypothesis.

Comparison HP-Brother HP-Lexmark HP-Konica HP-Xerox Konica-Brother Konica-Lexmark Xerox-Konica Xerox-Brother Xerox-Lexmark

DF 37 37 37 37 37 37 37 37 37

t Value
-6.93 -3.02 -3.25 7.01 0.65 0.77 -4.68 -9.41 -4.50 0.41

Pr > |t| 0 since γ < 1 and α1 − α 2 > e2 . PA − PD = (VA − VD ) + 1 3 6[(1 − γ )α1 + γα 2 ]

In both firms rebating equilibrium, we get PA − PD =

2 3

(VA − VD ) > 0 .

In mixed strategy equilibrium, we compare the average prices charged by both firms.

E ( PA ) = wPAr + (1 − w) PAnr E ( PD ) = qPDr + (1 − q) PDnr E ( PA ) − E ( PD ) = 2 3 (VA − VD ) −

α1 (1 − γ )( q − w)[6(α1 − α 2 ) − (2 + qw)e2 ] 3(4 − qw)[(1 − γ )α1 + γα 2 ]

Hence, E ( PA ) − E ( PD ) > 0 if

VA − VD >

α1 (1 − γ )( q − w)[6(α1 − α 2 ) − (2 + qw)e2 ] = u ** . QED 2(4 − qw)[(1 − γ )α1 + γα 2 ]

Proof of Proposition 2 The proof directly follows from the pure strategy equilibria cut-offs. Recall that the advantaged firm offers rebates

in two pure strategy equilibria given by solutions 3 and 4. Using the cutoffs u A and u A described earlier we see that the advantaged firm does not deviate from solutions 3 and 4, if VA − VD ≤ u A and VA − VD ≤ u A , respectively.
3 4

3

4

36

Clearly, as the relative advantage ( VA − VD ) increases, the preceding conditions are less likely to be satisfied. Therefore the advantaged firm is more likely to deviate for larger values of VA − VD . Similarly there are two pure strategy equilibria where the disadvantaged firm offers a rebate. These are given by solutions 2 and 4. Using the cutoffs u D and u D described earlier we see that the disadvantaged firm does not deviate from solutions 2 and 4, if VA − VD ≥ uD and VA − VD ≥ u D , respectively. It is clear that as the relative
2
4 2 4

advantage ( VA − VD ) increases, the preceding conditions are more likely to be satisfied. Therefore the disadvantaged firm is less likely to deviate for larger values of VA − VD . QED
Proof of Proposition 3

In order for firm A rebating alone in equilibrium u D ≥ u and u A ≥ u as given in A.19 and A.20, where
3 3

u = VA − VD . Reorganizing firm D’s equilibrium cutoffs we get:
2 (4α − 7γα 2 )e2 + 6α 2 (3α + 5α1 )e2 − 16α ue2 ≥ 27γα 2 (α1 − α 2 ) 2 .

Similarly, reorganizing firm A’s equilibrium cutoffs and multiplying both sides of the inequality by 9 leads to
2 27γα 2 (α1 − α 2 ) 2 ≥ −9(α + 2γα 2 )e2 + 54α 2 (α + α1 )e2 + 4α ue2 .

Note that the right hand side of the first and the left hand side of the second inequality are the same. Therefore, combining the inequalities we get e2 ≥

α 2 (36α + 24α1 ) + 20α u . When firm A rebates alone, plugging in the 13α + 11γα 2
2uα + 3α 2 (α1 + α ) . Combining the two conditions on e2 leads to 2α + γα 2

optimal price and rebate values (A.8-A.10) into equation A.2 and noting the restriction on market share τ 2 ≤ 1 and rewriting it in terms of e2 leads to e2 ≤

−[uα (12α + 2(1 − γ )α1 ) + α 2 [(33α 2 + 3αγα 2 + 9(1 − γ )α12 ] ≥ 0 . Since the left hand side of the preceding inequality is negative, firm A rebating alone cannot be Nash equilibrium. QED
Proof of Generalization 1

Using the equilibrium cutoffs we find u D − u D =
2 1 1 D

(1 − γ )α1e2


2 > 0 , i.e. u D > u1 . Clearly the equilibrium conditions D 2

for firm D rebating alone outcome ( u ≥ u ) and neither firm rebating outcome ( u D ≤ u ) cannot hold simultaneously. QED
Proof of Proposition 4 Reorganizing equations A.23 and A.24 gives w( Π Dr , Ar − mix − Π Dnr , Ar − mix ) − (1 − w)( Π Dnr , Anr − mix − Π Dr , Anr − mix ) = 0 q ( Π Ar , Dr − mix − Π Anr , Dr − mix ) − (1 − q )( Π Anr , Dnr − mix − Π Ar , Dnr − mix ) = 0

(A.25) (A.26)

The profit differences are:

37

Π Dr , Ar − mix − Π Dnr , Ar − mix =

(1 − γ )e2 u (1 − γ ) 2 − [(12γα 2 (2 − w(1 + q))( q − w)) + (1 − γ )(4 − wq) 2 (2q + w)α1 )e2 6α 2 24α 2 (4 − wq) 2 α

+12α 2 (α1 (4 − wq) 2 − (α1 − α 2 )γ ( qw((2 + q) w − 8 − q) + 2(2 − w) 2 ))e2 − 12γα 2 (α1 − α 2 ) 2 (2 + w)(4 + q − (1 + q) w)] (1 − γ )e2u (1 − γ ) 2 − [(12γα 2 (2 − w(1 + q))(2 + w) + (1 − γ )(4 − wq) 2 (3 − 2q − w)α1 )e2 Π Dnr , Anr − mix − Π Dr , Anr − mix = − 6α 2 24α 2 (4 − wq)2 α −12α 2 (α1 (4 − wq) 2 − (α1 − α 2 )γ ( qw((2 + q ) w − 4) + 8 + 2 w2 ))e2 + 12γα 2 (α1 − α 2 ) 2 (2 + w)(2 − (1 + q) w)] (1 − γ )e2u (1 − γ ) 2 − [(12γα 2 (2 − q(1 + w))( q − w) + (1 − γ )(4 − wq)2 (2 w + q)α1 )e2 Π Ar , Dr − mix − Π Anr , Dr − mix = − 6α 2 24α 2 (4 − wq) 2 α +12α 2 (α1 (4 − wq) 2 − (α1 − α 2 )γ ( qw((2 + w) q − 8 − w) + 2(2 − q) 2 ))e2 − 12γα 2 (α1 − α 2 )2 (2 + q)(4 − w + (1 + w)q )] (1 − γ )e2 u (1 − γ ) 2 Π Anr , Dnr − mix − Π Ar , Dnr − mix = − [(12γα 2 (2 − q(1 + w))(2 + q) + (1 − γ )(4 − wq )2 (3 − 2 w − q)α1 )e2 6α 2 24α 2 (4 − wq )2 α −12α 2 (α1 (4 − wq) 2 − (α1 − α 2 )γ ( qw((2 + w) q − 4) + 8 + 2q 2 ))e2 + 12γα 2 (α1 − α 2 ) 2 (2 + q)(2 − (1 + w)q )] Note that even though the above differences are functions of both (u, q, w), u does not interact with (q, w). Note that even though the above differences are functions of both (u, q, w), u does not interact with (q, w). Plugging in the expressions into equations A.25 and A.26 give the following equalities:
(1 − γ )e2 u (1 − γ ) 2 + [(12γ (2 − w − wq) 2 α 2 + (1 − γ )(4 − wq ) 2 (3 − 2q − 4 w)α1 )e2 6α 2 24α 2 (4 − wq) 2 α −12α 2 (α1 (4 − wq) − 2γ (α1 − α 2 )(2 + w)(2 − w − wq))e2 + 12γ (2 + w) α 2 (α1 − α 2 ) ] = 0
2 2 2

(A.27)



(1 − γ )e2 u (1 − γ ) 2 + [(12γ (2 − q − wq) 2 α 2 + (1 − γ )(4 − wq )2 (3 − 4q − 2 w)α1 )e2 6α 2 24α 2 (4 − wq) 2 α
2 2 2

(A.28)

−12α 2 (α1 (4 − wq) − 2γ (α1 − α 2 )(2 + q)(2 − q − wq))e2 + 12γ (2 + q ) α 2 (α1 − α 2 ) ] = 0

For u > 0 , the first term of equation A.27 is positive while the first term of equation A.28 is negative. Therefore, the second term of equation A.27 (in the square brackets) must be negative and the parallel term in equation A.28 must be positive in order to have A.27 and A.28 hold simultaneously. This can be stated as two inequalities:
2 ⎡ −(12γ (2 − w − wq) 2 α 2 + (1 − γ )(4 − wq) 2 (3 − 2q − 4 w)α1 )e2 ⎤ ⎢ ⎥ +12α 2 (α1 (4 − wq ) 2 − 2γ (α1 − α 2 )(2 + w)(2 − w − wq ))e2 ⎦ and 12γα 2 (α1 − α 2 )2 < ⎣ (2 + w) 2
2 ⎡ −(12γ (2 − q − wq) 2 α 2 + (1 − γ )(4 − wq) 2 (3 − 4 q − 2 w)α1 )e2 ⎤ ⎢ ⎥ 2 +12α 2 (α1 (4 − wq) − 2γ (α1 − α 2 )(2 + q )(2 − q − wq))e2 ⎦. 12γα 2 (α1 − α 2 ) 2 > ⎣ (2 + q ) 2

Since the left hand side terms are the same for both the inequalities, we can combine the two inequalities into a single inequality. This leads to the following condition that is true for any mixed strategy equilibrium for u > 0 :
( q − w)(4 − wq) ⎡ −[(1 − γ )(4 − wq)(20 − 2 q 2 − 2 w2 − 5q − 5w − 6 wq)α1 + 12γ (8 − w2 q − wq 2 − 6wq)α 2 ]e2 ⎤ ⎢ ⎥>0 (2 + w) 2 (2 + q) 2 ⎣ +12α 2 (α1 (4 − wq)(4 + w + q) − 2γ (2 + w)(2 + q)(α1 − α 2 )) ⎦

(A.29) In order for the term in the square brackets to be positive we should have e2 < 12α 2 (α1 (4 − wq)(4 + w + q) − 2γ (2 + w)(2 + q)(α1 − α 2 )) (1 − γ )(4 − wq)(20 − 2q 2 − 2 w2 − 5q − 5w − 6wq)α1 + 12γ (8 − w2 q − wq 2 − 6wq)α 2

(A.30)

Let X 1 = 12α 2 (α1 (4 − wq)(4 + w + q) − 2γ (2 + w)(2 + q)(α1 − α 2 )) and
Y1 = (1 − γ )(4 − wq)(20 − 2q 2 − 2 w2 − 5q − 5w − 6wq)α1 + 12γ (8 − w2 q − wq 2 − 6wq)α 2 .

38

We next show that inequality A.30 holds, i.e. e2 <

X1 . In a mixed strategy equilibrium when firm D offers a rebate, Y1 plugging in the optimal price and rebate values into equation A.2 we get u 1 ⎡ −[(1 − γ )(4 − wq )(3 + w − q )α1 + 6γ (2 + w)α 2 ]e2 ⎤ τ2 = − + ⎥ . Note that the first term of τ 2 is 6α 2 12α 2 (4 − wq )α ⎢ +6α 2 ( −α1 (4 − wq ) + γ (2 − w − wq )(α1 − α 2 )) ⎣ ⎦

negative when u > 0 . Thus for any τ 2 > 0 , the second term should be positive, i.e., solving for e2 we should have e2 <
6α 2 ( −(4 − wq)α1 + γ (2 − w − wq)(α1 − α 2 )) (1 − γ )(4 − wq)(3 + w − q)α1 + 6γ (2 + w)α 2

(A.31)

Let X 2 = 6α 2 ( −(4 − wq)α1 + γ (2 − w − wq)(α1 − α 2 )) and Y2 = (1 − γ )(4 − wq)(3 + w − q)α1 + 6γ (2 + w)α 2 . X X X Y − X 2Y1 > 0. Using this cutoff on e2 we will show that 1 < 2 , i.e. – since Y1 and Y2 are positive – 1 2 Y1 Y2 Y1Y2 Computing X 1Y2 − X 2Y1 we get
⎡ ((2 w − 39 wq + 4 q − 70 w − 8 + 6 w q + 2 wq − 7 w − 18q + 7 qw + 11wq + 2 w q )γ ⎤ ⎢ +16 − 4 w3 q + 16 w2 − 3wq 2 − 19 qw2 + 76 w − 6 w2 q 2 )α 2 ⎥ 1 ⎥ 6α 2 (4 − wq)((1 − γ ) ⎢ ⎢ + (42 q − 2 w3 q + 5qw2 − 4 q 2 + wq 2 − 2 w3 + 123wq + 142 w + 19 w2 − 2 wq 3 + 8 − 6 w2 q 2 )(1 − γ )γα1α 2 ⎥ ⎢ ⎥ ⎢ + ( qw2 + 6 w + wq 2 + 7 wq + 2 q + w2 )12γ 2α 22 ⎥ ⎣ ⎦
3 2 2 2 3 2 2 2 3

The above term is positive for all values of q ∈ (0,1) and w ∈ (0,1) . Thus the right hand side of inequality A.31 is larger than the right hand side of inequality A.30 indicating that inequality A.30 is satisfied for any feasible mixed strategy. Therefore, the value in the square brackets in inequality A.29 is positive. Since all other terms are also positive, we need to have q − w be strictly positive for A.29 to hold. Thus q > w if u > 0 . i.e., firm D offers a rebate with higher probability than firm A. QED

39

Similar Documents

Premium Essay

Consumer Cleaning Products Corporation

...1) In regards to recognizing the costs of a sales incentive, such as coupons, the Accounting Standards Codification (ASC) 605-50-25-3 states that, “a vendor shall recognize the cost of such a sales incentive at the later of the following: a. The date at which the related revenue is recognized by the vendor b. The date at which the sales incentive is offered” In this case, Consumer Cleaning Products Corporation (CCPC) had recognized revenue for over $2,000,000 by December 31, 2009. CCPC began releasing coupons concurrently with the detergent’s launch date of December 1, 2009; therefore, requirement (a) is the later of the two dates. All of the estimated coupon redemption of $20,000 should be expensed on December 31, 2009 which would fall within CCPC’s 2009 Income Statement. 2) According to ASC 605-50-25-4, “A vendor shall recognize a liability… based on the estimated amount of refunds or rebates that will be claimed by customers. However, if the amount of future rebates or refunds cannot be reasonably and reliably estimated, a liability (or deferred revenue) shall be recognized for the maximum potential amount of the refund or rebate.” The codification then states factors that make estimates unreliable including: “a. Relatively long periods in which a particular rebate or refund may be claimed b. The absence of historical experience with similar types of sales incentive programs with similar products or the inability to apply such experience because...

Words: 432 - Pages: 2

Free Essay

Comsumerism

...Consumerism: Using coupons to save money Gina York ENG102 May 23, 2012 Sarah Giragosian Consumerism: Using coupons to save money Consumers face daily struggles. However, many would say that the one thing they struggle with the most is how to find ways to stretch their paycheck enough to cover the bills and put food on the table. In fact, despite having two paychecks coming in, the average American family is still unable to make ends meet. While we can eliminate some things from our daily lives, such as the $5 cup of coffee at the local “Java Joe’s”, we cannot eliminate our daily need for food and basic necessities. Consequently, with the continued downturn in the economy, people have had to become more creative in finding ways to save money. Using coupons to aid in discounting products is widely becoming the method of choice. Consumers have had to make some very hard decisions based on income and necessities. We have all had to “tighten our belts” and “watch our pennies”. “During these hard economic times, many people are looking for new ways to save money on as many things as possible. Groceries, electric and other utility bills, as well as on other items like diapers and baby care supplies, cleaning supplies and paper products.” (How to Save Money With Grocery Coupons, 1999-2012) Along with the ever present thought of saving and keeping our hard earned dollars in mind, many have returned to the days of our grandmothers, known for saving their pennies. We realize that...

Words: 2111 - Pages: 9

Premium Essay

Ccpc

...Bright. Part of CCPC's marketing campaing was to "drop" appromixamatly 500,000 coupons in the Sunday newspaper where Fresh & Bright was sold. The coupon worked in the following way: The 500,000 coupons could be used through October 1, 2010. CCPC has data one six month coupons for other products but does not have any data on one year coupons for detergent. CCPC estimates that two percent of the detergent coupon will be redeemed. As of Septemeber 30, 2009 CCPC has sold $2,000,000 of Fresh & Bright. Issues 1. What is the accounting issue(s) and the relevant components of the autthoritative literature? 2. When should CCPC recognize the effects of the Fresh & Bright coupon donp in its financial statements? 3. What is the dollar amount of the effect of the Fresh & Bright coupon drop on CCPC's financial statement? 4. What would constiture "sufficient evidence" to support CCPC's expected redemtion rate of 2 percent?\ 5. What are the accounting implications if CCPC's estimated redemption rate changes to 2.5 percent at a later point in time? 6. How should the effects of the Fresh & Bright coupon drop be reflected in the income statement? 7. What are the necessard journal entries? Analysis Analysis of Issue 1: What is the accounting issue(s) and the relevant components of the authoritative literature? The accounting issues relevant to the case of CCPC is the correct recognition of coupons related to sales of detergant. Relevant components of the authoritative literature...

Words: 988 - Pages: 4

Free Essay

..Coupons

...How to Use Coupons Julie Rogers 04/04/2012 How to Coupon 1) Coupon Language a. Explanation of terms 2) Where to Get Coupons b. Places to find coupons 3) Organizing Your Coupons c. Helpful suggestions 4) Stacking Coupons d. How to maximize your coupons 5) Go To The Store e. Time to see 6) The Checkout Lane f. The experience of couponing How to use coupons Couponing is the technique of pairing up coupons with sales so you can get the best price on products you need.  There is a large range of couponers.  Some do it sporadically and others are extreme couponers.  To be a couponer yourself, you need to understand the basics of how to pair up store coupons and manufacturer coupon, if your store doubles coupons and how to hold on your coupons to use them at the best time. The coupon language is like a foreign language.  Here is a list of abbreviations, terms and definitions to help better understand the language used in couponing.  $$/$$ - This means $ off when you spend $ amount. $/# - This means that you get $ off for every # you buy. B1G1 = Buy One Get One Free Blinkie = A coupon that prints out at a machine in the store. They are located by the product associated with that particular coupon. BOGO = Buy One Get One Free CAT = Catalina. A coupon that prints out at the register that is either $$ off your next purchase or $$ off a certain product. Closeouts - These are typically greatly reduced...

Words: 1036 - Pages: 5

Premium Essay

Retail Marketing

...Part A 1. Coupons Coupons are the promotional tools that can be redeemed for discounts when purchasing goods and services. Normally the manufacturers, wholesalers, or retailers issue coupons to their customers through several ways like direct mail, email, and messages. By placing coupons in magazines or newspapers, the company can attract the potential customers to try its product, and they will continue to buy it if the customers like it. Current customers are delighted when they receive the coupons and the gift of savings from company of a product that they buy regularly. Coupons are the special offer and inexpensive form of marketing to persuade consumers to purchase the specific goods and services from specific companies. Due to these facts, the majority of companies would like to use some type of coupon program although competitors are doing it. Besides that, well-designed coupon programs help company to gain the competitive advantages and create brand awareness. For example, Tesco will send the coupons through email or attach in the newspaper to customers. Customers only need to print out or cut out, and present to the cashier when paying the discounted products. (Left) Tesco coupon sample 2. Rebates Rebates, like coupons, offer value to purchase typically by lowering the customer’s final cost for getting the product. Rebate is a type of sales promotion that marketers use primarily as incentives to product sales. Consumers benefit from the lower price...

Words: 2679 - Pages: 11

Premium Essay

Telecom

...~\C)I\ The Great Rebate Runaround Ah, the holiday shopping season: Santa Claus, reindeer-and rebate hell. Those annoying mail-in offers are everywhere these days. Shoppers hate col­ lecting all the paperwork, filling out the forms, and mailing it all in to claim their $10 or $100. But no matter how annoying rebates are for consumers, the country's retailers and manufacturers love them. From PC powerhouse Dell to national chains Circuit City and OfficeMax to the Listerine mouth­ wash sold at Rite Aid drugstores, rebates are prolifer­ ating. Nearly one-third of all computer gear is now sold with some form of rebate, along with more than 20% of digital cameras, camcorders, and LCD TVs, says market researcher NPD Group. Hal Stinchfield, a 30-year veteran of the rebate business, calculates that some 400 million rebates are offered each year. Their total face value: $6 billion, he estimates. Office-products retailer Staples says it and its vendors alone pay $3.5 million in rebates each week. TAX ON THE DISORGANIZED sees lower redemption rates during the Christmas shopping season, when consumers may be too dis­ tracted to file for rebates on time. Credit this bonanza for retailers and suppliers partly to human nature. Many consumers are just too lazy, forgetful, or busy to apply for rebates: Call it a tax on the disorganized. Others think the 50 cents, $50-or even $200---is just not worth the hassle of collecting. "I WAS FROSTED" Why the rage for rebates? The industry's...

Words: 2052 - Pages: 9

Premium Essay

Best Buy

...First off I want to say that this was a very interesting read because I actually saw Geek Squad in An Los Angles over the Christmas break inside a Best Buy and was very curious to what it was. Basically Geek Squad a group of highly trained technology agents that can you can bring electronics to be fix or they can come to you. They can now be found in some Best Buys and ware becoming very popular in our technology based society. The founder of Geek Squad Robert Stephens wanted to figure out a way to keep up with the fast pact advancement that our society is facing with technology in fact he called it “chaos”. When you think about it he has a good point. In our society now everything is technology based and with that being the case there are ways things that needs fixing or installed or something to that nature. Which is in fact why he created Geek Squad, he wanted to find away to off set the chaos caused by innovation. With innovation comes change and that effects not only is but our environment also. There are several environmental changes that helped open the door for Geek Squad to arise such as : the rise in broadband usage, viruses, maintenance management, social factors(demographics and culture), limited competition, the rise of our economy (more discretionary income) and many more. The changes in patterns in all consumers has had very big effect on why Best Buy wanted buy Greek Squad and also the impact of women purchasing patterns also made it a must do deal for Best...

Words: 1019 - Pages: 5

Free Essay

Week 4 Discussion Questions Math

...Which of the four operations on functions do you think is the easiest to perform? What is the most difficult? Explain why. The operation of adding function is easiest to perform because we can only combine like terms. If there are no other like terms within the operation that constant or variable remains as is. For example f(x) = 3x^2 + 1, g(x) = 3x +2. Solve (f+g)(x) = f(x) + g(x). (3x^2 + 1) + (3x + 2) = 3x^2+3x+1+2 = 3x^2 + 3x+ 3 In this equation 3x^2 and 3x, although similar are not alike so they cannot be combined. The most difficult operation to perform is multiplying functions because we also have to remember the properties of multiplying exponents. There is more work that has to be evaluated when it comes to multiplying functions. Is the compound interest formula—such as would be used to calculate a car loan—an example of a function? If yes, of what type of function is it an example? Why might you identify it with that type of function? Yes, a compound interest formula used to calculate a car loan is an example of a function. The compound interest formula is A = P(1 + r/n)^(nt) and would be considered an exponential function because P, r, and n are all fixed variables/ constants and t appears as the exponent which would be the changing variable. The function would then be written as A(t)= P(1 + r/n) ^ (nt) A= accumulated amount, t = the number of years, P = the beginning principal, r = the annual interest rate and n = the number of compounding periods...

Words: 653 - Pages: 3

Premium Essay

Great Rebate Round

...manufacturers might want to offer rebates rather than decrease wholesale price. Explain why this can be viewed as an example of customized pricing. Sol: Manufacturers will offer rebates instead of decreasing wholesale price because some people may not spend time on redeeming rebates by this, manufacturers can offer the rebate to those who really need and will redeem it and get the whole value from those who can spend money t and worry about getting the rebate. So, this will be the example of customized pricing as it customizes to both the Customers who bargain and those who are looking for the quality product without worrying about price. 2. Even if all rebates were redeemed, why might manufacturers still want to offer rebates rather than decrease wholesale prices? Sol: Manufacturers of the respected companies will be able to show their profits on their records and show that they have higher cash flow and rebates go as an expense on their records and this will raise their sales scale resulting in their stock value increase. Manufactures can also show records as a loss and can also get some tax exceptions on their overall profit. 3. Why do you suppose that Best Buy, rather than one of Best Buy's big suppliers such as Sony or Panasonic, is considering eliminating rebates? Sol: Best Buy don’t want to provide rebates on their products because they original price of Best Buy match the rebated price of other stores and by which, if they still add a rebate on top of their actual prices...

Words: 387 - Pages: 2

Premium Essay

The Great Rebate Runaround

...By Brian Grow Ah, the holiday shopping season: Santa Claus, reindeer -- and rebate hell. Those annoying mail-in offers are everywhere these days. Shoppers hate collecting all the paperwork, filling out the forms, and mailing it all in to claim their $10 or $100. But no matter how annoying rebates are for consumers, the country's retailers and manufacturers love them. From PC powerhouse Dell (DELL) to national chains Circuit City (CC) and OfficeMax (OMX) to the Listerine mouthwash sold at Rite Aid (RAD) drugstores, rebates are proliferating. Nearly one-third of all computer gear is now sold with some form of rebate, along with more than 20% of digital cameras, camcorders, and LCD TVs, says market researcher NPD Group. Hal Stinchfield, a 30-year veteran of the rebate business, calculates that some 400 million rebates are offered each year. Their total face value: $6 billion, he estimates. Office-products retailer Staples (SPLS) says it and its vendors alone pay $3.5 million in rebates each week. TAX ON THE DISORGANIZED. Why the rage for rebates? The industry's open secret is that fully 40% of all rebates never get redeemed because consumers fail to apply for them or their applications are rejected, estimates Peter S. Kastner, a director of consulting firm Vericours. That translates into more than $2 billion of extra revenue for retailers and their suppliers each year. What rebates do is get consumers to focus on the discounted price of a product, then buy it at full price...

Words: 1927 - Pages: 8

Premium Essay

1. Explain the Strategic Issues a Company Need to Address When Adding Clicks to Bricks

...channels to customer fulfillment to call centers. As a result, clients need to understand the overall impact and implications of the technology before a site goes live. Office supply giant Staples, for example, launched its Staples.com online site in early 1999, largely as an extension to its existing retail and catalog business. The expense associated with the Web effort pummeled the parent company's stock price and generated just an estimated $94 million in online revenue--about 1 percent of Staples' total 1999 revenue of $8.9 billion. Staples completely revamped the site in May, adding new search tools, small-business services and a streamlined checkout procedure. It has also promoted the site heavily in its existing stores and by offering rebates in newspaper advertisements to customers who move to the Web for their purchases. Multichannel retail — the merging of traditional brick-and-mortar retailing with online and mobile retail channels — involves far more than allowing customers to purchase items through a website. Multichannel retailing presents ample, seemingly boundless opportunities for brand engagement and interaction with customers across new platforms. Yet inevitably, these new technologies, platforms and sales channels come with new risks and challenges for companies to manage. With the growth of e-commerce, many retailers are using their websites to enhance their relationships with customers through offerings like live chats with service representatives and educational...

Words: 371 - Pages: 2

Free Essay

How to Coupon

...Where to Look for Coupons There are lots of coupons up for grabs, if you know where to find them. By far, the best places to look are: •Newspapers- the Smart Source and Valassis coupon inserts appear on a near-weekly basis. The Procter and Gamble insert appears at the start of each month •Magazines- women's publications such as Woman's Day, Red Book, Family Circle and Good Housekeeping frequently carry manufacturer coupons •In store- look for coupons on store shelves, on products and on the back of your receipts. Also look for coupons to print out at the register Additional places to look: •Online- look to free grocery coupon sites for loads of printable coupons. Not all stores take them; but if yours does, you’re in luck •Junk mail- high-value manufacturer coupons have started to appear in junk mailers, so be sure to look before you toss •Direct from the manufacturer- check manufacturer websites for printable coupons or contact companies (by mail, e-mail or phone) to request coupons •Store mailings- get a frequent shopper card for the grocery stores that you shop, and you may be rewarded with special coupon mailings •On products- look in and on the packaging of the products that you buy for special loyalty coupons How to Keep Coupons Organized There are lots of ways to organize coupons; the key is to find the approach that works best for you. Three options to consider: •Clipping out all coupons •Clipping out just the coupons that you intend to...

Words: 491 - Pages: 2

Premium Essay

Marketing

...Clue, The Game of LIFE, Scrabble or Monopoly games was 12.99 - 18.99 50 OFF % ALL Hot Wheels kid picks reg. 0.99- 32.99 ea. Discounted item must be of equal or lesser value to the lowest priced item purchased. BUY 1 GET 1 Sale 9.09 - 13.29 ea. 236985, 231967, 236772, 236888, 231215, 033480 FREE $10Gift Card when you buy ANY TWO Similac 8 oz. 24 pks. ready-to-feed formula In store only. Quantities limited; no rain checks. Gift card valid on your next purchase. Offer expires 9/6/10. See back of card for Terms & Conditions. Valid 9/3 - 9/6/10 $ 10 Save 30% ALL CAT 15" trucks To redeem online, enter promotional code #940520 at checkout. Online offer may vary. One coupon per guest. Not valid with any other “R”Us offer for same item or on prior purchases. Coupon must be surrendered at time of purchase and value is forfeited if item is returned. We reserve the right to limit quantities. Void where 5 prohibited. Valid USA only. Cash value 1/100 of 1¢. CPN ITEM #940520 00009 40520 7 3-DAY SALE: Quantities limited; no rain checks. Selection varies by store. Please check your local Babies“R”Us/Toys“R”Us or online for availability. Offers valid in USA only. 1 Save $20 ALL Radio Flyer My 1st Scooters Sale 29.99 ea. was 49.99 Helmets and pads sold separately. 50 OFF % ALL Nickelodeon DVDs reg. 6.99 - 29.99 ea. In store only. Discounted item must be of equal or lesser value to the lowest priced item purchased. BUY 1 GET 1 Save...

Words: 1082 - Pages: 5

Premium Essay

E-Marketing

...in five smart phone users over the age of 18 redeemed a mobile coupon and it is estimated that one out of three smart phone users will redeem coupon sent to their mobile phone in 2013 (eMarketer, 2011). With the online direction customers are taking in recent years and the tremendous forecasted growth to come; online couponing can be a beneficial marketing tool for companies. Accessibility has a huge part to play in mobile coupon initiatives. Looking back five years ago, we drove to the nearest convenient store to pick up a paper (or some of us had it delivered) and took time sorting through loads of coupons that meant nothing to searching ones that had value to us. Current technology allows companies to track purchases and identify specific consumer interests. In this way, companies have a better understanding of their customer’s wants, needs and values and can target specific categories that interest different types of consumers. This comes as huge value to businesses giving a sharp edge to speaking the consumer’s language. Online couponing can be labeled as a more sustainable objective as it eliminates paper waste, reduces cost in production and distributions, and can be directed towards target audiences. Distribution times are dramatically affected as well as getting the coupon in the customer’s hands faster. Mostly all coupons have an expiration date associated with them. Even when only clipping coupons that will be used, many go to waste due to the expiration date...

Words: 532 - Pages: 3

Premium Essay

Hard and Soft Technology

...other capital goods (Export Help, n.d.). A hard technology used by the Dollar General Company in the domestic environment is the digital coupon program. “On July 31, 2014 Dollar General, in partnership with Coupons.com, completed the successful rollout of its new Dollar General Digital Coupons program to its more than 11,300 stores across 40 states” (Cross, 2014). Another hard technology used by Dollar General is the workforce management system. This program assists in managing the labor hours, adjusting during forecasted busier hours and less personnel during expected lulls (Retail Information System News, 2011). A soft technology can be characterized as the use of the programs, personnel and hard technology, such as marketing, administrative procedures and finance (Export Help, n.d.). In 2011 Dollar General introduced a soft technology domestically and globally, with the incorporation of the e-commerce to boost sales over a greater distance (Retail Information System News, 2011). The technology barriers for Dollar General in the domestic and global environments encountered to introduce the digital coupon program and the workforce management system were limited to the hardware required at the store locations and internet capability for the customers to be able to click on the coupons of their choice. The strategy used to initiate the coupon program was to supply 11,300 stores across the 40 states with the required hard technology (Dollar General, 2014). This type of technology...

Words: 515 - Pages: 3