Free Essay

Npa in Indian Bank

In:

Submitted By ashis89
Words 19466
Pages 78
Determinants of NPAs in the Indian Public Sector Banks: A Critique of Policy Reforms
Dr. Pradip Kumar Biswas* and Ashis Taru Deb** The paper analyzes the process leading to formation and perpetuation of high levels of NPAs in Indian Public Sector Banks (PSBs). It distinguishes between random and non-random reasons of NPA formation in PSBs. It points out that a high degree of arbitrariness is involved in defining NPAs as it fails to capture diversity in terms of the seasonal and cyclical nature of the economic activities in India. The study conceptualizes random reasons for default in a simplified framework of a Poisson process. It then argues that the non-random reasons go beyond the conventional paradigm of interim, ex-ante and ex-post information asymmetries and incomplete contracts. It points out that the financial notion of NPA as a mere risk phenomenon is inadequate, because a number of reasons leading to non-random generation of NPA are related to the dimension of uncertainty. It highlighted that the use of a secondary asset market may take care of NPA problem, but it requires a number of conditions for its use, which hardly exist in India. The study observes a number of reasons for generation of NPAs which are important and peculiar to India. This is followed by a critical evaluation of the series of policy measures that have been adopted to improve the NPA scenario since liberalization. While one set of policies granting greater autonomy to the PSBs are proved to be quite effective in restricting formation of fresh NPAs, the other set of policies designed to recover loans, after default, have failed to deliver the goods. Finally, it concludes by making an assessment of the existing institutions and highlights the fact that the incidence of NPA is as much due to the malfunctioning of the banking institutions as due to the external institutional environment.

Section I
Introduction
The severity of the incidence of Non-Performing Assets (NPAs) in Indian PSBs, noted in the early 1990s, raised a severe hue and cry in various quarters. In fact, the problem started much earlier, which became evident from continued recapitalization of many PSBs since 1985-861. Whatever be the root
* Reader, Department of Economics, College of Vocational Studies (University of Delhi), Sheikh Sarai Phase II, New Delhi-110 017, Ph. 0120-2638618 (R), 011-33032388 (M), e-mail: pradipdelhi@sify.com ** Senior Lecturer, Department of Economics, College of Vocational Studies (University of Delhi), Sheikh Sarai Phase II, New Delhi 110 017, Ph. 011-25531684 (R), 9868031042 (M), e-mail: mrashishdev@now-india.net.in Acknowledgement: The authors are grateful to A D P Garg, K V Bhanu Murthy, Krishna Kumar, A J C Bose and Nandini Guha for help. However, usual disclaimers apply.
1

Over a period from 1985-86 to 2000-2001, the government has contributed Rs 20,046 cr towards recapitalization of PSBs. See Mathur (2002), p. 2246.

© 2004 IUP. All Rights Reserved.
Determinants of NPAs in the Indian Public Sector Banks: A Critique of Policy Reforms 15

cause, malfunctioning of the PSBs increased by the end of the 1980s. This led to the setting up of the Narasimham Committee (1991), which, in fact, identified NPA as one of the possible causes/effects of the malfunctioning of the PSBs. In order to quantify the NPA problem, Narasimham Committee made it mandatory on the part of the banks to publish annually the magnitude of NPAs. NPAs are those categories of assets (advances, bills discounted, overdraft, cash credits etc.) for which any amount remains due for a period of 180 days.2 Following the recommendations, banks started publishing in their annual reports NPA data, which were astonishingly high. RBI (1999) report on NPA stated that reduction in NPA should be treated as a ‘national priority’. In the Task Force3 report on NPAs in the Indian financial system, it is argued that three NPA-ridden banks (UCO Bank, United Bank of India and Indian Bank) are open sores threatening the health of the entire financial system. The report went to the extent of stating that these banks were not viable candidates either for privatization or for merger, and thus they should be closed down. The Verma Committee (1999), on the other hand, felt that these three banks could be revived if they submit themselves to the discipline of a rigorous restructuring, underpinned with adequate infusion of funds and simultaneous relief from the load of NPA and excess manpower.4 The difference in the respective recommendations has provoked protests of varying orders of frenzy, from the unionized employees. The unions have argued that the banks have been the victims of the wilful default5 by large corporate borrowers. Numerous studies regarding NPAs started pouring in. However, empirical works on NPA problems of commercial banks are inadequate. Rajaraman, Bhaumik and Bhatia (1999) attempted to examine NPA variations across Indian commercial banks. The findings show that the bank specific characteristics such as ownership or adherence to prudential norms do not suffice to explain inter-bank variations in NPAs. The region of operation however matters. This is a very significant contribution to understanding of the phenomenon and the steps to tackle it. The policy implications of the results of the paper are that sustainable reform in the financial sector and improvement in the performing efficiency of domestic banks require improvement in the enforcement environment in some regions of the country. The regional exposure effect would be more transparently evident were banks to report NPAs by state or region instead of merely as a national average as at present. The operating environment matters particularly in the Indian context where there are externally imposed compulsions on banks to enter into and operate in difficult regions. The environmental limits on bank operations cannot be tackled by reforms at bank level alone as will be discussed in a section below. Another paper by Rajaraman and Vasishth (2002) performed panel regression on NPA data of 27 PSBs covering a five year period from 1995-96 to 1999-2000. Among banks with higher than average NPAs, the exercise identifies two groups. In one case, high level of NPAs is explained by poor operating efficiency and in the other case, the operating indicator does not suffice to explain the high level of NPAs and leaves an unexplained intercept shift.
2 3 4

5

For details, see The Narasimham Committee (1991), p. 57. This Task Force was appointed by the Confederation of Indian Industries in March, 1999. The committee further felt that if the restructuring strategy failed to produce the desired results, only then other measures such as closure and/or privatization could be considered. The RBI has defined wilful default as non-payment of dues despite having adequate cash flow and net worth. Signs of siphoning of funds by the borrower, falsification of records, disposal of securities without bank’s approval, fraudulent practices etc., point out to a default situation. See Madhvendra P Das, The Economic Times, March 9, 1999, p. 14.

16

The IUP Journal of Bank Management, August 2004

Surprisingly, very few serious attempts have been made to find out the causes or determinants of the NPAs in Indian banks. Without such a study, policy recommendations and measures to contain NPAs would not be of much use, as evident from the continued poor performance of PSBs in spite of ten years of reforms. The present study makes an attempt to fill up such a gap. Once the root causes of NPAs are identified, one can evaluate the policies and find the lacuna therein in order to understand why the pace of improvement in the NPA scenario has been so slow.

Plan of the Paper
Section II discusses the severity of the NPA problem, as highlighted by various scholars and RBI. Section III discusses some conceptual issues that would help understand the determinants of NPAs of PSBs. It focuses on NPAs as an ordinary aspect of banking activity and clarifies that high NPA, so far as it is associated with high profits, does not pose any serious problem for the banks. It also discusses the limits to which banks can adjust to the NPAs problem. It further analyses the factors leading to formation of NPAs in the Indian PSBs. In this regard, alternative hypotheses have been put forward and investigated. In the light of the above analysis, Section IV critically evaluates the series of policy measures that have been adopted to improve the NPA scenario since liberalization. Finally, Section V concludes by making an assessment of the existing institutions and highlights the fact that the incidence of NPAs is as much due to the malfunctioning of the banking institutions as due to the external institutional environment.

Section II
Severity of NPA problem in the Indian PSBs
NPA data on PSBs are being published since the implementation of the recommendations of the Narasimham Committee. The Committee observed that banks were not following a uniform practice in respect of income recognition, valuation of investments as well as provisioning against doubtful assets. It further observed that a proper system of income recognition and provisioning was fundamental to the preservation of the strength and stability of the banking system.6 It was noted that PSBs accumulated NPAs using the cover of an archaic banking law which permitted banks to show revenue in their balance sheets whenever accrual of interest became due and not necessarily when the interest was realized. However, real profit bearing lies in realization of interest from credit extended and not accrual of interest. In order to comprehend the current situation of the banks, the Committee suggested a classification of assets into the following broad categories: Standard, substandard, doubtful and loss assets, that is, according to the quality of the assets. “Broadly stated substandard assets would be those which exhibit problems and would include assets classified as NPAs for a period not exceeding two years. Doubtful assets are those NPAs which remain as such for a period exceeding two years and would also include loans in respect of which installments are overdue for a period exceeding two years. Loss assets are accounts where loss has been identified but the amounts have not been written off.”7 Excepting the standard assets category, the other asset categories come under NPAs. The Committee defined NPA as an advance where, as on balance sheet date:
6 7

Narasimham Committee (1991), p. 54. Ibid, p. 56.

Determinants of NPAs in the Indian Public Sector Banks: A Critique of Policy Reforms

17

• In respect of term loans, interest remains past due for a period of more than 180 days. • In respect of overdrafts and cash credits, accounts remain out of order for a period of more than 180 days. • In respect of bills purchased and discounted, the bill remains overdue and unpaid for a period of 180 days. • In respect of other accounts, any amount to be received remains past due for a period of more than 180 days. This definition will be changed in 2003-04, when the duration of non-receipt of loan servicing for classification as non-performing has to be reduced from two quarters to one quarter (i.e. 90 days) following international norms8. A time series data on NPA is available since 1992-93 onwards. After 2002-03, there would be comparability problems because of changes in the definition of NPAs mentioned above.

Current Anomalies in Defining an NPA
There is a high degree of arbitrariness involved in defining NPAs so far as the duration of no-payment is concerned. The uniform norm of repayment of dues for 180 days (now 90 days) fails to capture diversity in terms of the seasonal and cyclical nature of the economic activities in India. For example, the agricultural cycle from sowing to harvesting and selling at a reasonable price (including some storage time) may extend more than 90 days. It may happen that selling crops immediately after the harvest in order to repay loans within 90 days may fetch a much lower price and the revenue may be lower than the loan amount. A sizeable part of the manufacturing activities is seasonal in nature, their products are sold in particular season like summer or winter, and thus the manufacturers cannot repay their dues throughout the year. In fact, the lean season may extend to more than 180 days. Further, in current banking practice, interest is fixed and applied from the first month and is also required to be served by the borrower in the month end. If the project has a longer gestation lag, the amount will turn to be NPA much before the project becomes operational. The current practice of fixing interest and defining NPA may induce more NPA. An analysis of NPA over time is constrained by quality of the data, changes in definitions and composite criteria as regards gross or net and varied quality of assets. Many of the interior branches of the banks are not properly audited. In addition to that, NPAs are not a homogenous category. Within NPAs there are various types of assets and relative changes in them are also important. Further, NPAs do not include default in interest payment or principal on privately placed debt9.

Choice of Gross or Net NPAs
For the present study, relevant data on NPA are collected from various issues of Report on Trend and Progress in Indian Banking. Aggregate data are available since 1993 and bank-wise data are available since 1995-96. It reports gross NPAs/gross advances, net NPAs/net advances, gross NPA/total assets and net NPAs/total assets. Net NPAs are obtained from gross NPA after deduction of the following: • Balances in interest suspense account i.e. interest due but not received; • Claims received from credit guarantors and kept in suspense accounts pending final settlement; • Part payments received and kept in suspensions; and •
8 9

Total provisions held (Report on Trend and Progress of Banking in India 1996-97; p.13).

See RBI, Annual Report 2001, reporting a policy announcement made on April 19, 2001. In the year 2000, RBI has issued draft guidelines which state that any default in payment of interest or principal in bank investments in privately-placed debt will have to be treated by the banks as NPAs. See Mayur Shetty, The Economic Times, April 6, 2000, p. 1.

18

The IUP Journal of Bank Management, August 2004

Similarly, gross advances consist of bills purchased and discounted, cash credits, overdrafts and loans and term loans, whereas net advance is calculated by netting out bills rediscounted, DICGC claims etc., from gross advance. It is interesting to note that banks will try to show a lower net NPA figure irrespective of gross NPA magnitude because net NPA below a stipulated level has been made one of the requirements for granting autonomy to PSBs. Rajaraman et al (2002) argued that gross NPA is a better indicator than net NPAs since the former does not incorporate the endogenous provisioning process. This is because banks make provisioning for NPAs according to their capacities. Hence, two banks with same gross NPAs may be able to show different levels of net NPAs10. On the other hand, two banks may show nearly the same net NPA figures when their gross NPA figures are different. Clearly one may not get a true picture of NPA from net NPA figures. They will have to be supplemented by gross NPA figures.

Dilemma of Relating NPAs to Advances or Assets
The severity of the incidence of NPA can be understood in relation to other variables like assets or advances. The ratio would help understand changes in the intensity over time and the variation of the intensity across banks and other financial institutions. Even, a cross-country comparison is also possible. There is some disagreement about what to be used as numerator and denominator for constructing a ratio to capture satisfactorily, the intensity of the NPA problem. The ratio used by the policy makers to judge the extent of the NPA problem of a bank is net NPA/net advances as it is internationally recognized Rajaraman et al (2002) have taken NPAs as a percent of gross/net advances rather than as a percent of total assets. They argue that the former is a post-facto measure of failure to judge credit risk, whereas the latter is a measure of threat to solvency posed by that misjudgement. A similar view was also expressed by Mukherjee (2003). She, however, preferred to use the ratio of NPA to advances for Indian banks. It is argued that such a measure will enable the bank to have an idea about what proportion of its lending is paid off. It is further argued that considering only the NPA to total assets ratio may underestimate the problem of NPA. This is because, in India, NPAs constitute a very small proportion of total assets, as loans and advances are around 40% of the total assets. However, in banking circles, it is argued that the international norm relates the NPA ratio to assets and not to advances. If NPAs are expressed as a ratio of assets, it allows the decomposition of the figure into substandard, doubtful and loss assets. This would throw more light on quality of assets.12 It does not appear to be easy to settle for one ratio against the other, as a measure of the NPA problem. The use of NPA as a ratio of advances is not free from problems. It may be argued that an asset, which has been degenerated into NPA in the current year, may relate to either advances made in the current year or to advances made in the earlier years. Clearly, NPA and advances relate to different periods of time. Hence, use of both the gross NPAs/ gross advances and net NPAs/ net advances do not appear to be very meaningful. On the other hand, as argued earlier, NPA as a proportion of assets is an underestimation of the problem. However, in order to get a holistic picture, it may be necessary to use all the four ratios. It may be mentioned that correlations between these four indicators of NPA in different years are highly significant over the relevant years.
10

11 12

For example, in 1995-96, net NPA/total asset ratios of State Bank of Mysore and Indian Overseas Bank, State Bank of Indore and UCO Bank were between 3.5 and 4.5%, but their gross NPA to total asset ratios varied between 7 to 12%. On the other hand, State Bank of Patiala and Union Bank of India had gross NPA ratio of 4.8% and 4.6% respectively, but their net NPA ratios were 2.62 and 6.1% in the same year. Report on Trend and Progress of Banking in India 1996-97, p. 13. Joshi, P N (2000) ‘NPAs: How Do We Tackle Them’? The Economic Times, July 11, p. 9.

Determinants of NPAs in the Indian Public Sector Banks: A Critique of Policy Reforms

19

Table 1: Gross and Net NPAs of PSBs ( amounts in Rs/crores)
End Gross Gross March NPAs Advance (1) As a % of (2) (3) 23.2 24.8 19.5 18 17.8 16 15.9 14 12.4 11.1 9.4 (1) as a % of Total Assets (4) 12 11 8.7 8.2 7.8 7 6.7 6 5.3 4.9 4.2 Net Net (5) NPAs Advance As a % of (2) (5) (6) (7) (6) Increment Increment as a in Gross in Gross % of NPAs Adv. Total Assets (8) (9) (10) (9) As Gross a % of minus (10) net NPA (11) (12)

(1) 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 39,253 41,041 38,385 41,661 43,577 45,653 51,710 53,033 54,672 56,473 54,086

(2) 169,194 165,488 196,846 231,450 244,214 284,971 325,328 379,461 442,134 509,368 577,813

17,567 18,297 20,285 21,232 24,211 26,187 27,977 27,958 24,963

164,178 205,584 220,922 260,459 297,789 352,714 415,207 480,681 549,351

11 8.9 9.2 8.2 8.1 7.4 6.7 5.8 4.5

4 3.6 3.6 3.3 3.1 2.9 2.7 2.4 1.9

1,788 -2,656 3,276 1,916 2,076 6,057 1,323 1,639 1,801 -2,387

-3,706 31,358 34,604 12,764 40,757 40,357 54,133 62,673 67,234 68,445

-48.25 -8.47 9.47 15.01 5.09 15.01 2.44 2.62 2.68 -3.49

20,818 23,364 23,292 24,421 27,499 26,846 26,695 28,515 29,123

Source: RBI website: www.rbi.org.in

NPA Levels for PSBs
Taking advantage of loopholes in the old banking law, PSBs developed enough laxity to accumulate a large volume of NPAs. It is clear from the figures of NPAs that are available for each year since 1993. Gross NPAs in the PSBs have increased rapidly from Rs 39,000 cr in 1993 to Rs 54,000 cr in 2003 as shown in Table 1. It grew at a rate of around 5% per annum during the period excepting the last year when it declined. Sheer size of NPA and its growth rate over the greater part of the 1990s indicate the ill health of the Indian public sector banks. In the year 1994, it was found that almost a quarter of the total volume of existing advances made by these banks remained non-performing. After implementations of the Narasimham Committee Report, banks could no longer show interest on an accrual basis but it had to make provisioning from its income while granting of advances. This led to a situation in which a large number of the PSBs started reporting negative profit in 1992-93. Banks fulfilling certain conditions were allowed to write off these losses against their capital. This called for recapitalization of these banks. Further, recapitalization was required to a large extent in order to write off bad debts. The total bad debt written off by 27 PSBs in 1997-98 was Rs 2,800 cr.13 A number of profitable Indian PSBs recorded huge increases in bad debt write offs in 1998-99 as compared to previous years.14 One more compelling reason for recapitalization was to enter into capital market15. Since the beginning of banking reforms in the early 80s, the government has contributed Rs 20,046 cr towards recapitalization and allowed banks to write off Rs 3,978 cr. Clearly, in the pre-reform era, when provisioning was not done, the profits of PSBs were overstated in their accounts. However, it is interesting to note that recapitalization started as early as 1985-86, as noted by Mathur (2002). This is indicative of the

13

14 15

See M K Venu. “Sharp increase in write offs by banks, financial institutions”, The Economic Times, March 15, 1999, p. 1. M K Venu, Banks Speed Up Loan Clean Up in 1999, The Economic Times, December 1999 23, p. 18. Mathur (2000), p. 2248.

20

The IUP Journal of Bank Management, August 2004

Table 2: Asset Classification Based on Quality (Amount in Rs/crores)
Year 1 Standard 2 SubAssets standard Assets 3 Doubtful 4 Loss Assets Assets Total Assets 1 As % 2 As % of Total of Total Assets Assets 3 As % of Total Assets 4 As % of Total Assets

1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 Growth Rate (%) 1993-2003

130087 124580 158967 189660 200637 239318 273618 326783 387360 452862 523724

12552 12163 7758 9299 12471 14463 16033 16361 14745 15788 14909

20106 23317 22913 24707 26015 25819 29252 30535 33485 33658 32340

393 4073 3732 4351 5090 5371 6425 6398 6544 7061 6840

163138 164133 193370 228017 244213 284971 325328 380077 442134 509369 577813

76.8 75.2 80.6 82.0 82.2 84.0 84.1 86.0 87.6 88.9 90.6

7.4 7.4 3.9 4.0 5.1 5.1 4.9 4.3 3.3 3.1 2.6

11.9 14.1 11.6 10.7 10.6 9.1 9.0 8.0 7.6 6.6 5.6

2.3 2.4 1.9 1.9 2.1 1.9 2.0 1.7 1.5 1.4 1.2

15.86

4.85

5.15

19.04

14.24

Source: RBI website: rbi.org.in

malfunctioning of the banks which started much before Narasimham Committee and continued throughout the 90s. Over the years bank advances increased much faster rate than that of NPAs and thereby reduced the share of gross NPA in gross advances to 14% by the end of the decade and close to 9% in 2003. In terms of total assets of these banks, it was found that around 11% of these assets were nonperforming in 1994, this ratio however substantially declined to 6% in 2000 and close to 4% in 2003. This happened not because of the substantial recovery of NPA but due to a rapid increase in bank advances and assets. Further, as shown in Table 1, increment of gross NPAs was quite high throughout the period under consideration, excepting in 1995 and 200316. This, in other words, shows that the volume of fresh defaults far exceeded the recovery in these years. A closer look at the NPAs would reveal that a majority of these assets are doubtful, i.e., for which installments are due for a period exceeding two years (Table 2). Assets under this category increased from Rs. 23,000 cr to Rs. 30,000 cr between 1994 and 2000. Share of these assets in total assets however declined from 14.1% to 8% during this period along with a rapid increase in the later. It may be argued that a parametric shift has taken place in the distribution of NPAs held by different PSBs (Table 3). A statistically significant fall is observed in the means and variances of all the four measures of NPAs during the period 1995-96 to 2002-03.17 However, it remains to be seen to what extent these NPA ratios are accommodated within the banking system. (See Table 4)
16

17

For instance, PSBs recovered around Rs 500 cr in 2002-03 under the Act of Securitisation and Reconstruction of Financial Assets and Enforcement of Security Interest (SARFAESI). See RBI website. Difference in the mean ratios of NPAs of PSBs (using t-test) for the years 2002-03 and 1995-96 is found to be significantly negative. Similarly, F- test is used to test variance ratio which indicated a decline of the variance in the later period.

Determinants of NPAs in the Indian Public Sector Banks: A Critique of Policy Reforms

21

Table 3: NPA Distribution Across Sectors (Rs/crores)
Year Priority Sector Gross NPA 19208 19106 20776 21184 22606 23715 24156 25139 24938 3.88 Non-Priority Sector Gross NPA Public Sector Gross NPA 1316 1411 1461 1362 1496 1055 1711 1116 1087 -2.32 Total Gross NPA Share of Priority Sector NPA in Total (%) 50 48.3 47.7 46.4 43.7 44.5 45.4 44.5 47.2 Share of Non-priority Sector NPA in Total (%) 46.5 48.2 49 50.6 53.4 53.5 51.4 53.5 50.7 Share of Public Sector NPA in Total (%) 3.4 3.6 3.3 3 2.9 2 3.2 2.0 2.1

1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 Growth Rate 1995-2003 (%)

17861 19067 21340 23107 27608 28524 27307 30251 26781 6.38

38385 39584 43577 45653 51710 53294 53174 56506 52807 4.95

Source: RBI website: www.rbi.org.in

Table 4: Trends in the Ratios of Gross NPA to Gross Advances Across Nationalized Banks
Banks State Bank of India State Bank of Bikaner & Jaipur State Bank of Hyderabad State Bank of Indore State Bank of Mysore State Bank of Patiala State Bank of Saurashtra State Bank of Travancore Allahabad Bank Andhra Bank Bank of Baroda Bank of India Bank of Maharashtra Canara Bank Central Bank of India Corporation Bank Dena Bank Indian Bank Indian Overseas Bank Oriental Bank of Commerce Punjab & Sind Bank Punjab National Bank Syndicate Bank Uco Bank United Bank of India Union Bank of India Vijaya Bank All Nationalized Banks 1995-1996 15.96 12.45 17.89 14.2 14.54 11.49 13.5 11.74 23.98 11.61 16.16 14.49 21.87 17.93 23.91 9.67 14.7 34.15 22.59 5.68 27.7 18.74 20.97 24.54 10.38 38 20.36 18.0 1996-1997 16.02 13.83 19.19 15.81 16.92 11.32 14.79 14.49 23.93 11.81 17.15 11.78 20.67 20.26 25 9.92 15.1 39.12 15.8 7.36 30.71 16.31 19.32 28.35 10.38 36.2 18.73 17.8 1997-1998 1998-1999 14.14 11.73 18.96 15.05 17.47 11.88 14.83 20.06 23.18 9.86 14.63 11.55 17.39 18.69 20.47 7.6 13.73 38.96 13.38 6.16 26.79 14.5 15.31 24.04 11.18 33.5 15.21 16.0 15.56 16.11 15.94 14.68 16.96 13.98 15.43 18.46 20.09 9.42 16.03 11.87 15.97 18.32 17.41 5.66 12.37 38.70 13.32 6.3 23.01 14.12 10.72 22.55 12.41 32.38 13.65 15.9 1999-2000 2000-2001 14.25 16.15 14.18 10.8 13.89 10.99 13.71 14.43 19.07 7.83 14.73 12.9 12.65 10.42 16.63 5.39 18.15 32.77 13.18 5.54 15.27 13.19 7.74 18.79 12.27 27.6 11.52 14.0 12.93 12.91 14.08 9.16 12.83 9.66 14.57 11.38 17.66 6.13 14.11 10.25 12.35 7.48 16.06 5.4 25.31 21.76 11.81 5.21 18.45 11.71 7.87 11.64 11.2 21.51 10 12.4 2001-2002 2002-2003 11.95 9.85 10.08 7.18 12.07 6.94 10.18 9.41 16.94 5.26 12.39 9.37 10.44 6.22 14.70 5.19 24.11 17.86 11.35 6.57 18.19 11.38 8.38 9.59 10.77 16.16 9.39 11.1 9.34 8.15 7.28 5.53 10.14 4.8 7.32 6.67 13.65 4.89 11.02 8.55 9.55 5.96 13.06 5.27 17.86 12.39 10.29 6.94 19.25 11.58 8.32 8.24 8.96 12.15 6.18 9.4

Source: RBI, Report on Trends and Progress of banking in India, Mumbai, various issues.

22

The IUP Journal of Bank Management, August 2004

Section III
Determinants of NPAs: Some Conceptual and Empirical Issues
In a layman’s perception, NPA formation in a bank is paradoxical.18 Unlike moneylenders, who on several occasions lend money without any collateral, the advances made by the banks are generally backed by some kind of collateral, which can be liquidated in case of default. This collateral is in fact insisted on while making an advance to guard against the possibility of default. But, the problem arises in several cases of default when some of these collaterals could not be acquired or liquidated by the bank to realize the loss involved. This inability was primarily due to institutional constraints, such as inappropriate legal framework, political interference or the general non-compliance attitude of the borrowing community. In addition to that, the existence of inadequately formed asset market might have aggravated the problem further. High transaction costs of operating in such a market also may be another reason. Even if we accept that NPA is a fact of life, so far as banking practices are concerned, then ideally there should be no reason why one should be worried about it. A bank can obtain the desired rate of return through properly adjusting the rate of interest on different categories of loans/advances in accordance with their risk profile.19 If the sample size is large enough for different categories of advances, which is in fact true for most of the Indian PSBs, the realized return, and desired return on the total asset of the bank would coincide.20 The loss due to NPA would exactly be compensated by higher interest earning in specific risk categories. In other words, high incidence of NPA need not necessarily affect the profitability of the bank. In fact, both can go together. This is because high profits can be earned only at the cost of facing high risk i.e. generating high NPA. There is no problem with a moderate NPA as it can be taken care of by differential rates of interest on advances made to different sectors. However, there is a limit to which the rate of interest can be increased in order to reflect the high profile of an asset category. If NPA becomes very high, it will be difficult to deal with its aftermath by means of an increase in rate of interest.21 A rise in the rate of interest may go against the central bank’s dictum. It may also lead to adverse selection (Akerlof, 1970). If the increment in the rate of interest were very high, the problem would be aggravated by further increase in default. This occurs through two routes. Firstly, at a high rate of interest, a section among borrowers borrows with an intention to default. Secondly, an increase in the probability of default

18 19

20

21

See Venkitaraman, ‘Myth and reality’, The Economic Times, January 6, 1999, p. 9. It may be pointed out that such an attempt was not possible during pre-deregulatory phase when interest rates on deposits and loans were fully administered. Even after deregulation, there exist ceilings or floors of interest rate on several types of loans. Suppose the bank’s desired rate of return be w from lending of A1, A2, A3, ...,Ak amounts of loans to k categories of borrowers, where A I +A 2+A 3+...+A k =A.The bank’s desired growth of capital after t years=A(1+w)t -A. Probability of default for different category of borrowers = dI, where I = 1, 2, ..k. The rate of interest for different categories of loans = rI , where I = 1, 2, ..k.The bank’s expected growth of capital after t-th year = Σ I (1- dI) AI (1+ r I)t– A. This holds good or is realized for large samples. For given w and d I, by suitably fixing rI , the desired growth of capital would be equal to the expected and realized growth. For instance, if the deposit rate of interest is 5%, the default rate (of loan amount) is 6% and the operational cost is 2% of the current deposit, the bank has to raise the lending rate to 13% (assuming all the deposit is used for lending) even to operate without profit. Under the present condition of lending rate in the market, SLR and CRR (and interest rate on investment), 6% default is too high to manage.

Determinants of NPAs in the Indian Public Sector Banks: A Critique of Policy Reforms

23

would take place because individuals take more risk when the interest rate is higher. One may add that if the demand for loans is inelastic, raising the rate of interest may not reduce the demand for credit. It may create a category of genuine defaulters whose margin is squeezed. This poses a limit to the use of the tool of raising the interest rate to overcome NPA problems.22 In case of large NPA accumulation by a bank, it may also react by decreasing its exposure to the particular sector generating high NPA and changing its composition of advances. However, this is also not without problems. With change in the composition of advances and increase in advances to non-risky sectors, rate of interest offered to these sectors will fall. This is currently happening to Indian banks, which, when faced with NPAs originating from industries affected by recession, are increasing their investment in government securities on the one hand23 and wooing the household sector with lower interest rate on personal loans on the other. However, apart from ceiling on interest rate or statutory restrictions on interest rates for some categories of loans irrespective of their risk profile, there may exist genuine problems of estimation of risks. Risks may not be time independent. They vary with the changes in overall business conditions. They may increase with economic slowdown and decrease with economic upturn. In addition to this there may also exist the problem of moral hazard or intentional default, principal agency problems where managers satisfy their own interest without considerations to the depositors/shareholders, political intervention and contagious effects in case of non-recovery, and all this may aggravate the problem of NPA. In fact, many of these factors proved very critical for the Indian PSBs, raising the NPA to an alarming level. This indicates that the role of evaluation and monitoring by the banks and transparency in banking operations assumes primary importance. For analytical simplicity, the occurrence of default, in the Indian context, may be split into two components: Random and the non-random components. The random component of default is assumed to be stochastic in nature. The different economic or commercial activities involve different levels of risks that are faced by borrowers with varied ability to sustain. Consequently, these risks are translated into NPAs through default. The relevant parameters can be estimated with a high degree of confidence when the number of borrowers in different categories of advances is reasonably high. The problem however arises with the second or non-random component. There are various possible situations when this component may increase. In such a case, a loan is not paid even when it is possible for the borrower to repay it —a case of wilful default. Several distinct instances may be put forward some of which are already mentioned.

Random Aspect of the Default Problem – A Poisson Process
In order to conceptualize the phenomenon of random default, we may express it in a simplified framework of a Poisson process. Let the bank lend to N number of borrowers where N is large. A borrower, operating in a smoothly functioning economy, would default only if he makes mistakes in predictions and/ or takes wrong decisions in his business. No other factors influence default. Under these circumstances, the occurrence of the incidence of default within a period, say a year, would be a Poisson process. Let X be number of default,
22

23

It may be useful to further extend the ideas contained in Akerlof. While interest rate is raised to cover up the risk factor, the basic idea is to increase the spread, keeping the rate of deposits unchanged. Assuming that return from other avenues which compete with bank deposits for money will remain the same, the relative attractiveness of bank deposits will remain the same. This is not a situation where there will be an increased flow of funds to the bank. This, coupled with the problems of default, mentioned by Akerlof will lead to a situation, where the role of banks as conduits of resource allocation between savers and investors will be undermined and allocative efficiency will suffer. Bhattacharya and Sivasubramaniam (2001), p. 4156.

24

The IUP Journal of Bank Management, August 2004

P(X = n) = e-m mn/n!

for n = 0, 1, 2…

The expected number of defaulters in a year would be equal to m, called default density24. If the economic conditions change, and have not been anticipated earlier, then the value of m will also change. For instance, if there were a downturn in the economy with adverse business conditions, then many of the predictions and decisions made by the borrowers that were correct under earlier circumstances would turn out to be wrong in the present situation. The Poisson process will move to a different state with greater expected value. Thus, in a downturn of the economy, we have a rising sequence of default density, {mi}, where mi > mi-1 and mi implies expected default in the i-th year. Similarly, in the phase of economic upturn, we have a declining sequence of default density. The same can be said about the growth of NPA. The above result is based on the assumption that the default is purely a stochastic process, and that the process does not involve any memory as is the typical characteristic of a Poisson process. Still it explains the possibility of increasing default and NPA and the bank cannot adjust interest rate according to the risk for the loans exceeding one year’s term leading to a less than expected realization of repayment. If the memory is introduced, particularly, in the process of default by the borrowers, the situation would be more alarming irrespective of the condition of the economy and the above stochastic model is no longer applicable. For instance, if borrower ail (l-th borrower in the i-th category) defaults and is not penalized, which the borrower aim learns then the latter’s probability of default increases: P (aim defaults/ ail already defaulted and not punished) > P (aim defaults). Over time, we then have an increasing sequence of defaults for which the bank has no estimation. It leads to contagious defaults. Although there are models for estimation of the speed of spreading rumor, technology or contamination, that may be invoked, the bank has no control over the process of default for those who have already borrowed.25 However, it cannot be a situation where all the defaulters will escape from punishment, but also one cannot assign probability of punishing a defaulter. The borrowers would act according to their subjective probability, which varies from borrower to borrower. The chances of loan defaults that a bank now faces cannot be expressed in terms of pure risk (that is, known probability distribution of defaults for different categories of loans) but more in terms of uncertainty. This problem may be taken care of to an extent by introducing memory in the process of lending by the bank that can make subjective assessment of chance of default for the borrower by studying his past record, his surroundings, his business activity, etc. Thus, screening of borrowers for the purpose of lending by a bank is important to avoid uncertainty to an extent. But, some of the problems originating from adverse selections, moral hazards, principal agency relations or political interference may still haunt the banking sector as discussed below. The very existence of banks is often interpreted in terms of its superior ability to overcome different kinds of information asymmetry over an individual lender. It may be seen that in the Indian context, a bank often fails to overcome these problems due to various non-random factors as discussed below.

Non-random Aspect of Default 1. Ex-ante Information Asymmetry
Irrespective of the size of the project, almost 70-75% of the investment is financed by banks and financial institutions and 25-30% comes from the promoters as their contribution in the form of capital26. In other words, major part of the investment in all the projects is financed by banks and
24 25 26

Also see Kijima, Masaaki (2001) For a discussion on the literature on diffusion of technology or rumour, see Karmeshu (1996). Desai, U C. ‘Managing Bad Loans’, The Economic Times, February 17, 1999, p. 9

Determinants of NPAs in the Indian Public Sector Banks: A Critique of Policy Reforms

25

financial institutions. It is the job of the banker to properly scrutinise the projects and stay away from unviable and un-bankable projects. The bank’s role is to screen potential projects to determine expected return and risk from the not very objective data presented by the demanders of funds. Clearly, the bank’s credit department takes the centre stage, because it is through its evaluation of potential investment opportunities the bank productively invests idle deposits mobilized from the household sector in the public interest. Term project proposals require detailed scrutiny as compared to working capital proposals, particularly keeping in view the future growth prospects of the project and that of the industry. The decision of the term loan is irreversible and any wrong decision could result in bad investment. There may exist situations where many borrowers hide information while borrowing and once the loans are granted they default. When banks fail to detect them adverse selection problems result.27 Adverse selection of the projects without properly scrutinising their viability has led to substantial accumulation of NPA in the banks. The following situations lead to failure to overcome ex-ante information asymmetry and thereby cause adverse selection of borrowers. a) Lack of organizational learning in the bank—repeated lending to same person or group of persons with similar dubious characteristics: Organizational learning on the part of the bank is very important in controlling the growth of NPA. It is obvious that with the experience of repeated lending over a period of time to varieties of borrowers, a bank can identify a particular type of borrower who is more likely to default. But in practice it fails to learn from the past. Due to several constraints, whether internal or external, like political interference, it cannot bar these potential defaulters. For instance, loans have been extended to: – Industries in the negative list circulated by IDBI, department of industries and RBI. – Existing accounts which have gone irregular, i.e. ever-greening of accounts.28 – A party which is irregular on existing accounts in a different branch of the same bank; and – Several projects with promoters or directors with doubtful integrity.29 b) Lack of vision of bank in sanctioning, reviewing and enhancing credit limits: While examining long term viability, both foresight30 as well as proper scrutiny is lacking on the part of the bank. Inefficient decisions have resulted in many newly born projects turning sick or closing down. There are instances in which instalments and interest have become due before the commencement of commercial production. Such accounts are considered as NPA, which reflects improper scrutiny and failure in considering moratorium period on a realistic basis.31 c) Political interference: Political leaders/organizations wield enormous power over the banks in granting loans to particular borrowers. It pays the political leaders to encourage default by the borrowers, in the absence of an efficient legal system. For instance, rural panchayats are responsible for recommending loans, but once the loan is disbursed, these rural political bodies take no initiative to ensure that the loan is serviced and repaid32. There are many instances where big companies received
27

28 29 30 31 32

Adverse selection exists when one participant in a transaction has more information about the game being played than the other participant. ‘Central Bank Sees Red Over Evergreening’. ‘The Economic Times’, August 25, 1999, p. 16. Desai, U.C, Managing Bad Loans, The Economic Times, February 17, 1999, p. 9. Possibly due to bounded rationality. Kannan, K. NPAs: How do we tackle them? The Economic Times, July 11, p. 9. This phenomenon is observed in West Bengal,where banks saddled with NPAs have become reluctant to come with fresh advances under employment generation and rural development programs unless some improvement takes place on the loan recovery front. See Ghosh, Sugoto, Bengal Banks Told to Get Moving on Loan Recovery, The Economic Times, February 1, 1999, p. 16. Similar phenomena may be prevalent in a number of other states.

26

The IUP Journal of Bank Management, August 2004

a large volume of loans under political influence and were able to escape punishment after default. Examples include UB Engineering promoted by Vijay Mallya, an MP in the Rajya Sabha and Mukand Steel promoted by Viren Shah, the governor of West Bengal.33 Earlier, loan melas and debt write offs under political pressure have also contributed to NPA problem of which further discussion will be made in the next section.

2. Ex post Information Asymmetry
There are asymmetries of information that develop subsequent to signing of a contract. Even when information asymmetries do not exist at the time of contracting, the parties to a contract often anticipate that asymmetries will develop sometime after a contract is signed. Because lenders have trouble ascertaining the quality of investment projects that borrowers wish to undertake, the borrowers have incentives to engage in activities that may be personally beneficial but increase the probability of default and thus harm the lender. For example, the borrower has incentives to cheat by misallocating funds for his own personal use, either through embezzlement or by spending on perquisites, which do not lead to increased profits. Moreover, the borrower has incentives to undertake investment in unprofitable projects that increase his power or to invest in projects with higher risk, in which the borrower does well if the project succeeds but the lender bears most of the loss if the project fails. When there are some actions which the borrower can take and which affect the likelihood of not being able to repay the debt, then there exists a kind of moral hazard problem.34 RBI (1999) report on NPA investigated around 800 top NPA accounts in 17 banks. It reveals that while loans were taken mostly for expansion, diversification, modernization, taking up new projects and for helping /promoting associated concerns, the single most prominent reason for units becoming sick and accounts turning sick is the diversion of funds by promoters.35 Further, nontransparent accounting policy and poor auditing practices often mislead the banks who otherwise could have taken appropriate measures to minimize loss due to default.36

3. Lack of Monitoring on the Part of Banks
Once lending decisions are made, ongoing monitoring needs to be done with a view to prevent moral hazard or otherwise in order to assure the maximum possibility of repayment. The Indian PSBs are not in a position to monitor perfectly the actions of those to whom they lend money. RBI report on NPA provided a number of instances where banks have financed projects of a company whose registered office is far away from the concerned branch of the bank, thus making it very difficult to monitor the accounts. Disbursement of loan in another area created problems for the bankers who often failed to keep track and check on end-use of the fund disbursed. Over-invoicing in cost of construction and machinery; disbursements against machines-materials-asset not relevant to the project, frequent cash withdrawals of huge amount, inter-firm transactions, payments for buying property of the partner or
33 34

35 36

Sangita Mehta (2002), ‘Foreclosure: Of Legal Tussles and Recovery’, The Economic Times, July 24, 2002, p. 11. In games with moral hazard, one player cannot directly observe the move made during the game (hidden action) that another player can and this unobserved move is made after the uninformed player moves. In case of a loan given by a bank, this may arise on either side of the transacting parties. One form of moral hazard may take place due to moral deprivation of the borrowers. But, it also may arise due to moral deprivation of the manager who is not acting towards fulfilling its duty towards depositors/shareholders. The problem of NPA may also arise due to a connivance of both the manager and the borrower. The Economic Times, Fund Diversion Leads to Mounting NPAs: RBI, The Economic Times, June 30. Diversion of funds is concealed by chartered accountants, who prepare the annual reports of the borrower and present it to the banks for credit. Also see K.Kannan, ‘NPAs: How do we tackle them?’, The Economic Times, July 11, 2000, p. 9.

Determinants of NPAs in the Indian Public Sector Banks: A Critique of Policy Reforms

27

director by withdrawing from cash credit account, and operating cash credit accounts for public issues are some prominent examples which point to the fact that bankers have not been vigilant in controlling the end-use of funds. During periodic inspection, appropriate enquiries are ignored even when certain irregularities are observed by the bankers. Three decades of government ownership has rendered banks organizationally weak. Faulty appraisals, absence of effective post-sanction monitoring have resulted in NPAs.37 Defective credit appraisal system, absence of risk rating and deficiencies in post-credit supervision and follow-up38 are important reasons that led to accumulation of NPAs. Further, it may be seen how conflict between government policy and bank’s interest generates NPA in the priority sector. In the case of priority sector lending, a certain proportion of the total advances would be provided to a particular type of borrower, irrespective of requirement, usage of the money, credibility or ability to repay. While devising such programs, the government has not devised any method of recovering loans in case of default. Thus, pre-approved nature of loans sanctioned under sponsored programs (leading to adverse selection), lack of effective follow up due to large number of accounts (and lack of monitoring) lead to formation of NPA in priority sectors for Indian PSBs.

4. Incomplete Contract
Contracts are inherently incomplete as it is difficult to specify all the modalities and the terms and conditions prior to signing of a contract. This is seen to be all the more true in the case of financial transactions in the PSBs where many disputes emerged regarding the magnitude of the interest amount dues. For instance, changes in the banking practice of applying and fixing of interest from quarterly to monthly caused confusion regarding the exact annual interest rates and thereby interest bills. Already a large number of litigations involving a sizable amount of bank money is pending in the court, for which neither interest nor the principal is forthcoming.39

Interaction between Random and Non-random Factors
NPAs are also created by interaction of random and non-random components. When a borrower cannot pay back due to the fact that his venture failed and he escapes any form of penalty, this induces another to default, even when he has the capacity to pay back. In such a scenario, occurrence of NPA due to random reasons leads to creation of additional NPA due to non-random reasons, a phenomenon called contagious default. RBI (1999) study of 800 top NPA borrowal accounts (referred above) distinguished between internal and external reasons behind accumulation of NPA. The external factors may be mentioned as under: • • • • Industrial recession40. Natural calamities like floods and accidents. Changes in economic policy and technology increasing the incidence of sickness. Labor problems, non availability and price escalations of raw materials, power shortage and other factors not within the control of the banks41.

37 38 39 40

41

Khan, S.H. NPAs: How do we tackle them? The Economic Times, July 11, 2000, p. 9 Joshi, P NPAs: How do we tackle them? The Economic Times, July 11, 2000, p. 9. .N. The Economic Times (1998) SBI, BOI Have Crores Locked in Litigation November 9, p. 12. Slowdown in the economy, liberalization, the South Asian Crisis, effect of globalization of domestic industries, cyclical factors are popular reasons cited for accumulation of NPAs. Changes in market condition, among other reasons.

28

The IUP Journal of Bank Management, August 2004

Among internal factors42, mention has been made of the following: • • Inefficient management and business failure Inappropriate technology43 and product obsolescence time and cost over runs by units.

Each of the external and internal reasons for NPA formation adduced by the RBI may come under both random and non-random processes of default as discussed above. We may take the examples of industrial recession or policy of technological changes increasing the intensity of sickness which come under external factors. This might have genuinely affected the borrower, thereby making it a random factor behind NPA formation. It is also possible that an unaffected borrower wilfully defaults and pretends that the above factor affected his business. This comes under non-random factor behind default. The external factors, according to RBI, are beyond the control of the banks and thus, the banks cannot be held responsible for the defaults caused by these factors.

Default Risk—Inappropriate Conceptualization
In the literature on finance, two kinds of risks are distinguished: Systematic and unsystematic risk. Systematic risks arise due to economic, sociological, and political reasons which have bearing on the entire market. Unsystematic risk arises due to factors peculiar to any firm such as labor strike, change in product line, change in demand for the product. It is necessary to relate our concepts of random and non-random reasons of NPA to these two kinds of risk. It may be argued that random reasons of NPA formation may either relate to the entire economy like a recession or it may also relate to factors typical of a borrowing firm, as has been mentioned above. Thus the random reasons of NPA formation may be related to both systematic and unsystematic risk. However, so far as the non-random factors are concerned, not all of them can be reduced to risk alone. This would be well understood if we take the case of political interference, which is an important factor in non-random default. As discussed above, it arises when there is a strong lobby related to a specific sector of the economy, which is placated by the politicians for votes. This factor is neither related to the whole economy nor typically to a borrowing firm. This makes it difficult to relate it to systematic or unsystematic risk. But the fact remains that if an advance is made to a borrower with political clout, there is a high chance of default associated with it. Interestingly, the loan may be granted to the borrower in the first place because of his political connections. It may be noted that many other reasons leading to non-random generation of NPA can also be related to the dimension of uncertainty and not risk44. It is known that the phenomenon of moral hazard exists, but the probability of its occurrence is unknown. So far as the aspect of contagious default is concerned, there is no basis of providing some estimate of probability of default induced by another default. The aspect of contagious default as well seems to tread in the realm of uncertainty and not risk.
42 43

44

An internal reason, which was not cited by the committee, is under financing of a project by a bank. Labor-oriented small-size technology operations, for example. Also see K Kannan, NPAs: How do we tackle them? The Economic Times, July 11, 2000, p. 9. In case of both risk and uncertainty, possible outcomes are known. In case of risk, it is possible to assign probabilities to the outcomes, but it is not possible in the case of uncertainty.

Determinants of NPAs in the Indian Public Sector Banks: A Critique of Policy Reforms

29

Table 5: Regressions Coefficients of Gross NPA on Growth Rate of GDP and on Industries (1993-2003) (Y variable in Rs crores)
Variables Regression of GNPA on GDP growth rate Regression of GNPA of industry growth rate Intercept GDP growth rate Intercept Industry growth rate Coefficient 63516.54 -274998 54085.71 -109513 t-value 6.40* -1.67 13.37* -1.90* Adj R2 0.15 0.21

Note: * Denotes significant at 10% or lower level.

If the above reasoning is correct, then it has very significant implications. The financial notion of NPA as a risk phenomenon only, is an inherently incomplete approach.45 Moreover, if policy prescriptions and provisions being applied to banking practices to handle NPA is based on risk aspect alone, then they adhere to a financial notion of understanding NPA and are hence inadequate.

Alternative Hypotheses Explaining NPAs of the Indian PSBs 1. High Incidence of NPAs are a Result of Slowdown of the Economy, Particularly Industrial Recession
The macro factors that are popularly adduced to explain high incidence of NPAs include slowdown of the economy, particularly in the industrial sector, liberalization, the South East Asian Crisis, effect of globalization on domestic industries and cyclical factors. Given the availability of data, it is difficult to isolate the impact of liberalization or South East Asian crisis on NPAs, but one can relate the latter to economic slowdown or economic performance in general. During 1993 and 2001, gross NPAs increased at a rate of 5.01% per annum. The growth rate of GDP at factor cost in India was reasonably high (5.52% per annum) during the 1980s which accelerated in the 1990s to reach 6.12% per annum.46 The growth performance of the industry sector was even better in the 1980s and 1990s —although it marginally declined from 7.65% per annum to 6.59% per annum between the two decades. As regards overall trend of GDP one cannot say that it decelerated in the 1980s and 1990s. , However it may happen that fall in the growth rate for some specific years contributed to NPA formation. The result of a regression of gross NPA on the GDP growth rate (for the years from 1993 to 2003) showed that the relation is negative but insignificant, explaining only 24% of the variation. A similar regression of Gross NPA on the industry sector’s growth yields more significantly negative relation. (See Table 5)

2. Stagnation in Specific Industries with Large Share of Loans Contributed to NPAs
As on March 31, 2001, industry shared 43.58% of the outstanding credit of the PSBs. Textiles shared 6.10 percent of which cotton textiles shared 2.37%. Basic metal and metal products shared 5.84%, within this group iron and steel shared 4.22 %. Personal loans including housing shared a very high proportion of the total outstanding credit (11.73%). According to the estimates of Uchikawa (2001), the growth performance of the textiles industries was rather slow in the 1980s (4.8 percent) which
45

46

Three sources of risk affecting banks: Default risk, interest rate risk and liquidity risk are discussed in textbooks (Freixas and Rotchet, 1997). NPA is related to default risk which is said to occur when a borrower is not able to repay a debt (principal and interest). Data on the growth rate of GDP and various sectors are compiled by RBI (2003) Handbook of Statistics of the Indian Economy 2002-03.

30

The IUP Journal of Bank Management, August 2004

turned to be negative in the 1990s (-1.1%). Wood industries witnessed a negative growth in the 1980s (-2.1%) Variables coefficient t-value Adj R2 which however made some Intercept 30940.75 16.53 0.72 Growth rate of agriculture 4796.63 0.47* improvement in the 1990s. Growth rate of SSI -102218.59 -4.64 The industries that did not Note: * Denotes insignificant. perform so well over these decades include leather, beverage and metals industries. Dasgupta undertook a study on financial risk, measured in terms of Altman’s Zeta Score, on several industry groups for the years from 1993-94 to 1999-2000.47 It was observed that textiles, paper, pig iron and sponge iron, steel and castings had high risks throughout the period. Cement, sharing the major part of the non-metallic mineral products, started becoming riskier after 1996-97. Leather products were able to overcome their financial risks and metal products, which were earlier not risky, have become so since 1997-98 (p.4). Table 6: Regression Coefficients of the Priority Sector Gross NPA on Growth Rate of Agriculture and SSI (1995-2003) (Y variable in Rs crores) It is therefore evident that selected groups of industries became a major source of NPA accumulation. Steel being so important in this regard, one needs to mention that with the initiation of liberalization and globalization and state emphasis on infrastructure building, this industry made massive investment for capacity building. However, for various reasons, it could neither raise exports nor face adequate growth of domestic demand. The unfulfilled expectations raised by liberalization, contributed towards NPA formation.

3. The High Share of Lending to the Priority Sector, Consisting of Primarily Agriculture and SSI, Contributed to NPAs in a Big Way
The agricultural sector achieved a moderate growth (3.12% per annum) in the 1980s which was slightly reduced in the 1990s (2.98% per annum). Similarly, the SSI sector’s performance was also impressive. It was as high as 11.63% in the 80s which declined to 8.59% in 1990-2002. NPAs in these sectors cannot be attributed to their poor performance. However, in agriculture, price crash of commercial crops after harvest (which is generally not reflected in the aggregate figures) is a common phenomenon that leads to loan defaults by the farmers. Sometimes, failures of the high valued crops, like cotton due to pests attack or other reasons, may lead to default by farmers as recently noted in many states of India. Thus, year to year fluctuations in their growth rates may have some impact on NPAs. A regression exercise of gross NPA due to priority sector on agricultural and SSI sectors’ growth rates also indicated no relation with respect to agricultural growth but significantly negative relation with the growth of SSI explaining 72% of the variations. (See Table 6) However, the explanation of NPAs in the priority sector has to be made in terms of the indiscriminate choice of the borrowers that contributed to the high incidence of default. There is some element of truth in it as this sector’s share of NPAs is more than that of loans as in 1993. Nevertheless, over time, its share in loan declined but the decline in the share of NPAs was faster than the share of the loans (Mukherjee, 2003). The growth rate of NPAs of the priority sector was 3.9% which was much lower
47

Dasgupta, Sushmita ‘Nonperforming Assets of the Steel Industry – A general Economic Concern’, www.indiainfoline.com.

Determinants of NPAs in the Indian Public Sector Banks: A Critique of Policy Reforms

31

Table 7: Correlation Coefficient between Gross NPAs to Advances Ratios and Interest Earnings to Advances Ratios across PSBs
Year Correlation coefficient for 27 PSBs t-values 1995-96 0.17 0.86 1996-97 0.27 1.40 1997-98 0.35 1.87 1998-99 0.45 2.52* 1999-2000 2000-01 0.55 3.29* 0.29 1.52 2001-02 Pooled 0.32 1.69 0.32 4.62*

Note: * Significant at less than 5% level.

than that of the non-priority sector (6.4%) during the period 1993 - 2001. The relative improvement of the priority sector’s NPAs in the latter part of the 1990s may be attributed to the more cautious approaches and policies of the banks and their exertion of choice in selecting borrowers helped to motivate the borrowers, who are generally small, to repay the loans in due time. Using the same logic, one may say that in the non-priority sector, it is neither possible to deny loans to a large number of big borrowers nor to motivate them to repay. In consequence NPAs due to the non-priority sector are growing disproportionately.

4. NPAs are Generated as a Result of Lending to more Risky Ventures in Search of Higher Profits
One may argue that the banks attempt to earn a high rate of profit by taking risky lending with high interest rates and the high NPA is a necessary outcome. Under such circumstances, it is expected that both the NPAs and interest earnings would increase or move together. In order to test this association a simple correlation exercise has been undertaken between gross NPAs and advances ratios and gross interest earnings to advance ratios across PSBs for the years from 1995 to 2001, as shown in Table 7. It may be seen from the table that the correlation becomes significantly positive only in the last two years of the decades, i.e., 1998-99 and 1999-2000, when the relevant NPA ratios already started declining. Prior to this, it was insignificant implying that in the peak period of NPA problem there was no marked association between high risk lending (implying high interest rate) and the high incidence of NPAs. However, it is interesting to note that the correlation and the level of confidence improved throughout the second half of the 1990s when most of the PSBs also improved their NPA ratios. It was since the beginning of the next decade that the association again loosened. The foregoing suggests that the kind of NPAs generated by the Indian PSBs is a normal characteristic of banking practices. It is generally expected to remain within a bound defined by the level of risks and their management as observed in many developed countries. However, in the case of Indian PSBs, the level of NPAs far exceeded than which was expected from the risk profile of their advances. It seems that the primary reasons of generation of disproportionately high NPAs is related to the problem involving the various kinds of interventions, and also the nature of functioning of the asset market as discussed below. Problems related to the asset market: Apart from screening and monitoring the actions of the borrower after the loan is granted, another instrument available with banks to minimize loss due to default/occurrence of NPA is the liquidation of the mortgaged asset after default. The crux of the problem, not highlighted in the literature, is the non-existence or malfunctioning of the asset market that enables/encourages generation of NPA through conventional routes of asymmetric information, adverse selection, moral hazard and improper monitoring. In brief, collateral is very useful for the bank in a situation where there is a possibility of default. It may be pointed out that if the asset market is perfect, the use of collateral with a reasonable amount of margin money is sufficient to avoid any NPA

32

The IUP Journal of Bank Management, August 2004

accumulation irrespective of the problems like adverse selection and moral hazard. But in reality, collaterals are not always safeguards against NPAs. Calomiris and Hubbard (1990) and Greenwald and Stigltiz (1988), emphasized that a sharp decrease in the valuation of firms’ assets in a stock market crash lowers the value of the collateral and thereby makes adverse selection a more important problem for lenders since the losses from loan defaults are now higher. In other words, collateral can be a risky asset whose value can fluctuate. They, however, missed the point that market for many of the assets are not well developed or there may exist a legal problem in liquidating the asset. In such a situation, collateral value may not be fully realized. Further, operations in this kind of markets may have high transaction costs. In addition to that, many of the assets are idiosyncratic which do not have much value in other use. Furthermore, the value of a going concern erodes rapidly the moment it ceases to operate. Thus, collateral fails to solve the problems of default in general, or of adverse selections created by asymmetric information48 of which further discussion will be made in the section below. Reasons peculiar to Indian PSBs: Apart from the above reasons, there are a number of typical reasons leading to emergence of the NPA problem in the case of Indian PSBs. Some of these include malfunctioning of the institutional environment, captured by its economic, political, legal, social manifestations. The other reasons include use of the bank as an instrument of public policy, incompatibility of bank’s interest with certain policy instruments as well as the change in the economic regime. It is also argued that new laws on environment and social security not envisaged at the time of appraisal have also contributed to accumulation of NPA. Defaulter friendly legal system: RBI report (1999) on NPA pointed out lacunae in credit recovery, largely arising from inadequate legal provisions on foreclosure and bankruptcy, long drawn legal procedures and difficulties in execution of the decrees awarded by the court. The legal system does not permit early recovery of dues. The report said that the Indian legal system is sympathetic towards borrowers and works against bank’s interest (defaulter friendly legal system). It may also be mentioned that there is no social stigma attached to the defaulters, especially wilful defaulters.49 Further, it is becoming increasingly futile to keep the litigation alive for long, as it is only a drain on resources. These legal procedures are highly time consuming as the matters get invariably delayed with law courts granting adjournments one after another for any small reason. More money is spent than what is hoped to be recovered by pursuing these cases in the courts of law. Despite most of the loans being backed by security, banks are unable to enforce their claims on the collateral, when loans turn nonperforming, and therefore loan recoveries remain insignificant. Unsustainability of litigation in cases where borrowers are neither paying up nor likely to do so makes provisioning against these NPAs a losing proposition. The bank may feel that a write-off against such loans would help clean up the balance sheet and induce greater transparency. Thus there may be a tendency to write-off a small amount of advances in the face of prohibitive legal and administrative cost and inordinate delay in final settlement.

48

49

In such cases, the importance of the issue of screening of borrowers by the lender remains and this has to be done through collecting extraneous information about borrower. But that is again costly. As per neo-classical principle, the collection of information would go up to the extent where the marginal cost of information collection equals the marginal benefit of the information collected. While deciding to go for additional informational collection, one needs to know the worth of that information which leads to a problem of circularity or infinite regress. K Kannan (2000) NPAs: How do we tackle them? The Economic Times, July 11, 2000.

Determinants of NPAs in the Indian Public Sector Banks: A Critique of Policy Reforms

33

Use of bank as an instrument of public policy: A number of examples may be cited in order to show that the use of PSBs as an instrument of public policy has helped accumulation of NPAs. Lending under populist schemes like loan melas, directed lending to certain sectors like mini-steel, mini-paper, mini-cement units, sugar and cotton spinning co-operatives are examples. Use of certain policy instruments cutting across interest of banks: Indecision on exiting out of bad loans through OTS due to fear of investigating agencies like CBI, CVC have all contributed to worsening the NPA situation of the banks. The banks are owned by the government, which brings them under the purview of CVC, and business decisions are given a go by for adhering to procedures. The private and foreign banks are outside the purview of the CVC, which makes them recover and write off at a faster pace. BIFR is an escape route easily available to a wilful defaulter. Once the case is registered with BIFR, the bank’s option to proceed legally is closed. For quite a few corporate houses, reaching to BIFR has become the most convenient route to avoid bank litigation. Over the years, the process of revival of sick industries has led to a situation in which the corporate houses do not mind blackmailing the lenders with the threat of taking refuge under the Sick Industrial Companies (Special Provisions) Act. The BIFR experience shows how it has become a safe haven for companies that want to deter a feasible solution such as closure and prefer to be parasites on public money. There is a proposal to repeal Sick Industrial Companies Act that will prevent defaulting companies from taking refuge in BIFR.50 Intentional misuse of settlement policy of RBI: RBI has initiated a policy of settlement of loans with the borrowers, where an element of concession is granted to the defaulters. This has created a moral hazard problem where even the smaller and less influential borrowers are refusing to pay off their loan. This tendency to misuse the settlement policy of RBI has been increasing over the years. Euphoria generated with liberalization: A dream of globalization with great market prospect led to huge investments like steel which was unfortunately not realized. Often large corporate houses delayed payments and contributed indirectly to NPA of SSI units51. Projects financed in the pre-reform era, with high gearing, low promoter’s stake, with viability based on high tariff and fiscal concessions have turned sick in the new regime52.

Section IV
A Critical Evaluation of the Policy Measures to Control NPAs
A discussion of NPAs reveals that two sets of factors are in action. One that leads to the emergence of NPA and the other helps in its perpetuation and does not allow the problem to be resolved. Correspondingly, policies to solve these problems are of two distinct types. One set of policies aims at preventing an asset from degenerating into NPA and the other set is to ensure recovery in case of default. While PSBs have their share of fault in failing to check the growth of NPAs, the more significant problem appears to be related with the asset market. It is in this context that the policy measures introduced need to be critically looked into. In the first set of policies, the measures intended to granting a measure of autonomy subject to prudential guidelines are discussed below. These measures may be classified into two categories. One
50 51 52

The Economic Times, Mission NPA II: Foreclosures deterrent to trip defaulters, March 1, 2001, p. 16. Joshi, P NPAs: How do we tackle them? The Economic Times, July 11, 2000, p. 9. .N. Ibid.

34

The IUP Journal of Bank Management, August 2004

was deregulation of interest rate, while the other one related to dismantling of statutory credit allocation mechanisms. The period prior to 1992 was characterized by administered interest rate as well as tight credit allocation mechanisms53. In April 1992, steps were taken by RBI to deregulate interest rate on liabilities and assets in a phased manner. Interest rate deregulation started with deposit rate. Banks were allowed to fix deposit rates below a ceiling rate announced by RBI. Deregulation of lending rates began in October 1994 with deregulation of rates for advances greater than Rs 200,000 subject to a certain norm. The single most important event in this phase was deregulation of entry of private domestic banks through the issue of specific guidelines by RBI on January 22, 1993 as per the recommendations of Narasimham Committee. The interest rate on liabilities was further deregulated subsequently. Since July 1996, RBI had been taking steps to abolish ceiling on interest rates for deposits of different maturities, beginning with those with the maximum maturity. By April 1998, interest rate on deposits for more than 15 days had also been freed. Banks were allowed to charge differential rates on deposits of similar maturity but of different sizes. However, interest rates on saving deposits continue to be governed by RBI. Interest rates on NRI domestic term deposits under Non-Resident (External) Rupee Accounts scheme have also been deregulated, and banks have been given the freedom to fix their own interest rates on deposits under Foreign Currency Non-Resident Accounts (Banks) scheme subject to a ceiling prescribed by the RBI from time to time. Alongside this, banks were exempted from obtaining prior approval of the RBI or prior concurrence of the IBA for introducing new deposit mobilization schemes, except for NRI deposits. However, it remains obligatory for banks to obtain prior approval of their respective boards and follow the directives on interest rates, premature withdrawal, sanction of loans and advances against deposits etc., issued by RBI from time to time. During this phase, deregulation of interest rate on assets was continued. After deregulating the lending rate for loans above Rs 2,00,000 and for those below Rs 2,00,000 have also been partially deregulated with effect from April 1998. Interest on all loans below Rs 2,00,000 was allowed to vary upto an upper limit set by PLR. These rates were earlier fixed at 12% for credit up to Rs 25,000 and 13.5% for credit limits between Rs 25000 and Rs 2,00,000. Deregulation in lending rates has been followed by lifting of different quantitative restrictions on credit allocation. All instructions relating to maximum permissible bank finance and credit monitoring arrangements have been withdrawn since April 1997. Similar deregulations have also been made with respect to term finance by virtue of which RBI has withdrawn its stipulation both on time and quantum of loans that can be granted by banks either individually or in consortia for a single project. Deregulation of interest rate has provided an opportunity for banks to fix interest rates for different categories of borrowers in accordance with their risk profile. Discarding of credit allocation schemes has led to more autonomy on the part of the banks in formulating their own method of assessing working capital needs of borrowers within the prudential guidelines and exposure norms prescribed by RBI.

Problems with these Policies
Monetary developments in the first half of 1998-99, as outlined in the mid-term review of the credit policy, have made it clear that there is adequate liquidity in the system and had advised the banks to
53

Different credit allocation mechanisms included capital authorization scheme, credit-monitoring arrangement, and consortium financing and lead bank system.

Determinants of NPAs in the Indian Public Sector Banks: A Critique of Policy Reforms

35

step up their lending operations. However, this has not happened. Due to very stringent RBI norms on NPAs, there appears to be a universal thought process in all echelons of the banking system that it is better not to lend rather than to face the risk of NPAs. Banks are more comfortable with lending to companies with AAA or AA ratings since they do not run the risk of NPAs. This resulted in what has been termed as “islandization of credit”54. It is a phenomenon where the credit delivery is polarized and a handful of large companies with very good ratings would gobble up most of the credit leaving the rest of the industrial sector high and dry. It has been observed that Corporation Bank roped in certain zero risk clients in 1999 for extending Rs. 500 cr at PLR55. However, it is argued that such a phenomenon is also fraught with problems. Denying credit to companies without top ratings has an adverse effect on the industrial production and GDP growth. This will not only stifle the companies that are deprived of credit but also harm the companies with top ratings by aggravating recession.56 The new banking culture, nurtured by economic and financial reforms has induced PSBs to focus on consumer credit and capital-market related activities, apart from corporate elite. Lending to agriculture, small-scale industries and the self-employment sector has become infra-dig. This illusion was shattered with the capital market becoming moribund during 2003. While, in the case of consumer lending, a sort of saturation point was reached57, the PSBs found the soft option of investing a bulk of their resources in government securities. This trend, which has become a chronic feature of PSBs, has been characterized as a sort of sickness of the PSBs58. It is against this backdrop that the activist role that RBI has at long last resumed playing in prodding PSBs to lend more to the rural and semi-urban areas has to be viewed. Credit policy measures announced on April 29, 2003 also carry a firm tone that PSBs be dissuaded from exercising the soft option of investing bulk of their resources in government securities. A drastic step like imposing a ceiling on PSBs investments, say 30% of their NTDL has already been suggested59 to provoke these PSBs to reach out to the intended sectors. To overcome the second type of problems, the policies adopted by the government are to strengthen institutional framework so as to ensure speedy recovery consequent on default. After default, the only course of action left to banks is to take possession of the collateral and sell in the market at a price covering the loan amount, interest amount and the incidental expenses. But, for utilizing the asset market in solving problem of NPA may require the following three conditions: • • • The bank can smoothly take the possession of the asset. A secondary market in the ceased asset must exist. Transaction cost of operating in the market is low so that it may be used for realizing a commensurate price of the collateral.

54

55 56 57

58 59

This term has been coined by Prasad Godbole in his contribution on credit delivery published in The Economic Times, December 23, 1998. The Economic Times (1998) Corporation Bank to lend Rs 500 cr to “0” risk clients, August 17, 1998, p. 12. Godbole, P Credit delivery: Risk some, win some, The Economic Times, 23rd December, 1998, p. 7. . This was predicted by a report on retail banking by KPMG, an international consultancy agency in 1998. See, Mukherjee, S. Stress on retail banking may hurt bank bottom lines, The Economic Times, December 21, 1998, p. 10. Mujumdar, N.A(2003), p. 8. Ibid, p. 8.

36

The IUP Journal of Bank Management, August 2004

Selvam Committee framed by IBA on NPAs argued that it takes decades for courts to decide cases and even when decrees are obtained, execution of decrees are virtually an impossible task. In view of the inability of the legal system to help tackle the problem of NPAs, government set up the Debt Recovery Tribunals (DRTs) during 1994 in terms of “Recovery of Debts Due to banks and Financial Institutions Act, 1993.” DRTs have been conferred jurisdiction to try and entertain application for recovery of debts due to banks and financial institutions. The jurisdiction of the civil courts has been excluded in matters falling within the jurisdiction of the Tribunal except under Articles 226 and 227 of the Constitution of India. The Debt Recovery Tribunal, which has the jurisdiction to entertain only claims from banks and financial institutions, will not have the jurisdiction to entertain a cross suit or counterclaim that may be founded either on the same or a separate cause of action and/or the amount of which may even be in excess of the claim in suit. This is because the Debt Recovery Tribunal has no jurisdiction to pass and decree or order for recovery against the bank or financial institutions. An Appellate Tribunal has also been constituted to entertain appeals from orders of the Debt Recovery Tribunal. If a person is aggrieved by the order of the DRT, he can file an appeal to the Appellate Tribunal within 30 days from date of receipt of the DRT order. If the DRT or Appellate Tribunal holds that possession of assets by the secured creditor was wrongful and directs the secured creditor to return asset to concerned borrower, the borrower shall be entitled to compensation and costs as may be determined by DRT or Appellate tribunal. The Tribunal can also direct return of assets, if the secured creditor had already sold or transferred the asset to a third party. However, DRTs, conceived as fast techniques for recovery of bank loans remained virtual non-starters. The reasons include inadequate infrastructure unable to handle large number of cases under DRTs, inappropriate legal framework governing the functioning of DRTs and ineffective threat of forcing recovery through DRT, when loans are not backed by assets.60 A new ordinance called “Securitization and Reconstruction of Financial Asset and Enforcement of Security Interest Act” was issued in 2002. It allowed secured lenders to sell and lease assets which are charged with them by a defaulting borrower without the lender’s consent, after issuing a notice61 the assets are immediately classified as non performing, without a protracted legal battle. The ordinance deals with three basic issues: sclerotization of assets, setting up of an asset construction company and enforcement of securities. What is being focused here is enforcement of security, which boils down to taking control of a defaulter’s assets. However it has been observed that, DRTs frequently raise objections when lenders approach them with the plea to initiate action under Sclerotization Act in suit filed accounts that have been lying before the tribunals. This is an example how two measures designed to solve the same problem run at cross-purposes. The passage of the above mentioned Act did not mean end of court interventions in settlement of NPA problem. The legality of the Act has been challenged by several lenders against whom banks had threatened action of seizure and sell-off assets under the powers derived from the legislation. The Supreme court had issued a stay on sale of assets under the Act after Mardia Chemicals had filed a case against ICICI Bank for paying up its dues, failing which the bank had threatened recovery action under the Act. Subsequently, several companies that had incurred the wrath of their

60 61

Gogoi and Iyengar, RBI maps out new rules for recovery, The Economic Times, August 2, 2000, p. 1. From March 2004, a borrower can be classified as a defaulter if dues are not paid for 90 days against 180 days. See Mehta (2002).

Determinants of NPAs in the Indian Public Sector Banks: A Critique of Policy Reforms

37

lenders filed cases in the high courts challenging the notices issued to them and have obtained stay of further action62. Subsequently, the validity of the ordinance was upheld by the Supreme court subject to some caveats. However, the same judgement has created overlapping jurisdiction in the process of loan recovery, as indicated by the legal imbroglio between ICICI bank and Mardia Chemicals, which would ultimately delay the process of recovery. The judgement on the one hand enabled the bank to attach the asset of the defaulter bypassing the BIFR and on the other hand, allowed the defaulter to move DRT. Further, it has made the litigation cost too heavy for the banks as against the defaulter.Once the assets are attached, it is obvious that the defaulter would move from DRT to Supreme court, as it takes a little cost, inflicting tremendous loss on the lender in terms of time, litigation cost and the cost of maintaining the attached asset. The case of Mardia chemicals vs ICICI bank revealed that the role of DRT has been reversed under the Supreme court judgement, where the defaulters approach for redressal. Pending litigation blocks attachment and selling of collateral by the bank in case of default. In the meantime, the value of assets erodes faster with lengthy time taken for sale only realizing junk value. After the first round of notices to big defaulters with loans up to Rs10 cr as per Sclerotization Act, some banks,63 still reluctant to seize assets have sent a second round of notices to defaulters to come forward for compromise for settlement. Banks do not want to attach the assets of the defaulter as they have inadequate expertise in managing or disposing of those attached assets to recover their dues from its defaulters. Instead they prefers to bring the provisions of Sclerotization Act to bring their defaulters to the negotiation table and execute compromise deals towards early recovery of NPAs. The biggest failure of PSBs in recovering their NPA is on account of big borrowers with PSBs making recoveries of merely Rs 168 cr against NPAs under this category of Rs 22,355 cr till March 2003. This poor response of the scheme forced RBI to extend the scheme till December 31, 2003 against the earlier deadline of October 31, 200364. High value defaults with dues exceeding Rs 5 cr accounted for total NPAs of PSBs to the extent of Rs 22,866 cr, accounted for a large portion of their total Rs 56,000 cr NPAs. Quite clearly, the response of this section of defaulters is the most critical part of any attempt to significantly bring down the NPA burden of PSBs. It is felt that reluctance of the large defaulters to come forward for settlement discussions indicates that they are probably more confident to take on the lenders if action is threatened under the Sclerotization Act presumably because of political clout65. Thus, political interference appears to be significant as it acts as a double-edged sword, both in creating as well as perpetuation of NPA problem. With the recent Supreme Court Judgement upholding the Sclerotization Act, 2002, PSBs started feeling that the NPA problems would be resolved overnight66. But, the reality is different – neither a bank can take control over the management of a defaulting unit as the bank does not have the required expertise, nor it can realize the full value by disposing off the asset. As discussed below, the asset

62 63 64 65 66

Sen, Sarbajeet K, DRTs block implementation of Securitisation Act, Buisness Line, July 7, 2003, p. 12. Sukumar, C.R., Bank of Maharastra prefers compromise deals on NPA, Business Line, May 24, 2003, p. 10. Sen, Sarbajeet K, RBI one time settlement schemes fail, Buisness Line, July 1, 2003, p. 1. Many of them may have enormous clout with the banks themselves (borrower-manger nexus). Bankers upbeat about better asset recovery, Buisness Line, April 9, 2004,p.5

38

The IUP Journal of Bank Management, August 2004

market may not exist or may be highly imperfect, the transaction costs in the asset market may be very high, the asset may be idiosyncratic, the unit might have already been closed down and reduced to junk value, share value of the unit might have crashed—all this leads to much reduced recovery of the NPAs. Nevertheless, this judgement will broaden financial sector reform and will benefit the banks in the long term. Narasimham Committee suggested formation of an “Asset Reconstruction Fund” which will take over bad and doubtful debts from banks at a discount and subsequently follow up the recovery of dues owed to them by the primary borrowers. Having acquired bad loans, ARFs have four options to recover. They include sale of collateral, restructuring the loan, foreclosure of the loan and seizure of all the assets and going for liquidation of the company. A complexity of factors conspires against formation and consequent satisfactory operation of ARFs. They are discussed below.

a) Lack of a Market in Impaired Financial Asset
The first step towards formation of ARF is to transfer impaired financial assets from banks to the new entity. However, it has been observed that talks between banks and RBI on guidelines for ARFs appears to be stuck on the pricing of the impaired assets67 in the absence of a market, where such prices may be determined. ARF managers prefer to price the impaired assets net of provisioning with a view to reduce financial outgoes to the banks. Banks have not agreed to this and have expressed preference for auditors and chartered accountants to value the market price of an NPA put up on sale to the ARF68. This problem is aggravated due to lack of existence of a secondary market of physical assets. This leads us to the next problem.

b) Lack of a Secondary Market in Physical Asset
It appears ARCs cannot be a success story in absence of secondary market in ceased asset69. The problem originates due to the fact that these assets are idiosyncratic, i.e. invested for a specific purpose. Its value is realized only if it is functioning for that particular purpose. It has no value (except scrap value) for other purposes. The set of its potential buyers is highly restricted to those who can utilize this asset in a productive way, provided the asset will remain technologically viable.

c) Claims of Banks Preceded by that of Financial Institutions
There is again a legal aspect of the current standoff with regard to ARFs. As per the law, financial institutions providing long-term funds have to first charge on assets, with banks holding second or third charge. On current asset, the bank holds the first charge, but in the case of an NPA current assets are usually nil. In such a case, financial institutions get away with the sale proceeds of the NPA, leaving the banks in the lurch. While some bankers have argued for a pro-rata sharing of sale proceeds irrespective of the nature of the charge, RBI cannot change the basic law.70 The above discussion reveals that a number of conditions are necessary for operating in a secondary market for assets with a low transaction cost. They include speedy trial at lower litigation cost, getting possession of the asset, once the verdict is given in favor of the bank, lower intermediation cost.
67 68

69 70

Banks at receiving end on bad debt sale by ARCs, Buisness line , March 8, 2003, p. 10. Even when a price is agreed on by both the parties, bank and ARF, presence of kickbacks may be alleged and parliament, CBI and CVC may frame charges of corruption against bank management. See, Onkar Goswami, The myth of Asset Reconstruction Companies, The Economic Times,12th August, 1999, p. 6. Renu Kohli (2004) Looking beyond Non-performing Assets, The Indian Express, February 12. However, it could enforce a MOU between long term and short term lenders before transfer of NPAs to an ARC. See Buisness Line, March 8, 2003, p. 10.

Determinants of NPAs in the Indian Public Sector Banks: A Critique of Policy Reforms

39

Section V
Concluding Observations – Degenerated Banking Institutions and Institutional Environment
It was commonly believed that the Indian government could not afford bank failure, the government would rescue the banks whatever was the level of the crisis. This caused some sort of desperation on the part of both the bankers and borrowers. The earliest estimates of NPAs were available for the year 1993 when gross NPAs of the PSBs amounted to as high as Rs 39,000 cr. The severity of the problem was well understood as it shared 23.2% of the total advances or 11.8% of the total assets. The state, and RBI in particular, made concerted efforts to control it. When the new accounting practice was introduced, where interest earnings included the realized interest only71, not the interest accrual, PSBs showed substantial losses and thereby a massive recapitalization was called for. On the other hand, in order to clean off the NPAs from the balance sheet, banks had to make provisioning against these loss assets. This, in turn, affected their profit to a great extent putting these banks in a kind of vicious cycle. Over the next ten years these ratios slowly declined—by 2003, gross NPAs to total advances became 9.4% and that in total assets became 4.2%. This decline was not due to recovery of the loss assets but due to faster growth of advances and assets of the banks compared to their NPAs. However, incremental NPAs in fresh advances or assets declined considerably. This may be interpreted in terms of concerted efforts made by the RBI in raising competitiveness and efficiency and in terms of granting greater autonomy to the banks in their decision making. However, in absolute terms, gross NPAs rapidly increased—within the ten year period, 1993-2003, it rose from Rs 39,000 cr to Rs 54,000 cr. While analyzing the factors responsible for the massive accumulation of NPAs, alternative approaches and frameworks have been used in this paper. First, formation of NPAs is seen as an integral part of banking activities and its magnitude would depend on the exposure of the banks to various levels of risks across sectors of economic activities. But, it was noted that the risks (measured by returns in terms of interest earnings) are not commensurate with the NPAs. The explanations of liberalization and globalization, overall economic slowdown, stagnation in many industries and agriculture leading to NPA formation, could not stand in explaining such a high share of default in total advances. Nevertheless, the above mentioned problems might have contributed towards NPA formation to an extent. A micro-level probe would reveal that non-economic factors, like moral hazards, adverse selection, screening and monitoring problems, principal agency problems, are highly important—some of which are operating through political and bureaucratic channels and some others through banks’ own administrative channels in granting loans and in preventing recovery of dues. In case of Indian PSBs, this has become a rampant and all-pervasive phenomenon. In fact high incidence of default in the priority sector lending may be attributed to a great extent to the political factors. Similarly, there is ample evidence of big borrowers in the non-priority sectors who defaulted but the banks could not penalize and confiscate their assets because the latter wielded enormous political power and at times influence over the board of members of the banks. The problem of confiscation of asset was further aggravated by two important factors—legal factors that take a long time to settle any dispute, and highly imperfect or inadequately formed markets for confiscated assets. Banks, therefore, often fail to realize the value of the defaulted amount by disposing of the confiscated assets. All this leads the banks to go for compromise with the defaulters giving several concessions to the latter and this encourages the others to default. The evolving policies of settlement of NPAs are being frequently thwarted by legal
71

In the earlier practice, interest accrual to any loan is automatically entered in the revenue book irrespective of being realized.

40

The IUP Journal of Bank Management, August 2004

Table 8: Growth Rate of Schedule Commercial Banks’ Deposits and Investments in Government Securities
Period Growth rate of commercial banks’ deposits (%) 20.68 17.96 17.07 Growth rate and investments in government securities (%) 21.16 19.22 20.62

injunctions and are yet to be concretized. Thus, NPA formation

depends not only on banking rules, regulations and practices that are part of its institutions, but also on the external institutional environment within which PSBs

1970-80 1980-90 1990-2002

operate, like the political will, cultural practices or the social customs/moral fabric of the society, and overall economic conditions. Several of these internal and external institutions have degenerated over the decades, some of which are worth mentioning. Until the initiation of reforms in 1992, Indian PSBs, had been operating not as independent organizations, but as if subsidiaries to the government with the objective of meeting the financial requirements of the state. They operated under the strict guidelines of the RBI, which were all encompassing. Although most of their deposits came from the private sector, i.e., households, a major part of their lending was confined to the government, and they also made substantial investment in government bills/securities as shown in Table 8. The share of investment in government securities in aggregate deposits of the commercial banks slowly increased from 23.6% in 1970 to 25.97% in 1990, thereafter it rapidly increased to 30.48% in 1995, to 35.32% in 2000 and to 40.75% in 2001. On the other hand, a reasonable return (excepting the amount deposited as CRR and the assets held as SLR) with full security is also beneficial for the bank.72 The developmental policies of the staterequiring mobilization of a large sum of money made the state a major customer of the PSBs. RBI acted as the mediator between the state and PSBs more or less determining the amount/share of the deposit to be allocated to the state and the private sectors. For the private sector lending it fixed ceiling and floor rates of interest depending on the type of loan, size of loan, type of borrower, nature of collateral, etc.73 The interest rates often did not reflect the risks of lending. RBI also fixed interest rates on deposits. The bank had little room for making own decisions in adjusting interest rates with the risks of lending, especially to the private borrowers. With frequent intervals, RBI changed CRR, SLR, and shares of loans to priority sector and other sectors, and the banks gradually learnt to adjust receiving deposits, lending and making investments accordingly.74 Through division of labor in the branches, banks were able to routinize things. Under

72

73

74

Interest on government securities was around 7 to 9 % in the early 1980s, 11 to 11.50% in the early 1990s and to the peak level of 14 % in the mid 1990s. Thereafter it rapidly declined and reached to the level of 9-9.5 % in 2001. For instance minimum of the key lending rates was 13.50% in 1980, which increased to 16% in 1989 and then to 19% in 1991-92. Thereafter it declined slowly. Similarly, the ceiling rate was 19.50 percent in 1980-81, which declined to 16.50% in 1987-88. The minimum rate for selective credit control also varied over the years which was freed in 1994-95 (RBI, 2003, Hand Book of Statistics on the Indian Economy, p.99). CRR more or less steadily increased from 4% by the end of 1974 over the decades to reach 15% in the mid 1989 and remained at that level till mid 1993. It then rapidly declined, with some occasional reversal, to the level of 4.75% by the end of 2002. A similar pattern may be noted with respect to SLR, it steadily increased from 26% in the early 1970 to 35 % in late 1981and remained around the peak level of 38-38.5% in the late 1980s and early 1990. Since 1993 it started declining rapidly to reach 25% in 1997.

Determinants of NPAs in the Indian Public Sector Banks: A Critique of Policy Reforms

41

this system, there was very limited scope for making profitable innovations in terms of both organizational changes and seeking new sources of fund and new avenues of investments/lending. As stated above, for many of the private sector loans, banks were not able to match risks with interest rate restrictions imposed by the RBI. Once RBI fixed the share of loans and the rate of interest to particular sectors, banks became constrained not to discriminate among borrowers of a limited number. For a long period, real interest rates were negative for many of these loans; obviously, vested interest, political and local intervention would creep in order to extract surplus in the system (i.e., difference between the opportunity costs and actual cost of borrowing). Since it was not mandatory on the part of the banks to declare NPA or recover loans, and since, RBI was happy so long as the banks were able to finance state expenditure, a laxity crept into the banking sector. This happened particularly for the kind of private sector lending mentioned above and, in general, profit earning/ meeting the interests of the depositors became the secondary objective of the banks. Often the non-intended borrowers received the loans, and even for the case of some target borrowers, the influential brokers who arranged the loans would take away a sizeable amount of the loan disbursed. The borrowers would not be able to repay the loans; even if they could, they would not be interested in doing so. The broker had to manipulate the system in such a way that the bank could not penalize the borrowers. On the contrary, the bank granted fresh loans to the defaulters so that the debt would roll on (known as evergreening of accounts). Under these circumstances, it was quite obvious that some personnel of the bank would also try to extract some surplus. Thus, a new institution, which is degenerative of the bank, evolved. The institution involved a nexus of some personnel of banks, brokers, and borrowers, that would siphon off public money through manipulating banking machinery, state machinery, mobilizing political and local forces. The banks on the other hand showed this lost money, or the rolling loans, as normal assets, as if earning interests or compounding over the years. The banking institution and their institutional environment that evolved over the decades were therefore not supportive of healthy and innovative ways of making progress by the banks. This is reflected in the functioning of the banks during the post reform period when several attempts have been made to improve upon the situation. Changes in the instruments with the banks, on the one hand, through reducing CRR, SLR, (marginally raising capital adequacy ratio), raised banks’ loanable money from a given deposit, and on the other hand, considerably widening banks’ freedom in their own decision making raised efficiency. Of late, state enactment provided greater power to the banks to penalize defaulters. It was expected that all this would make the PSBs more profitable, efficient and innovative with much reduced NPA. It needs to be mentioned that the institutions are slow to change, routines are difficult to break or change. Previously, almost the entire part of the decisions was de facto guided by the state/RBI, and the return on the compulsory lending to the state was also certain. Under the changed situation, in spite of the autonomy in decision making, PSBs could not come out of this routine behavior of operating in a risk free environment. They invested the extra money released from reduced SLR, CRR, on government bills and securities with assured return. Their lack of innovativeness is also indicated by the late introduction of credit/debit cards, ATM facilities which private banks started

42

The IUP Journal of Bank Management, August 2004

much early. Possibly PSBs did it under compulsion, as the ultimate strength of a bank is its depositors who tended to move away from the PSBs. As regards continued loan defaults and NPA, the bank routines/rigidities, and the institutions involving nexus of borrowers, agents and bank personnel continued to be responsible even under liberalization, RBI’s insistence on reduction of NPA and more restrictive legal enactment. It is not yet mentioned that the innovations may be a routine affair and can be institutionalized. But this is not the case with the Indian PSBs. Rather it could be a case with institutions, involving the nexus of vested interests indicated above, making frequent innovations in diverting bank money for personal gain as revealed in the past when special types of fraud cases were made public. The latter institutions are very difficult to change—it not only requires stringent punitive enactment and vigilance, but also public awareness, campaign and reforming electoral colleagues. Political forces to induce default must be contained. Given the institutional features of the PSBs and their institutional environment, no radical improvement is expected from these banks within a short period whatever be the improvement in the legal structure, organizational change and the level of autonomy. These are nevertheless essential for long term improvement and for building healthy institutions albeit slowly.

Reference # 10J-2004-08-02-01

Determinants of NPAs in the Indian Public Sector Banks: A Critique of Policy Reforms

43

Bibliography
1. Akerlof (1970) ‘The Market for Lemons : Qualitative Uncertainity and Market Mechanism’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol 84,pp.488-500. Bhattacharya, Prabir C and Sivasubramaian (2001) ‘Aspects of Banking Sector Reforms in India’, Economic and Political Weekly, October 27. Bharadwaj Swati (1998) ‘NPA is Likely to Affect Bank Wage Set up’, The Economic Times, 3rd November. Buisness Line (2003) ‘Banks at Receiving End on Bad Debt Sale by ARCs’, March 8. The Economic Times (1999) ‘Central Bank Sees Red Over Evergreening’, August 25. The Economic Times (1998) ‘SBI, BOI Have Crores Locked in Litigation’, November 8. The Economic Times (1999) ‘Fund Diversion Leads to Mounting NPAs: RBI’, June 30. The Economic Times (2001) ‘Mission NPA II: Foreclosures Deterrent to Trip Defaulters’, March 1. Ghosh, D N (1999) ‘Verma Committee Report on Weak Public Sector Banks’, Economic and Political Weekly, November 27. Ghosh, Sugoto (1999) ‘Bengal Banks yold to Get Moving on Loan Recovery’, The Economic Times, Februray 1. Godbole, Prasad (1998) ‘Credit Delivery: Risk Some, Win Some’, The Economic Times, December 23. Gogoi and Iyengar (2000) ‘RBI Maps Out New Rules for Recovery’, The Economic Times, August 2. Goswami, Onkar (1999), ‘The Myth of Asset Reconstruction Companies’, The Economic Times, August 12. Das, Madhvendra P (1999) ‘RBI Defines Willful Default as per CVC’s November Directive’, The Economic Times, March 9. Dasgupta, Sushmita ‘Non-performing Assets of the Steel Industry – A general Economic Concern’, www.indiainfoline.com. Desai, U C (1999) ‘Managing Bad Loans’, The Economic Times, February 17. Freixas, Xavier and Rochet Jean-Charles (1997) Microeconomics of Banking, MIT Press. Joshi, P N (1998) ‘The Banking Blues’, The Economic Times, December 28. Joshi,P N (2000) ‘NPAs: How Do We Tackle the Problem?’, The Economic Times, July 11. Karmeshu (1996), ‘Stochastic Models of Innovation Diffusion and Technology Substitution, The Mathematics Student, Vol. 65, Nos. 1-4, pp. 117-142. K.Kannan, Joshi, P N, Khan S H (2000) ‘NPAs: How do we tackle the problem?, The Economic Times, July 11.

2.

3.

4. 5. 6. 7. 8.

9.

10.

11.

12.

13.

14.

15.

16. 17. 18. 19. 20.

21.

44

The IUP Journal of Bank Management, August 2004

22. 23.

Khan S H (2000) ‘NPAs: How Do We Tackle the Problem?’, The Economic Times, July 11. Kijima, Masaaki (2001) ‘A Gaussian Term Structure Model of Credit Spreads and Valuation of Credit Spread Options’, The Kyoto University Economic Review, Vol LXX No 1-2, April-October. Kohli, Renu (1999) ‘Rural Branches and Financial Reforms’, Economic and Political Weekly, January 16-23, vol XXXIV ( 3 and 4) pp.169-174. Renu Kohli (2004) ‘Looking Beyond Non-Performing Assets’, The Indian Express, February 12. Mathur, K B L (2002) ‘Public Sector Banks in India: Should they be Privatised?’, Economic and Political Weekly, June 8. Mukherjee, S (1998) ‘Stress on Retail Banking May Hurt Bank Bottom Lines’, The Economic Times, December 21. Sangita Mehta (2002) ‘Foreclosure: Of Legal Tussles and Recovery’, The Economic Times, July 24. Mujumdar, N A (2003) ‘Credit Policy: Sound, Fury and Substantive Issues’, Business Line, May 13. Narasimham Committee I (1991): Report of the Committee on financial System. Puhazhendhi. V and Jayaraman, B (1999) ‘Rural Credit Delivery: Performance sand Challenges before Banks’, January 16-23, Economic and Political Weekly, vol XXXIV (3 and 4). Rajaraman, Indira, Bhaumik, Suman and Bhatia, Namita (1999): ‘NPA variation across Indian Commercial Bank: Some Findings’, Economic and Political Weekly, XXXIV (3 and 4). Rajaraman, Indira, Vasishtha (1999): ‘Non-Performing Loans of PSU Banks’, Economic and Political Weekly, XXXVII No. 2, February 2. Reserve Bank of India, Annual Report, Mumbai, various issues. Reserve Bank of India, Report on Trends and Progress of banking in India, Mumbai, various issues. Reserve Bank of India, Handbook of Statistics of the Indian Economy, Mumbai, various issues. Sen, Sarbajeet K (2003). ‘DRTs Block Implementation of Securitisation Act’, Business Line, July 7. Sen, Sarbajeet K (2003) ‘RBI One Time Settlement Schems fail’, Business Line, July 1. Shetty, Mayur (2000) ‘Draft Norms Want Banks to Treat Privately Placed Debt as Advance, not Investment’, The Economic Times, April 6. Singh, J K (2002) Financial Management-Text and Problems, Dhanpat Rai and Co, Delhi. Sukumar, C R (2003) ‘Bank of Maharastra Prefers Compromise Deals on NPA’, Business Line, May 24. Venu M K., (1999) ‘Sharp Increase in Write offs by Banks, Financial Institutions’, The Economic Times, March 15. Venu, M K (1999) ‘Banks Speed up Loan Clean up in 1999’, The Economic Times, December 23. Vekitaraman, S (1999) ‘A Level Playing Field: Myth and Reality’, The Economic Times, January 6.

24.

25. 26.

27.

28. 29. 30. 31.

32.

33.

34. 35.

36. 37. 38. 39.

40. 41.

42.

43. 44.

Determinants of NPAs in the Indian Public Sector Banks: A Critique of Policy Reforms

45

Similar Documents

Premium Essay

Npa in Banks

...was not taken seriously. Subsequently, following the recommendations of Narasimham committee and Verma committee, some steps have been taken to solve the problem of old NPAs in the balance sheets of the banks. It continues to be expressed from every corner that there has rarely been any systematic evaluation of the best way of tackling the problem. There seems to be no unanimity in the proper policies to be followed in resolving this problem. There is also no consistency in the application of NPA norms, ever since these have been recognized. Non Performing Assets are also called as Non Performing Loans. It is made by a bank or finance company on which repayments or interest payments are not being made on time. A loan is an asset for a bank as the interest payments and the repayment of the principal create a stream of cash flows. It is from the interest payments that a bank makes its profits. The problem of NPA is not limited to only Indian public sector banks, but it prevails in the entire banking industry. Major portion of bad debts in Indian Banks arose out of lending to the priority sector at the dictates of politicians and bureaucrats. If only banks had monitored their loans effectively, the bad debt problem could have been contained if not eliminated. The top management of the banks was forced by politicians and bureaucrats to throw good money after bad in the case of unscrupulous borrowers. Agriculture advances have registered a 7 fold net increase...

Words: 2574 - Pages: 11

Premium Essay

Non Performing Assets

...RECOVERY OF NPA STATUS AND CHALLENGES IN THE INDIAN BANKING SYSTEM EXECUTIVE SUMMARY: Non-performing Assets means a loan which has been classified by a bank or financial institution as substandard or loss assets. According to this default status would be given to borrower if the dues are not paid for 90 days. Asset Classification: * Standard: are the ones in which the bank is receiving interest as well as the principal amount of the loan regularly from the customer. If asset fails to be in this category i.e. amount due more than 90 days then it is NPA and NPAs are further need to be classified in sub categories. i) Sub-standard: the account holder comes in this category when they don’t pay three instalments continuously after 90 days and up to 1 year; ii) doubtful NPA; iii) Loss Assets: under this 100% provision is made. When account holder comes in this category their account can be written off by the banks. Types of NPA: * Gross NPA: reflects the quality of the loan made by the banks. * Net NPA: reflects the actual burden of the banks. The main reason behind NPA would be lack of proper enquiry by the bank, wilful defaulter, change in government policies etc. which could affect the bank by restriction on flow of cash by the bank for sanctioning a loan, drain of profit, bad affects on goodwill, etc. There are different acts and institution for the NPA recovery like SARFAESI ACT, 2002; SARC; ARC; DRT; Lokadalats; etc. Current...

Words: 4106 - Pages: 17

Premium Essay

Npa: Introduction About Npa

...NON-PERFORMING ASSETSCHALLENGE TO THE PUBLIC SECTOR BANKS INTRODUCTION After liberalization the Indian banking sector developed very appreciate. The RBI also nationalized good amount of commercial banks for proving socio economic services to the people of the nation. The Public Sector Banks have shown very good performance as far as the financial operations are concerned. If we look to the glance of the financial operations, we may find that deposits of public to the Public Sector Banks have increased from 859,461.95crore to 1,079,393.81crore in 2003, the investments of the Public Sector Banks have increased from 349,107.81crore to 545,509.00crore, and however the advances have also been increased to 549,351.16crore from 414,989.36crore in 2003. The total income of the public sector banks have also shown good performance since the last few years and currently it is 128,464.40crore. The Public Sector Banks have also shown comparatively good result. The gross profits of the Public Sector Banks currently 29,715.26crore which has been doubled to the last to last year, and the net profit of the Public Sector Banks is 12,295,47crore. However, the only problem of the Public Sector Banks these days are the increasing level of the non performing assets. The non performing assets of the Public Sector Banks have been increasing regularly year by year. If we glance on the numbers of non performing assets we may come to know that in the year 1997 the NPAs were 47,300crore and reached to 80,246crore...

Words: 6989 - Pages: 28

Free Essay

Non Performing Asset Npa

...Public sectorBank | Private sectorBank | | | Allahabad Bank | Axis Bank | Andhra Bank | DCB | Bank of India | Dhanlaxmi Bank | BOB | Federal Bank | Bank of Maharashtra | HDFC Bank | Central Bank | ICICI Bank | Corporation Bank | Induslnd Bank | Dena Bank | ING Vysya Bank | IDBI Bank | Karnataka Bank | Indian Bank | Yes Bank | Oriental Bank | J&K Bank | PNB | Lakshmi Vilas Bank | Punjab & Sind Bank | South Indian Bank | Syndicate Bank | | UCO Bank | | United Bank | | Union Bank | | Vijaya Bank | | SBI | | State Bank Bikaner & Jaipur | | State Bank Mysore | | State Bank Travancore | | Listed Banks in BSE 50 WEAK SECTOR Weak Sectors | No of Live Cases (2013) | No of Live Cases (2014) | Infrastructure | 20 | 25 | Iron & Steel | 59 | 53 | Power | 18 | 15 | Textiles | 74 | 45 | Ship-Breaking/Ship Building | 3 | 4 | Telecom | 11 | 5 | Weak Sectors | Aggregate Loan Amt (2013) | Aggregate Loan Amt (2014) | Infrastructure | 21912 | 57233 | Iron & Steel | 52682 | 43539 | Power | 18640 | 19138 | Textiles | 17677 | 20138 | Ship-Breaking/Ship Building | 6213 | 16792 | Telecom | 11681 | 10785 | Major Players Company | Loan Amount | Kingfisher Airlines | 2673 | Winsome Diamond | 2660 | Electrotherm India | 2210 | Zoom Developers | 1810 | Sterling Biotech | 1732 | S Kumars Nationwide | 1692 | Source: AIBEA, media report Rank:...

Words: 2296 - Pages: 10

Premium Essay

Comparative Performance Analysis of Indian Banks

...COMMERCIAL BANKS PRESENTED BY Gurlovleen Kaur ABSTRACT Commercial banks form the most important part of Indian financial landscape in terms of their role in channeling credit to the commercial sector and facilitating the process of financial inclusion. In the era of global competition, performance is the key factor for any subject, especially in banking. The Indian banking industry is made up of the Indian public sector banks and private sector banks. In this project an effort has been made to evaluate the financial performance of commercial banks by using key performance indicators as a benchmark, generally the financial performance of bank is evaluated by working out a number of ratios depending upon the data. This study has made use of five financial parameters ,i.e. ,Capital to Risk Weighted Assets Ratio( CRAR) ,Return on Assets ( ROA), Non Performing Asset (NPA),Net interest Margin (NIM), Profit Per Employee( PPE), as these are generally accepted ratios to evaluate the performance of banks ,in order of their performance. Research plan includes decision on data sources, research approaches, research instrument, sampling plan and contact method. The present study is based on secondary data. The data is collected through various journals, studies, websites and publications of banks. The collected data is analyzed to reach at conclusions regarding the various issues related to performance of commercial banks. In this study the 10 commercial banks are selected...

Words: 4494 - Pages: 18

Premium Essay

Analytical Study of Npa of Three Nationalised and Three Foreign Banks

...STUDY OF NPA OF THREE NATIONALISED AND THREE FOREIGN BANKS | | | Deep Majumder | Apeksha Shriyan | Non-performing Asset is an important parameter in the analysis of financial performance of a bank as it results in decreasing margin and higher provisioning requirements for doubtful debts. It affects the liquidity and profitability of the bank. The main objective of the present study is to find out the loop holes in the mechanism of controlling NPA. The data has been analysed by using tables and pie charts. The important point to be noted that if the level of NPA declines the profitability of the banks will increase. | INTRODUCTION The banking industry has undergone remarkable changes after the first phase of economic liberalization in 1991 and hence credit management. The primary function of the banks is to lend loans to various sectors such as agriculture, housing, personal and industry and to take deposits. Now the lending of the loans involves higher risk as there is always a risk of default involved. Now the present scenario of lending has changed as banks become more cautious about lending loans, the reason being the rising amount of non-performing assets. Earlier the Narasimham committee-I clearly pointed out that the reduced profitability of the banks are due to the NPA and thus recommended that it should be phased out. NON PERFORMING ASSET An asset, including a leased asset, becomes non- performing when it ceases to generate income for the bank. A...

Words: 2637 - Pages: 11

Premium Essay

Non Performing Asset

...in Management NPA’s of Bank Submitted to Lovely Professional University In partial fulfillment of the Requirements for the award of Degree of Master of Business Administration Submitted by: Suruchi Sehdev 10907783 RR1904A56 DEPARTMENT OF MANAGEMENT LOVELY PROFESSIONAL UNIVERSITY PHAGWARA EXECUTIVE SUMMARY After liberalization the Indian banking sector developed very appreciate. The RBI also nationalized good amount of commercial banks proving socio economic services to the people of the nation. The public Sector banks have shown very good performance as far as the financial operations are concerned. The total income of the public sector banks has also shown good performance since the last few years. The public sector Banks have also shown comparatively good result. The gross profits and the net profits of the Public Sector banks have been on a high from past few years. The private sector banks are also showing good results in case of profits. However, the only problem of the Scheduled Commercial Banks these days are the increasing level of the non performing assets. The Non-Performing Assets (NPAs) problem is one of the foremost and the most formidable problems that have shaken the entire banking industry in India like an earthquake. Like a canker worm, it has been eating the banking system from within, since long. It has grown like a cancer and has infected every limb of the banking system. At macro level, NPAs have choked off the supply...

Words: 9118 - Pages: 37

Premium Essay

Mba Wt Experience

...Nadu. s.poongavanam@gmailo.com ABSTRACT The banking industry has undergone a sea change after the first phase of economic liberalization in 1991 and hence credit management. While the primary function of banks is to lend funds as loans to various sectors such as agriculture, industry, personal loans, housing loans etc., in recent times the banks have become very cautious in extending loans, this is due to mounting nonperforming assets (NPAs). Therefore, an NPA account not only reduces profitability of banks by provisioning in the profit and loss account, but their carrying cost is also increased which results in excess & avoidable management attention. Apart from this, a high level of NPA also puts strain on a banks net worth because banks are under pressure to maintain a desired level of Capital Adequacy and in the absence of comfortable profit level, banks eventually look towards their internal financial strength to fulfill the norms thereby slowly eroding the net worth. Considering all the above facts banking industry has to give more importance to NPA and to structure proper remedial solutions. Key words: Assets restructuring company, Global competition, Rate of return, Repayment schedule, Lok Adalats. 1. Introduction After Nationalization the initial mandate that bank were given was to expand their branch network, increase the saving rate and extent credit to rural and SSI sector.(Talwar, 2001) Since 1990 the focus was sifter towards...

Words: 3314 - Pages: 14

Premium Essay

Indian Banking

...The Indian Banking Sector On the Road to Progress G. H. Deolalkar G. H. Deolalkar is formerly Managing Director of State Bank of India. 60 A STUDY OF FINANCIAL MARKETS Overview of Banking and Financial Institutions The Banking Sector The banking system in India is significantly different from that of other Asian nations because of the country’s unique geographic, social, and economic characteristics. India has a large population and land size, a diverse culture, and extreme disparities in income, which are marked among its regions. There are high levels of illiteracy among a large percentage of its population but, at the same time, the country has a large reservoir of managerial and technologically advanced talents. Between about 30 and 35 percent of the population resides in metro and urban cities and the rest is spread in several semi-urban and rural centers. The country’s economic policy framework combines socialistic and capitalistic features with a heavy bias towards public sector investment. India has followed the path of growth-led exports rather than the “exportled growth” of other Asian economies, with emphasis on self-reliance through import substitution. These features are reflected in the structure, size, and diversity of the country’s banking and financial sector. The banking system has had to serve the goals of economic policies enunciated in successive fiveyear development plans, particularly concerning equitable income distribution, balanced...

Words: 30682 - Pages: 123

Premium Essay

Measuring Risk Effeciency

...INTRODUCTION To start with Indian commercial banking was dominated by private ownership; profit and return to investments were its performance indicators. This was the scenario prior to 1969. Subsequently, commercial banks were nationalized adding to their list additional objectives of optimizing social benefit and geographical expansion to meet the growing needs of people. Globalization opened gates to increased competition by the entry of foreign banks. The changes that are taking world wide continued to give shocks to the banking system which resulted in an expansion of banking services both in range, volume and non-performing assets. Gauging efficiency of commercial banks is an important issue to bank management and the policy maker. Before this task is initiated a commercial bank has to be modeled appropriately to meet the needs and objectives of the analyst. To model a commercial bank two approaches followed mostly are the intermediation and production approaches. Under the intermediation approach financial institutions are viewed intermediate funds between depositors and borrowers (Piyu, Y., 1992). Banking business has to satisfy both the users and suppliers of bank funds. The intermediation approach is also known as the asset approach. In production approach a commercial bank’s resources produce services to the customers (Berg et.al, 1991; Berg et.al. 1993; Parson et.al, 1993; Shaffnit et.al, 1997). The basic difference is that in production approach ...

Words: 1201 - Pages: 5

Premium Essay

Research About Npa and Profitability

...which they maintain growth and control inflation in Indian economy. One of these tools is repo rate. An increase in the repo rate will make the borrowings more costly and it attempts to decrease the aggregate demand. Rising lending rates will also make the existing loans costly and thus adds to the pressure on the borrowers’ ability to service the debt. These accumulated debt leads to the massive NPA issue in nationalized banks in India. Net Worth relation with NPAs Net worth gets depleted by annual operating losses or a substantial decrease in asset values relative to liabilities. Banks are required to categorize non-performing assets further into three units on the period for which the asset has remained non-performing and the reliability of the dues: (i) Sub-standard Assets, (ii) Doubtful Assets, and (iii) Loss Assets. According to RBI directives, all banks are required to maintain NPAs both on gross and net basis. It is usually expressed in percentage term. NPAs= [(Gross or Net NPAs) / Total Advances]*100. NPA’s Relation with Capital Adequacy Ratio(CRAR) Capital adequacy ratio is used to protect depositors and promote the stability and efficiency of financial systems around the world. Correlation Analysis is one of the major objectives of the financial reform agenda was to securitization of the banking capitals by means of capital adequacy norms so that the magnitudes of NPA as a proportion to total deposit (NPA/D) will fall and as a result of that the overall C-D(Credit...

Words: 319 - Pages: 2

Premium Essay

Banking

...NPA is an advance where payment of interest or repayment of installment of principal (in case of Term loans) or both remains unpaid for a period of 90 or more days (new norms with effect from 31st March, 2004). Ninety days overdue - With a view to moving towards international best practices and to ensure greater transparency, it has been decided to adopt the '90 days overdue' norm for identification of NPAs, from the year ending March 31, 2004. Accordingly, with 1. Interest and /or installment of principal remain overdue for a period of more than 90 days in respect of a Term Loan, 2. The account remains 'out of order' for a period of more than 90 days, in respect of an Over-drat (OD) 3. The bill remains overdue for a period of more than 90 days in the case of bills purchased and discounted, 4. Interest and/ or installment of principal remains overdue for two harvest seasons but for a period not exceeding two and half years in the case of an advance granted for agricultural purpose. NPA represent bad loans, the borrowers of which failed to satisfy their repayment obligations. Michael (2006) emphasized that NPA in loan portfolio affect operational efficiency which in turn affects profitability, liquidity and solvency position of banks. Non-Performing Assets (NPAs) of the Indian banking sector have been rising in 2011-12, reached at 2.9% from 2.4% in 2008-09. NPA represent bad loans, the borrowers of which failed to satisfy their repayment obligations. Michael (2006)...

Words: 302 - Pages: 2

Premium Essay

Impact of Wilful Defaulter on Npa

...NON-PERFORMING ASSET An asset becomes non-performing when it ceases to generate income for the bank or financial institution. In the past RBI had sets guidelines for an asset to be classified as an NPA. An asset was considered as non-performing asset based on the concept of Past Due; a credit in respect of which interest/instalment of principal remained past due for a specific period of time. The specific period was reduced in a phased manner. An amount was considered as past due if it remained outstanding for 30 days beyond the due date. Starting from April 2001, the past due concept was removed and the period to be reckoned for calculation of non-payment started from the due date of payment. From the financial year 2003-04, in order to move towards international best practices, the RBI adopted the 90-days-overdue norms for identification of NPAs. With effect from March 31, 2004, a non-performing asset has been defined as a loan or an advance where:- * Interest/instalment of principal remains overdue for a period of more than 90 days in respect of a Term Loan * The account remains Out of order for a period of more than 90 days, in respect of an Overdraft / Cash Credit facility * The bill remains overdue for a period of more than 90 days in the case of bills purchased and discounted * In the case of direct agricultural advances, an annexure Annex 1 lists the types of advances which are to be treated in a special way as advised in the overdue norm. Agricultural...

Words: 2538 - Pages: 11

Free Essay

Non Performing Assets of Banks

...problem that the Indian banks are facing is the problem of their NPAs. It is only since a couple of years that this particular aspect has been given so much importance. The banks have to overcome these difficulties properly in order to effectively counter the competition faced by the foreign banks. With the framing of laws as per international standards and setting up of Debt recovery tribunal we can say that steps have been taken in this direction. Banks in India have traditionally been saddled with very high Non-Performing Assets. Banks burdened with huge NPA’s faced uphill tasks in recovering then due to archaic laws and procedures. Realizing the gravity of the situation the government was quick to implement the recommendations of the Narsimham Committee leading to the enactment of the SARFAESI ACT 2002. (Securitization and Reconstruction of Financial Assets and Enforcement of Security Interest Act). This Act gave the banks the much needed teeth to curb the menace of NPA’s. The non performing assets (NPAs) of banks have at last begun shrinking. As reported from surveys, it is understood that there has been substantial improvements in non performing assets and this has been because of several measures such as formation of asset reconstruction companies, debt restructuring norms, securitization, provisioning norms and prudential norms for income recognition. We also give our suggestions as to how NPA retrieval can be made easy and in what way the NPA scenario is headed...

Words: 993 - Pages: 4

Premium Essay

Sbi Performance Analysis

...SBI Research Department in 2000, through its paper “Performance analysis of 27 Public sector banks” published in SBI monthly review performance, Vol XXXIX, was prepared by Economic Research Department of State Bank of India, is to analyze the Performance of the 27 Public Sector Banks for the year 1999-2000 vis-a-vis the preceding year. Selecting four different categories of indicators-Business Performance, Efficiency, Vulnerability and labor productivity indicators, carried out the analysis. Altogether, 39 indicators were selected for this purpose. For the purpose of analysis, 27 PSBs disaggregated into four groups, namely, the SBI, ABs (7), the SBGs (8), the NBs (19). During 1999-2000, the PSBs exhibited better show in terms of several parameters...

Words: 1017 - Pages: 5